Saw this on another list; always good to read articles by the fellow whose
book inspired the Armchair list....

----

http://slate.msn.com/?id=2070182

One Small Step for Man …
… and one giant leap for economists: How we figured out why people walk up
staircases but not up escalators.
By Steven E. Landsburg  Wednesday, August 28, 2002,


I am privileged to teach in one of the world's most respected economics departments.
We're on pretty much everyone's top-15 list, and by a lot of measures, we're
considered top-five. I mention this by way of pointing out that this is not some
bunch of bozos we're talking about here.

And yet somehow last summer, we managed to spend a week in a state of collective
befuddlement, obsessing over a seemingly impenetrable conundrum that came up over
lunch: If people stand still on escalators, then why don't they stand still on
stairs?


It was observed early on that if you stand still on stairs, you'll never get
anywhere. But for reasons I can no longer entirely reconstruct, that explanation was
dismissed as overly simplistic. Soon the search for a deeper theory was under way.
Within a few days, blackboards all over the economics building were covered with
graphs and equations. Research projects were temporarily shelved while we tackled
the escalator puzzle, which had taken on the dimensions of a profound and perhaps
insurmountable challenge to economic theory.

For those of us who were too dense to see what all the fuss was about, one of our
colleagues spelled out the paradox: Taking a step has a certain cost, in terms of
energy expended. That cost is the same whether you're on the stairs or on the
escalator. And taking a step has a certain benefit—it gets you one foot closer to
where you're going. That benefit is the same whether you're on the stairs or on the
escalator. If the costs are the same in each place and the benefits are the same in
each place, then the decision to step or not to step should be the same in each
place.

In other words, a step either is or is not worth the effort, and whatever
calculation tells you to walk (or not) on the escalator should tell you to do
exactly the same thing on the stairs.

And so one of the world's top economics departments entered a state of near
paralysis. Theories were presented, considered, and rejected; I will spare their
inventors (including myself) the embarrassment of having those theories recounted
here. Suffice it to say that each theory centered around one or another cockamamie
reason why "marginal analysis"—the weighing of costs and benefits associated with
taking a single step—might not apply in this situation.

For a bunch of economists, that's a pretty radical position since we use marginal
analysis to explain how people choose everything from the lengths of their workdays
to the number of chocolate-chip cookies they have for lunch. (What is the cost, in
terms, say, of calories, of one additional cookie? What is the benefit, in terms of
deliciousness? If the benefit exceeds the cost, have another! Otherwise, it's time
to stop.)

Soon the madness spread beyond Rochester, N.Y. One of my colleagues posed the
escalator problem at a conference in Boston, where he was overheard by an economist
from another top department who excitedly volunteered that he'd always been plagued
by exactly the same question.

Oh, we've been collectively obsessed before. Faithful readers of this column might
recall that we once spent a week arguing about the right way to peel a banana. But
with bananas we knew we were being whimsical; with escalators we felt genuinely
challenged.

Regarding escalators, the solution came in a blinding flash. Marginal analysis does
work. It is right to compare the costs and benefits of each individual step. (And
thank God it's right; otherwise I'd have to retract everything I've told my students
since the day I started teaching.) But before you can weigh costs against benefits,
you've got to measure the benefits correctly. And in this case, "getting one foot
closer to where you're going" is the wrong way to measure benefit. Who cares how
close you are to where you're going? What matters is how long it takes to get there.
Benefits should be measured in time, not distance. And a step on the stairs saves
you more time than a step on the escalator because—well, because if you stand still
on the stairs, you'll never get anywhere. So walking on the stairs makes sense even
when walking on the escalator doesn't.

My colleague Mark Bils figured out a way to rephrase this so that even an economist
can understand it. Every producer knows that workers should spend less time with
inferior machinery. Compared to an escalator, a staircase is an inferior machine, so
the "workers"—that is, the people who use the stairs—should try to minimize their
time there. The way to limit your time on a staircase is to keep walking until you
get to the end.

The same argument proves, incidentally, that even if you choose to walk on the
escalator, you should always walk even faster on the stairs. If you're planning to
write and tell me that in fact you walk at the same speed in both venues, I'd really
rather not hear about it right now.

So what's the moral of the story? To me, the moral is that we should take seriously
what we tell our students: Marginal analysis really works. If it seems not to be
working, the right question is not, "Why doesn't the marginal analysis work?"
Instead, the right question is, "How am I failing to understand the marginal
analysis?" or, more succinctly, "In what way am I being stupid?"






Reply via email to