[Only the first part of this message is displayed. The entire message has been
turned into a text attachment, which you can retrieve by selecting Download.
Once downloaded, open it with a word processor or text editor for reading.]

********

Date: Wed, 17 Feb 1999 19:47:23 -0500
From: "James V. DeLong" <[EMAIL PROTECTED]>

Here is a skeptical look at current antitrust enforcement.
        Best,
        Jim DeLong


REASON * March 1999

The New Trustbusters
What's behind the resurgence of antitrust activism--and why it's bad news for
consumers.

By <[EMAIL PROTECTED]>James V. DeLong

Joel Klein is a famous man. The head of the Antitrust Division at the U.S.
Department of Justice usually toils in anonymity, known only to the in-groups
of the bar. Not Klein. He has sued Microsoft, the most prominent company in
America's jazziest industry, and demonized the world's richest human, Bill
Gates. He has assaulted the ubiquitous credit card franchises of Visa and
MasterCard and blocked important aerospace industry consolidations. He makes
speeches extolling the pivotal role of the Antitrust Division in the "new
economy" of globalization and information. These acts have earned him serious
attention in the national press.

Not to be left behind, Klein's fellow antitrusters at the Federal Trade
Commission are equally active. They have beaten up on superstores by stopping
the merger of Staples and Office Depot and by knocking down important
marketing
practices of Toys "R" Us. Like the DOJ Antitrust Division, the FTC has gone
high tech. It is challenging Intel, the grandee of computer chips, and probing
Cisco Systems, the dominant company in Internet switching hardware. In a
recent
suit against a drug company, the FTC asserted a heretofore unknown
authority to
force an alleged monopolist to refund to consumers $120 million in allegedly
ill-gotten profits.

Professional discussion of this surge in antitrust activism is proceeding at
two levels. One is the highfalutin language of bar association meetings and
academic conferences, where sessions are given titles like "Antitrust
Enforcement and High Technology Markets," "Networks, Lock-In Effects, and the

********

Date: Wed, 17 Feb 1999 19:47:23 -0500
From: "James V. DeLong" <[EMAIL PROTECTED]>

Here is a skeptical look at current antitrust enforcement.
        Best,
        Jim DeLong


REASON * March 1999

The New Trustbusters
What's behind the resurgence of antitrust activism--and why it's bad news for
consumers.

By <[EMAIL PROTECTED]>James V. DeLong

Joel Klein is a famous man. The head of the Antitrust Division at the U.S.
Department of Justice usually toils in anonymity, known only to the in-groups
of the bar. Not Klein. He has sued Microsoft, the most prominent company in
America's jazziest industry, and demonized the world's richest human, Bill
Gates. He has assaulted the ubiquitous credit card franchises of Visa and
MasterCard and blocked important aerospace industry consolidations. He makes
speeches extolling the pivotal role of the Antitrust Division in the "new
economy" of globalization and information. These acts have earned him serious
attention in the national press.

Not to be left behind, Klein's fellow antitrusters at the Federal Trade
Commission are equally active. They have beaten up on superstores by stopping
the merger of Staples and Office Depot and by knocking down important
marketing
practices of Toys "R" Us. Like the DOJ Antitrust Division, the FTC has gone
high tech. It is challenging Intel, the grandee of computer chips, and probing
Cisco Systems, the dominant company in Internet switching hardware. In a
recent
suit against a drug company, the FTC asserted a heretofore unknown
authority to
force an alleged monopolist to refund to consumers $120 million in allegedly
ill-gotten profits.

Professional discussion of this surge in antitrust activism is proceeding at
two levels. One is the highfalutin language of bar association meetings and
academic conferences, where sessions are given titles like "Antitrust
Enforcement and High Technology Markets," "Networks, Lock-In Effects, and the
New Economy," and "New Approaches to Reviewing Horizontal Agreements." In this
world, Platonic guardians mull over the implications of technological change
and devise optimal policies to safeguard American enterprise. They "open up a
dialogue with the bar and the academic community about antitrust doctrine," as
Klein put it in one of his speeches, on topics such as "the relationship
between antitrust and intellectual property, the significance of...network
effects and tipping points...
the impact of differentiated products theory, the role of potential
competition
and innovation markets, and [the meaning of] `agreement.'"

The second level of analysis is more skeptical, grounded in the public choice
school of economics. Public choice theory holds that exercises of government
power are driven by the material and ideological interests of the people who
wield it and by the private parties who can reward them with campaign
contributions, money, job security, or whatever else they value. Viewed
through
the lens of public choice theory, the recent burst of antitrust activity is
not
primarily about consumers or competition. It is about four kinds of interests:
1) competitors of successful firms who want to hamstring their rivals,
appropriate part of their businesses, or turn the clock back so they can
re-run
the race; 2) companies blown by the winds of technological change and looking
for ways to nullify their disadvantage; 3) the personal ambitions of antitrust
enforcers, who do not prosper in quiet times; and 4) the class interests of
the
legal profession, which are served by a combination of activist bias and mushy
theories.

Only a taste of this view creeps into the formal talks at antitrust
conferences. To get the full flavor, you must hang out in the corridors and
hotel bars, and stick around for the after-conference receptions. There you
hear jokes like this one: "What is the government's theory in the Microsoft
case? That the state of California has more computer companies than the state
of Washington, and a hell of a lot more electoral votes." Or this one, about
"Gore-Techs," the high-tech entrepreneurs who confer with Vice President Al
Gore: "What is Gore-Techs? A new fabric made by combining silicon and money,
used for wrapping up politicians."

In these less formal settings, last summer's Senate Judiciary Committee
hearings on Microsoft, in which Chairman Orrin Hatch (R-Utah) laid into Bill
Gates, are dismissed with, "What else would you expect from a senator who has
Novell in his state?" Testimony in the ongoing Microsoft trial about the
frequency with which the head of Netscape, the moving force behind the
lawsuit,
met with Klein and other Antitrust Division representatives is greeted with
blasé yawns. So are testimony and e-mail messages showing that high-tech
companies regard government antitrust action as simply one more tool in their
competitive arsenal, an alternative to price cuts or new products. And as the
head of Netscape said when asked why he did not file his own suit, it is much
cheaper to use the government's lawyers.

Behind the scenes at the conferences, you hear snickers about the innocence of
Microsoft, which thought it could sit out there in Redmond writing software
and
ignoring Washington, D.C.--as if such a big pot of wealth could go
unnoticed by
a rapacious imperial capital. The idea that perhaps a company should be
able to
do its business and ignore Washington is regarded as hopelessly naive.
Microsoft is now playing catch-up, adding former congressional aides to its
staff and boosting its budget for political contributions.

The suit against Visa and MasterCard, announced in October 1998, also evokes
grins. (See "Credit Where It's Due," January.) The Antitrust Division's press
release speaks of harm to consumers and of an industry that is "competitively
impaired." But the arrangement that the government just attacked has been
around a long time and was created in part due to antitrust concerns expressed
by the DOJ almost 20 years ago. Prior administrations investigated and
declined
to take action. The corridor talk notes the close relationship between the
Clinton administration and American Express, which has been complaining about
its rivals for years. Presidential friend Vernon Jordan is an AmEx director.
According to news accounts, AmEx has other ties to the White House: It bought
heavy advertising from the 1993 inaugural committee, it won the White House
Travel Office account, and it has replaced Diner's Club as the
government-issued credit card for federal workers.

In the 1997 Office Depot/Staples merger case, the FTC defined the relevant
market as "office supplies sold by superstores," even though the two chains
together sell only about 5 percent of all office supplies. Wal-Mart alone
sells
more than this, and bulk mail-order firms sell another huge chunk. Everyone,
except the FTC and the federal district judge who upheld its decision, regards
the commission's market definition as a laugher. (See "Pricing Pencils,"
August/September 1997.) But no one can figure out who had the political clout
to persuade the FTC to adopt such a silly position. The Wall Street
arbitragers
who lost a bundle when the deal cratered think the FTC's action was triggered
by complaints from Office Max, the third major superstore chain, which
stood to
get some assets on the cheap if the government forced the merged entity to
spin
them off in the name of protecting competition.

Last March, when the DOJ Antitrust Division nixed Lockheed Martin's effort to
acquire Northrop Grumman, the formal reasons involved concentration in the
defense industry. The corridor talk this time actually made it into The Wall
Street Journal. Lockheed had been blindsided by rival Raytheon, which gave the
government mountains of negative information. In its June 1998 story, the
Journal noted that Lockheed, not expecting trouble, had failed to adopt the
usual techniques of the merger game: "lobbying Capitol Hill, working the
executive branch and creating a drumbeat of support in the media."

The interests of selected businesses and political figures are not the only
ones served by the trend toward antitrust activism. The corridor lounger also
notes a certain incestuousness among the conference participants. Almost all
the private lawyers and economists on the panels used to work for the
government, while the government reps used to work in the private sector, and
most will return there at some point. Even the career employees turn free
agent
if the stars are right. The FTC litigator who led the Staples case left a few
months later for a well-paid partnership in a major law firm. In the
condottiere world of lawyering, his victory in a case that looked like a dog
greatly increased his market value. The arbs who lost big as a result want him
on their side next time.

It is a new springtime for antitrust lawyers and economists, promising a
return
to the good old days of three decades ago. Their memories of that era are
bathed in a golden glow. It was a time when antitrust regulators were
hyperactive, inhibited only by the need to invent a plausible scenario under
which a business arrangement might be regarded as "anti-competitive," and this
concept could be given any of several not necessarily consistent meanings.
Given such a nonstandard, the government won almost every time it challenged a
business arrangement. But the charade required a lot of lawyers and
economists.

This era ended in the 1970s. Two disastrous pieces of monster litigation--one
against IBM by the DOJ Antitrust Division, the other against the oil companies
by the FTC--ground on for years. Each went long past the point where it became
obvious that the government lacked a coherent theory of the supposed offenses
and long past the point where changes in the industry and in the world turned
the case into a joke.

During the same period, the University of Chicago school of antitrust analysis
began to convince judges and law students, and eventually even the bar, that
many of the government's anti-competitive scenarios were not plausible at all
and that arrangements which were valuable to consumers were being outlawed.
Antitrust law was suppressing rather than nurturing competition.

This revolution in antitrust thinking was consolidated in the 1980s, when the
Reagan administration pared enforcement back to the hard core of attacking
agreements to fix prices or divide markets, which almost all antitrust
analysts
regard as beyond the pale, and preventing mergers among direct competitors in
highly concentrated industries. The number of cases dropped off as enforcers
ceased to invent new theories, and businesses, with a fairly clear idea of the
line between legal and the illegal, could adjust their conduct with little
reference to the high priests of antitrust.

Antitrust practice came to mean filing the notification forms the government
requires before a corporate merger can be consummated and negotiating the
terms
on which the government would approve. This often meant selling off a division
or two in the name of preserving "competition" in some minor market or product
line, but the issues were usually marginal, rarely involving fundamental
questions of antitrust purpose and policy. Antitrust became a particularly
boring kind of regulatory law, consisting mostly of copying thousands of pages
of documents to ship over to the DOJ and the FTC for pre-merger review.

Now, after almost two decades of marginal relevance, the thrill of activism is
back. Corporate officers and Wall Street arbs once again furrow their brows
when they speak of "The Division" or "The Commission." The telephone rings.
Hours are billed. People who say "let's do lunch" actually follow up.
Headhunters pass out business cards. Members of the opposite sex no longer
flee
when you say, "I do antitrust."

It is important to avoid what the English writer C.P. Snow called "the
cynicism
of the unworldly." One should not underestimate the impact of sincere
belief on
the actions of government officials. The Antitrust Division, the FTC, and the
private bar are full of honest lawyers who would be outraged at the suggestion
that they are acting for personal or class interest, or that they are
stretching the law in the interests of ideology. But it is also important to
recognize that self-interest is the aphrodisiac of belief and that adopting
the
theories underlying the new activism is much to the benefit of the antitrust
professionals on both sides. To those with a bent for public choice
explanations, the enforcers, flogged on by the politicians and the
competitors,
have seized upon the computer, the information revolution, and the Internet as
excuses to reverse the cautious "first, do no harm" antitrust policy of the
past 20 years and restore the promiscuous activism that characterized the
1960s.

The question, of course, is whether these dour apostles of the public choice
view are right. Answering that question requires a return to the basics. The
antitrust laws stem from our collective fear of monopoly, a bred-in-the-bone
knowledge that a supplier of a good or service who lacks competitors will jack
up the price, cut the quality, become arrogant and unresponsive, and in
general
behave obnoxiously. Economists can give you good explanations for this,
complete with charts and graphs of supply and demand curves made out of solid
and dotted lines and annotated with lots of alphas and deltas. They can
explain
with precision why raising the price increases the monopolist's revenue
even if
it cuts sales, and they can tell you the size of the price hike that will
maximize the loot.

The noneconomists among us fear monopolies even without the charts and graphs,
based on common sense. After all, raising the price is logical; it is what we
would do if we had a monopoly of our own. We also look to our experience.
Think
of the U.S. Postal Service, cable television companies, state liquor
stores, or
the local public school. Monopolies all, and legendary for unresponsiveness,
ineptitude, and overcharging. But these things are mostly peripheral to our
lives, or there are safety valves in the form of substitute goods or direct
action, so the lack of competition is an annoyance rather than a disaster.
Imagine the impact of a complete monopoly in a truly essential product,
such as
automobiles or groceries.

The fear of monopoly that triggered the first of the big antitrust
statutes--the Sherman Act of 1890, which outlawed combinations in restraint of
trade and attempts to monopolize--was far from unfounded. Alfred D. Chandler
Jr., the eminent business historian, documented the situation in the late 19th
century in his classic book The Visible Hand. The rise of mass production,
combined with the railroad, the steamship, the telegraph, and the telephone,
created the possibility of nationwide marketing and management. As output
exploded, prices dropped precipitously. Many industries responded by
attempting
to put together cartels intended to reduce output and stabilize prices. The
means varied--contracts, holding companies, corporate voting trusts,
mergers--but the goal, as explicitly stated by the participants, was to attain
the joys of monopoly power over a market.

Considering these expressed intentions, public fear was rational, but history
has shown that it was largely unnecessary. It turned out that amalgamation is
not alchemy, and the trusts could not achieve their goal of excluding
competitors and sustaining prices at monopoly levels. The experience of the
National Cordage Association, recounted in Chandler's book, illustrates the
vulnerability of monopoly schemes. The NCA could not achieve economies of
scale
in operation or management. Nonetheless, it was forced to pay premium
prices to
lure competing companies into selling out, which stuck it with huge capital
costs. The bought-out competitors then used their money to start new cordage
companies that were more efficient than the NCA, so they could undercut its
prices. The association went bankrupt in 1893.

Even mighty Standard Oil, the great bête noire for trustbusters of the late
19th and early 20th centuries, was a symbol more than a true villain. By 1911,
when the Standard "monopoly" was broken up by the Supreme Court, eight other
large integrated oil companies were competing with it. Before that, Standard
never tried to sustain prices at high levels. The history of oil during the
late 19th century was one of huge expansion in markets and facilities and
steadily falling prices.

Many of the complaints about Standard came from medium-sized refiners that
lost
cozy local monopolies to Standard's rationalizing and price cutting. The same
pattern has been repeated many times. As changes in communications and
transportation create possibilities for new forms of business organization
that
might make things cheaper and better for consumers, firms that are doing well
under the old forms fight back. This was true in the late 19th century, and it
remains true today.

Often, the beneficiaries of the status quo cry "Monopoly!" Almost always, they
are wrong. If you look back at the examples of monopolies given a few
paragraphs ago, you will notice that all are public institutions or publicly
regulated businesses. It is impossible to find examples of truly private
monopolies, except on a minor scale. In areas where the natural technical and
economic structure of an industry would tend toward monopoly, such as
utilities
or railroads, public regulation was imposed early (with dubious results--but
that is a different tale). In other sectors, monopolies are rarely developed
and never sustained.

Some thinkers, such as Dominick T. Armentano, a professor emeritus of
economics
at the University of Hartford and a scholar of antitrust history, have
responded to this experience by advocating the elimination of the antitrust
laws. They argue that the benefits from the few instances in which these laws
might do good are outweighed by the harm caused by their inevitable
misapplication at the behest of the political system.

Others are less willing to scrap the antitrust laws. They note that it's
always
possible that the members of an industry might succeed in getting together and
setting a monopoly price. Perhaps in 1911 Standard and the other eight big oil
companies could have set up regular meetings and fixed prices or merged into
one company. Over the long term, such a monopoly would not last, any more than
OPEC lasted. As the price remained high, new entrants would want to get a cut
and would have to be brought into the cartel. Eventually, shares would get so
diluted that some members would find it worthwhile to break off and cut the
price, thereby ruining the system.

But a cartel can cause pain while it lasts, as did OPEC, and the wait for its
inherent contradictions to assert themselves can seem awfully long for us
short-lived humans. So most people who study the problem, whatever their
general political orientation, agree that a core of antitrust enforcement is
important. In particular, they agree that price fixing among competitors
should
be outlawed, and so should merger to monopoly and agreements to divide markets
and set up a series of monopolies in different sectors of the economy. This
was
the basic antitrust policy of the Reagan years.

As the abolitionists love to point out, though, when you take this first step
you step on an intellectual banana peel that sends you skidding down a
slippery
slope. The fundamental problem is that the meaning of "monopoly" is amorphous,
and the ambiguity leaves unclear exactly what the law is trying to prevent,
encouraging ad hoc approaches and governmental mischief.

A true, clear monopoly would be something for which there are no substitutes.
If you are drowning in the middle of a lake, and someone in a boat comes along
and asks if you want to buy a life jacket, he can fairly be said to have a
monopoly. Short of a situation like that, there are only varying degrees of
power to charge a premium price. A beef company's power is limited by the
availability of chicken and fish, and a local grocery store's power is limited
by your ability to shop in a neighboring town. In each case, the power is real
but limited. So at what point does this power justify government action? There
is no clear answer, and no satisfactory theoretical basis for developing one.

This fuzziness gives those interested in expanding antitrust enforcement,
including the enforcers, a lot of leverage. They argue that any power over
price, however small, in any identifiable product market is illegal. Then they
seek to define the market narrowly, making it easy to find a price effect.
In a
recent paper for the Cato Institute, University of Mississippi economist
William F. Shughart II, one of the most relentless public choice critics of
antitrust policy, lists some markets defined by the government: "high-priced,
non-ethnic frozen entrees" "noncarbonated, ready to serve, naturally or
artificially flavored fruit drinks, fruit punches, or fruit ades which contain
50 percent or less fruit juice and are customarily sold under refrigeration to
the consumer" "direct contract front-loaded trash removal in Dallas." These
market definitions do not have quite the same impact as "oil" or "steel."

The next step in expanding the realm of antitrust is to use static economic
models to predict an effect on price, often ignoring strategic responses
available to competitors that would erode any monopoly power. In analyzing the
Staples/Office Depot merger, for example, the FTC noted that slightly higher
prices prevail in some areas where only one of the companies operates. It
assumed this pattern was immutable, ignoring the ability of superstores,
mail-order houses, and customers to observe it and react.

By the time these steps are taken, the result is ordained. Anyone playing by
these rules who cannot find a monopoly on every corner isn't trying.

This game discourages efficiency-enhancing mergers. It also discourages
arrangements among firms, such as joint ventures and strategic partnerships,
that could create innovative products and reduce costs. Such deals always
involve some agreements on price and territory because the partners must
decide
how to split the proceeds. Each also needs to ensure that its partner does not
use it for a time, then muscle it out of the way and take over the whole
business.

Banning these contracts outlaws many worthy projects. As Fred Smith, head of
the Competitive Enterprise Institute, explains: "Any company wants to do many
different things. But it can be only one size, which means it cannot be
exactly
the right size and have exactly the right mix of skills and resources for each
of the things it wants to do. For some it is too big, for others too
small." If
different and possibly competing businesses can integrate some of their
operations without merging entirely, they can form entities that are the right
size for the venture at hand. The size that is appropriate for inventing a
software product, for example, may be different from the size needed to
make it
commercially viable. Manufacturing and marketing require still different
sizes,
talents, and structures. The industry is filled with people patching together
the temporary alliances needed to fill the gaps in their own organizations.
The
result, in software and elsewhere, is a flexible and adaptive economy, which
serves consumers well.

For a century, antitrust enforcement has been hostile to such partial
integrations among businesses. Ironically, this hostility creates pressure for
firms to merge completely. Due to oddities of antitrust law, merger may be
allowable under circumstances where partial integrations by contract would be
blocked.

In the 1960s, scholars with a public choice perspective began analyzing
whether
past antitrust actions had actually benefited consumers. It is not an easy
question to research, but a variety of ingenious studies have looked at stock
prices, scholarly opinions, competitors' reactions, and other indicators. The
results are strikingly consistent: Antitrust actions do not help the public,
though they may help the special interests that trigger them (while providing
well-paid employment for antitrust professionals). CEI's 1997 Antitrust Reader
and the 1995 book The Causes and Consequences of Antitrust: A Public Choice
Perspective (University of Chicago Press), edited by Shughart and Emory
University economist Fred McChesney, are good introductions to this
literature.

This research, combined with the dearth of empirical work on the other side,
was an important factor in the reforms of the 1980s. Proponents of
interventionist antitrust had an embarrassing lack of good examples. As
McChesney and Shughart point out, when you have a century of experience with a
program and virtually every landmark case looks to have been a mistake,
perhaps
it is time to stop saying, "well, we'll get it right next time," and start
rethinking the basic premises.

The current activists are having none of this. Quite the opposite. The seminar
sessions at antitrust conferences--the serious part, where the participants do
not joke about Gore-Techs--operate as if none of this rethinking happened. The
governing assumption is that basic antitrust policy and doctrine was and is
sound. The question is whether this tool that has served us so well can be
applied to the growing high-tech economy as it stands, or whether it needs to
be adapted and extended to reflect new realities. The possibility that the
antitrust emperor might be stark naked is ignored.

This should not really be surprising. More than 20 years ago, when I was a
middle manager in the FTC, an exasperating commission action prompted me to
say
to another staffer: "They tell the story of `The Emperor's New Clothes' a
little differently around here. It goes along as usual until the little boy
pipes up, `That man is naked!' Then, in the government version, the emperor
turns and says, `Kill that kid.' And they do." Public choice analysts know
that
an agency-emperor will seize any opportunity to off the uppity kid and
re-impose the myth of the beautiful robes. It will be assisted
enthusiastically
by private interests who want to turn the myth to their own advantage.

As a result, there is now a gusher of amorphous theories justifying renewed
antitrust activism. For example, theories of "path dependence" and "lock-in"
hold that society can become committed to an inferior technology, unable to
break free when a superior one comes along. It is an interesting idea with
little empirical support, as has been demonstrated by economists Stan
Liebowitz
and Stephen Margolis in the pages of REASON ("Typing Errors," June 1996)
and at
greater length in the academic literature. The Dvorak typewriter keyboard was
not really significantly better than the old QWERTY version, and now that
anyone can go Dvorak with a computer keystroke, almost no one does. The other
standard example, the triumph of VHS over Beta in videotape, is also wrong.
VHS, with its longer recording time, was regarded by consumers as a better
product.

It's true that once companies or consumers buy into a technology they will
incur costs if they want to change later. But this is hardly a new
development;
the same is true for purchases of equipment, constructing buildings, or any
other investment. Change occurs only when a new technology is sufficiently
superior to justify the switching costs, or when investment is turning over
anyway. So what? The fact that a company that introduces a good product gets
some first-mover advantages is one of the mainsprings of innovation. Is the
government now saying this should be foreclosed?

Another phrase popular among antitrust activists is "network effects." Some
things become more valuable as more people sign up, and the company that gains
an initial advantage may then sweep the field. The classic example is the
telephone, where everyone wants to be on the same network.

Again, an interesting idea, and one with clear merit. But again, not new, and
not unique to high-tech industries. Timothy Muris, now a professor at George
Mason University law school and, as head of the FTC's Bureau of
Competition, an
architect of the antitrust reforms of the 1980s, notes: "The fact that network
effects are everywhere should give us pause about the utility of the concept
[for antitrust]. Many products, not just high-tech ones, have the
characteristic [that] the benefits of use increase as the number of users
grows. Thus, consumers of products that require post-sale service, such as
automobiles and appliances, produce network effects from the growth of service
outlets when more consumers purchase the product. Coke and Pepsi drinkers
benefit from the network of their fellow consumers in that their drinks are
widely available in restaurants and from vending machines. Sports fans benefit
when they live in an area with enough other fans that teams find it profitable
to locate there."

During the formal presentations at antitrust conferences, the audience listens
raptly as phrases such as "path dependence" and "network effects" roll off
speakers' tongues. During the receptions the respect drops off, especially
because the speakers seem more interested in explaining why the concepts
justify an increase in their power than in any real analysis. A typical
corridor reaction to the new concepts is "buzzwords and bullshit."

More genteelly, participants note that most of the ongoing antitrust actions
lack basic clarity and coherence. The Microsoft litigation started with the
idea that the company was illegally tying sales of a Web browser to its
operating system. Then, during the trial, the theory shifted to a charge that
Microsoft wanted to divide the browser market with Netscape--a pretty silly
idea, given the capacity of other companies to make browsers of their own. Now
the government seems to be trying to prove that Microsoft is a meanie,
which is
not an offense under the Sherman Act. It is for the most part simply
hard-edged
jockeying over the terms of the partial integrations that are crucial to an
efficient software industry.

The government also seems to think that high market share alone meets the
legal
definition of monopoly, even if there is only tenuous evidence of power to
raise prices. Microsoft argues, of course, that it has a high share only
because it keeps prices low and that this is what really bothers its
competitors. They want Microsoft to be forced to set prices high enough to
leave room for them.

The incoherence extends beyond the Microsoft case. The FTC accuses Intel of
withholding information about forthcoming chips from companies that sued it
for
patent infringements. This is a novel extension of antitrust law. The relief
sought would force Intel to treat all similarly situated customers alike,
which
would put the FTC in the middle of endless disputes over the meaning of
"similarly situated" and "alike." The case looks like intervention in contract
disputes combined with casual meddling in difficult intellectual property
issues, plus an unarticulated assumption (also apparent in the Microsoft case)
that any company with a large market share should be converted into a new
breed
of public utility by government fiat.

The DOJ's Visa/MasterCard case is also puzzling. Two separate violations are
charged. First is the practice called "duality," whereby the two brands of
card
are issued by the same banks. The government contends that duality causes both
Visa and MasterCard to go easy on introducing new products, such as smart
cards, that might damage the other. The second alleged violation is that the
Visa/MasterCard banks do not issue AmEx, Discover, or any other card.

These theories are confusing. If Visa and MasterCard are agreeing to slow down
innovation, then AmEx, Discover, and other potential competitors should be
thanking them for leaving open such a valuable market opportunity. Government
intervention would be superfluous, and the last thing a competitor would want
is for the government to wake Visa and MasterCard up.

As for the other theory, if duality is illegal, then why is the government
trying to make it into quadrality? Or is the government saying that the banks
must become the partners of anyone who wants to go into the credit card
business? Again, this is a theory that converts any dominant company into a
public utility.

All of these matters, and more besides, fan suspicions that government policy
is blown by the winds of special pleading and political interest, and that the
complex intellectual rationales are simply a new cover for old-fashioned rent
seeking.

In a 1961 paper later published in Ayn Rand's Capitalism: The Unknown Ideal,
Alan Greenspan wrote: "The entire structure of the antitrust statutes in this
country is a jumble of economic irrationality and ignorance. It is the
product:
(a) of a gross misinterpretation of history; and (b) of rather naive, and
certainly unrealistic, economic theories." His analysis is still on target.
Building a new structure of "buzzwords and bullshit" atop an old one of
irrationality and ignorance will not fix the problem.

In the end, the private interests that are so eager to foster this activism
will regret it. As more than a few princes of Renaissance Italy could testify,
once you bring in the condottieri you have a problem. Before long, you don't
own them; they own you. The princes of Silicon Valley will soon have cause to
reflect on this lesson of history, as they plead with ignorant but arrogant
lawyers for permission to make deals or enter partnerships.

As T.J. Rodgers of Cypress Semiconductor recently warned his fellow tycoons in
a New York Times op-ed piece: "Winning by politics is antithetical to the
free-market competition that underpins Silicon Valley's success. The Justice
Department isn't just attacking Microsoft; it's attacking the way Microsoft
does business--and, by extension, the way most successful high-technology
companies do business."

Rodgers closed by pleading with his colleagues to go back before it's too
late.
It is possible they will see their own interest and bring their political
weight to bear on the side of free markets. If not, then the weary witness to
the predictive power of public choice theory, watching the government
re-create
the good old days of antitrust disasters, will be left with nothing but the
consolations of schadenfreude.

Contributing Editor <[EMAIL PROTECTED]>James V. DeLong is an adjunct
scholar
with the Competitive Enterprise Institute and the author of
<http://www.amazon.com/exec/obidos/ISBN=0684874377/reasonmagazine/>Property
Matters: How Property Rights Are Under Assault--And Why You Should Care (The
Free Press). His Web site is <http://www.regpolicy.com>www.regpolicy.com.



--------------------------------------------------------------------------
POLITECH -- the moderated mailing list of politics and technology
To subscribe: send a message to [EMAIL PROTECTED] with this text:
subscribe politech
More information is at http://www.well.com/~declan/politech/
--------------------------------------------------------------------------



Reply via email to