http://www.hindu.com/2005/01/03/stories/2005010301861000.htm
The Hindu
Jan 03, 2005

Guaranteeing employment: a palliative?

By T.N. Srinivasan

Let us not kid ourselves: an employment generation programme is a 
palliative and not a means for poverty eradication.

AMIT BHADURI's article ( The Hindu , Dec 27, 2004) is an eclectic 
mixture of micro and macroeconomic arguments, comments on electoral 
politics, political economy, and above all a plea to the Government 
to come up with a "much larger employment programme and the right to 
information at all levels." Many overlapping employment generation 
programmes (EGP) have been in operation over a considerable period of 
time, with varying degrees of effectiveness. Professor Bhaduri does 
not comment on them nor does he offer a precise, quantitative, and 
time phased description of his "larger" programme as well as a 
reasoned case for its feasibility and cost-effectiveness.

Professor Bhaduri rightly points out that the classic theorems about 
Pareto optimality of a laissez-faire Competitive Market Equilibrium 
say nothing on the desirability from a social perspective of the 
resulting distribution of income, let alone on the existence and 
dynamic stability of the equilibrium. However, he fails to add the 
crucial corollary that in attempting to move income distribution in a 
socially desirable direction policy interventions have to be 
carefully chosen. Prices in a competitive market play a dual role as 
signals for an efficient allocation of scarce resources, at a point 
of and over time, and as determinants of income distribution. While 
changing the path of income distribution in desired directions, one 
has to ensure that the policies chosen distort the allocative role of 
prices the least. Most policies over the first four or so decades of 
our development, rationalised in the name of poverty alleviation 
would hardly satisfy this desideratum of policy choice. Until 
twenty-five years ago our growth was too slow to make any dent on 
poverty on its own, poverty-oriented programmes were ineffective, and 
other policy interventions slowed growth and increased poverty from 
what they might have been. The cancer of corruption and rent seeking 
these policies induced in the body politic are well known.

Professor Bhaduri invokes the Keynesian argument that deficit 
financing to activate idle capacity would not be inflationary. He 
asserts that there is idle capacity in cement, steel and transport. 
The argument applied to an economy closed to international trade so 
that stimulation of domestic demand (I do not want to enter the 
debate on the role of price rigidities in Keynesian analysis) was 
needed to activate idle capacity. In an open economy, such as ours, 
lack of demand cannot be the reason for idle capacity - with steel 
and cement being exportable there would always be world demand for 
them provided we are internationally competitive. Thus the demand 
constraint as an explanation for idle capacity is overblown and so is 
any concern, at least for now, about inflation being stoked by any 
addition to an already huge fiscal deficit.

Theories about competitive equilibrium, irrelevance of fiscal 
deficits, and putting rights based arguments as well as capabilities, 
entitlements and functionings in their proper modest places are not 
central to Professor Bhaduri's plea. It rests on the undoubted 
attractiveness of a well-designed and well-implemented EGP for 
providing the poor (and only the poor) income earning opportunities 
in the short run that they do not have in an adequate measure. If, in 
addition to enhancing the incomes of the poor, the programme also 
produces valuable assets or goods and services, it is an additional 
argument in its favour. Having published with N.S.S. Narayana and 
Kirit Parikh, some quantitative simulations based on a model of the 
Indian economy, on the effectiveness of rural employment generation 
programmes, under alternative assumptions about their productivity 
effects and leakage (to non-poor) propensities, I am certainly 
sympathetic to Professor Bhaduri's plea.

However I have three concerns.

First, I am not confident in the ability of our 
political-administrative system in designing and executing an EGP of 
a size needed to make a significant dent on poverty. For example, 
given the differences in governance across States and particularly in 
the functioning of Panchayati Raj institutions to which Professor 
Bhaduri rightly assigns the responsibility for executing the EGP, one 
cannot assume that one can successfully replicate, say in Bihar, what 
was successful, say, in Maharashtra. Realistically the non-resource 
political and administrative constraints, rather than constraints of 
budgetary resources, would restrict the size of the programme.

Secondly, the EGP could become a permanent transfer programme to 
alleviate poverty, and to the extent it is successful, it could 
divert attention from addressing the fundamental issue of eradicating 
poverty. Creating employment opportunities otherwise unavailable is 
certainly an appropriate short-term measure. But the long-term 
solution is to create an economic, political, and social environment 
in which the economy generates productive employment opportunities in 
a sustained manner, for wage earners, casual workers, as well as the 
self employed (the largest single source of employment for our work 
force) including women, and take children out of work and keep them 
in schools.

Thirdly, subsidies, justified as pro-poor, should be reconsidered 
while expanding EGP. Subsidising some goods or services consumed by 
the poor (such as primary education, healthcare and sanitation) for 
the reason that there is a significant beneficial, social externality 
in enabling the poor to consume more than what they would have in the 
absence of a subsidy, is eminently worthwhile. However, not charging 
for scarce power or subsidising fertilizer use or cross subsidy of 
passenger transport by Railways, etc., and even a large part of 
public distribution system for food grains cannot possibly be 
rationalised on grounds of social externality. Elimination of such 
subsidies would generate resources for a larger EGP. Privatisation of 
public enterprises will also raise resources. Whether a public 
enterprise makes a profit or loss is irrelevant in deciding whether 
to privatise it. The loss (profit) of a socially justified public 
enterprise has to be made up from (add to) general revenues. 
Privatisation of public enterprises (including a large part of the 
financial sector) that have no social rationale, and at the same time 
creating a competent and independent regulatory system to ensure that 
a possibly inefficient public enterprise is not replaced by an 
efficient private monopoly, should raise large resources.

If our panchayats and other relevant bodies could identify the truly 
needy in their jurisdictions, a simple transfer of income to the 
needy would be most cost effective in addressing poverty. Only if 
such unconditional transfers are viewed as insulting the self-esteem 
of the recipient or distorting work/leisure choices, EGP is a better 
alternative. In an environment conducive to the generation of 
productive opportunities in the normal course, the economy would be 
growing at a rapid and sustainable pace, and the fruits of growth 
would be widely shared. The social environment, obviously, would be 
free of any discrimination based on caste, class or sex. The 
political environment would be a thriving participatory democracy 
with efficient and incorruptible judicial and administrative systems.

I am afraid our economy is currently nowhere close to such an 
environment, nor are our social, political and administrative 
environments. The facts that (a) high fiscal deficits have not 
kindled inflation;(b) foreign reserves continue to grow; (c) real 
interest rates are at all time lows; (d) commercial banks are holding 
far more government paper than they are required to hold;(e) the 
current account has been in surplus for two years in a row;(f) the 
rate of domestic savings (investment) in 2002-03 the same (less) 
compared to 1990-91; and above all, (g) GDP rate of growth has slowed 
down since the peak of 7.8% in 1996-97 and appears to be converging 
to the contemporary Hindu rate of growth of about 6%, are consistent 
with the hypothesis that the domestic investment climate is poor. 
India attracts as much foreign direct investment as Thailand WHICH 
EXPERIENCED A SEVERE financial crisis in 1997, and a tenth of the 
inflows to China in 2003. Our poor country invests its reserves in 
U.S. Government securities yielding very low rates of return. 
However, with fiscal deficits already high, it may be unwise to use 
of part of foreign exchange reserves for domestic investment with 
higher return, say in infrastructure, since any mechanism for doing 
so would necessarily increase the fiscal deficit.

A serious and sound empirical analysis is needed of whether (a) the 
fiscal deficit is sustainable, (b) reserves are far more than would 
be needed to smooth trade fluctuations and (self) insure the economy 
against a financial crisis of foreign origin and indeed, (c) whether 
the real binding constraints on the growth process of the economy are 
the dominant presence of a slowly reforming, inefficient and 
inflexible public sector in crucial power and the financial sectors. 
Fiscal deficits are indeed too high and some analysts have found 
India's macro indicators to be similar to those of countries that 
experienced a macroeconomic and financial crisis.

Notwithstanding bright spots such as our IT and telecommunication 
sectors, the failure to address the fiscal consolidation, 
dilly-dallying relating to the implementation of the Electricity 
Bill, the rhetoric on privatisation of the Left parties, the shelving 
of any change in labour laws, failure to complete trade reforms and 
clinging on to demands for counterproductive special and differential 
treatment in the Doha round negotiations, and the persistent 
infrastructure bottlenecks do not leave much room for optimism about 
creating soon an economic environment for eradicating poverty through 
rapid growth. Until then there is no better alternative to an EGP of 
a scale consistent with implementation capacities, for alleviating 
poverty. Let us not kid ourselves: it is a palliative and not a means 
for poverty eradication.

(The author is Samuel C. Park Jr. Professor of Economics, Department 
of Economics, and Chair, South Asia Studies Council, Yale University, 
Newhaven, CT USA)

_________________________________

Labour Notes South Asia (LNSA):
An informal archive and mailing list for trade
unionists and labour activists based in or
working on South asia.

LNSA Mailing List:
Labour Notes South Asia
To subscribe send a blank message to:
<[EMAIL PROTECTED]>

LNSA Web site:
groups.yahoo.com/group/lnsa/

Run by The South Asia Citizens Web
www.sacw.net
_________________________________








------------------------ Yahoo! Groups Sponsor --------------------~--> 
What would our lives be like without music, dance, and theater?
Donate or volunteer in the arts today at Network for Good!
http://us.click.yahoo.com/Tcy2bD/SOnJAA/cosFAA/e0EolB/TM
--------------------------------------------------------------------~-> 

To join the Labour Notes South Asia Mailing List, send a blank message to:   
[EMAIL PROTECTED]
To Unsubscribe, send a blank message to: [EMAIL PROTECTED] 
Yahoo! Groups Links

<*> To visit your group on the web, go to:
    http://groups.yahoo.com/group/lnsa/

<*> To unsubscribe from this group, send an email to:
    [EMAIL PROTECTED]

<*> Your use of Yahoo! Groups is subject to:
    http://docs.yahoo.com/info/terms/
 



Reply via email to