And the Oscar Goes to...Not Its Voting System 
Selection of Academy Award Nominees and Winners is Flawed, but 
Reformers Can't Seem to Elect a Better Candidate
By CARL BIALIK
   
Academy Award nominees and winners are selected using two different 
voting systems that are, according to some political mathematicians, 
the worst way to convert voters' preferences into an election 
outcome.

The nominees are selected using a system called instant runoff, 
which has been adopted in some municipal and state elections. Out of 
last year's 281 eligible films, each voter selects five nominees in 
order of preference for, say, best picture. All movies without any 
first-place votes are eliminated. The votes for those films with the 
least first-place votes are re-assigned until five nominees have 
enough.

One problem with that system is a kind of squeaky-wheel phenomenon: 
A movie that is second place on every ballot will lose out to one 
that ranks first on only 20% of ballots but is hated by everyone 
else. Then, in another upside-down outcome, a movie can win for best 
picture even if 79% of voters hated it so long as they split their 
votes evenly among the losing films. This isn't as unfamiliar as it 
sounds: Some people think Al Gore would have won the Electoral 
College in 2000 if Ralph Nader hadn't diverted more votes from him 
than he took from former President George W. Bush.

 
Getty Images"It's crazy," says Michel Balinski, professor of 
research at École Polytechnique in Palaiseau, France. The nomination 
system's properties are "truly perverse and antithetical to the idea 
of democracy," says Steven Brams, professor of politics at New York 
University. He thinks the final vote for the Oscar winner may be 
even worse than the selection of nominees.

The big problem: If voting systems themselves were put to a vote, 
prominent scholars would each produce a different ballot, then 
disagree about which system should be used to select the winner. So 
it's no surprise that advocates of alternate voting systems, which 
range from simple yes/no approval ratings to assigning numerical 
scores to each candidate, have had little more luck reforming 
political elections than they have with entertainment awards.

Consider two systems that, on the surface, seem similar. Prof. 
Balinski and mathematician Rida Laraki have devised a system they 
call majority judgment that requires voters to rank each candidate 
on a scale from 1 to 6. The votes are lined up in order, and each 
candidate is assigned the middle, or median, score. The highest 
median score wins. Another system, range voting, isn't that 
different: The candidate with the highest average, or mean, score 
wins.

Yet the second system's leading advocate, Warren D. Smith, co-
founder of the Center for Range Voting, has devoted a Web page to 
the Balinksi-Laraki system's "numerous disadvantages."

Brace yourselves for "Ishtar" defeating "The Godfather." Suppose 49 
voters award "The Godfather" six points and "Ishtar" only four. One 
voter grants the desert debacle four points and the mafia 
masterpiece three, and the remaining 49 award "The Godfather" three 
points and "Ishtar" only one point. "Ishtar" actually wins with a 
median score of four points compared to "The Godfather's" three 
points. Prof. Balinski, in turn, calls range voting a "ridiculous 
method," because it can be manipulated by strategic voters.

Despite the flaws in Oscars voting, the system remains as it has 
since 1936. Every 15 years or so, the Academy re-examines its voting 
and has decided to stick with it, says the Academy of Motion Picture 
Arts and Sciences' executive director, Bruce Davis. "It is a very 
effective method of reflecting the will of the entire electorate," 
Mr. Davis says.

 But many voting theorists aren't so keen on the system. It's called 
instant runoff because it is used in political elections in lieu of 
a two-stage vote in which top candidates compete again if none 
receives a majority of the vote. Among the potential problems, 
showing up to vote for your favorite candidate may create a worse 
outcome than not showing up at all. For example, your vote could 
change the order in which candidates are eliminated, and the next-in-
line candidate on the ballot for the newly eliminated film may be a 
film you loathe.

To choose Oscar winners, voters simply choose their favorite from 
the nominees, and the contender with the most votes wins. That could 
favor a film that has a devoted faction of fans, and sink films with 
overlapping followings who split their vote. Even most critics of 
instant runoff say it beats this plurality system that led to the 
Gore-Nader-Bush result. In the film realm, Prof. Brams of NYU blames 
the current system for the best-picture victory of "Rocky" over 
films such as "Network" and "Taxi Driver" that he speculates would 
have won head to head.

How this works out in reality is hard to know, because the Academy 
doesn't release any details about the balloting, even after the 
telecast, in part to avoid shaming fifth-place films. Mr. Davis says 
even he never learns the numbers from his accountants: "Are there 
years when I'm curious as to what the order of finish was? 
Absolutely. But I recognize it as a vulgar curiosity in myself."

More
The Oscars involve two stages of voting, for nominees and for 
winners. Delve into the math of elections in the Numbers Guy blog.

Complete Coverage: Academy AwardsSuch secrecy frustrates voting 
theorists who are anxious for experimental data about voter behavior 
that may help them choose from among different voting systems. 
Without such evidence, they are left to devise their own studies, to 
dream up examples that sink rival systems or to create computer 
simulations to study how easily different systems can be manipulated.

Sports fans cry manipulation when votes don't go as they'd hoped. 
Many sports awards and rankings are derived from what is known as 
Borda count, which asks voters to rank candidates and then assigns 
points on a sliding scale, with the most for first-place votes and 
the least for last-place ones.

Critics of these systems fear that strategic voters will assign 
their top choice the highest possible score, and everyone else zero, 
thereby seizing more power than voters who approach the system 
earnestly; or, in the case of rankings, bury or omit a preferred 
candidate's top rival. Boston Red Sox fans will tell you to this day 
that such strategic voting by a New York beat writer cost Pedro 
Martinez the American League Most Valuable Player award a decade ago.

Says Prof. Balinksi, "Not everyone will do it, but enough will do it 
to manipulate the results."

There is a philosophical question obscured by that criticism: Should 
voters with stronger feelings have more influence? A voter may 
support Candidate A strongly and loathe all the rest; two other 
voters may like Candidate A but slightly prefer B. Should B beat A 
even though all voters would have been fine with A?

Some scholars back the Condorcet winner, the candidate that would 
beat all others in head-to-head matchups. Trouble is, there isn't 
always one. As an alternative, Prof. Brams advocates approval 
voting, which tallies the number of voters who approve of each 
candidate and chooses the one with the most votes.

Rob Richie, executive director of FairVote, which has had success 
pushing the adoption of instant runoff for elections, says that 
approval voting doesn't fly with politicians: They're uncomfortable 
with the idea that voters who prefer them might throw equal support 
to a rival. For advocates of alternate systems, it's crucial to get 
support from politicians because voters aren't likely to get excited 
about such issues unless the country is hanging on a chad.

Mr. Richie argues that, in practice, instant runoff hasn't displayed 
the feared paradoxes. He says his critics should go get their 
preferred systems adopted so they can offer their own proofs of 
concept. He adds that mathematicians haven't made much headway 
changing voting laws "so they hound reformers who are being 
successful, and that's just irritating."

Vanderbilt University mathematician Paul H. Edelman, who has 
consulted with the Country Music Association on its annual awards, 
says his colleagues should tone down the dogma and embrace a range 
of voting systems for different situations. "The mistake that 
mathematicians make is to assume that all elections are the same," 
Prof. Edelman says. "That's a terrible thing to do."

Get Me a Recount
 While Academy Award nominees and winners are selected using two 
different voting systems, there are at least six other major ones 
that have been proposed and studied by scholars. And each one can 
produce different outcomes from the same ballots.

In a hypothetical 11-voter election, in which voters score eight 
candidates from 0 to 20, each candidate would win under one of eight 
major voting systems. Bolds mean that voter approves that candidate -
- roughly equivalent to a yes/no vote.

  
Number of Ballots Candidate 
A B C D E F G H 
4 18 4 5 17 15 0 13 14 
3 0 14 5 11 12 10 8 9 
2 0 12 20 10 11 9 18 19 
1 2 0 12 17 1 11 16 3 
1 0 1 4 2 3 16 15 5 
Wins in Plurality Runoff Instant runoff Borda count Condorcet 
Approval voting Mean range voting Median range voting 

See how each candidate wins in each system:

A wins in plurality: A has four first-place votes, more than any 
other candidate.

B wins in runoff: All but the top two first-place vote getters, A 
and B, are eliminated. B is preferred by three of the four voters 
who ranked other candidates first, and beats A, 6-5.

C wins in instant runoff: Under this system, each voter selects five 
nominees, in order, in a given category. E, G and H have no first-
place votes and are eliminated first. Then come D and F, which each 
have one first-place vote. Among remaining candidates, C ranks 
second on those ballots, so C picks up two more first-place votes 
and is now tied with A, with four. B, with three, is eliminated 
next, and C ranks above A on the ballots that belonged to B, so C 
beats A, 7-4.

D wins in Borda count: Borda count asks voters to rank candidates 
and then assigns points on a sliding scale, with the most for first-
place votes and the least for last-place ones. On each ballot, give 
seven votes to the first-place contender, six to second, and so on, 
down to zero for the last-place candidate. D edges E, 52-48.

E wins in Condorcet: The Condorcet winner is the candidate which 
beats all others in head-to-head matchups. E beats every other 
candidate head to head, by ranking higher than each on a majority of 
ballots. E beats A, 6-5; B, 6-5; C, 6-5; D, 6-5; F, 9-2; G, 7-4; H, 
7-4.

F wins in approval voting: This system tallies the number of voters 
who approve of each candidate and chooses the one with the most 
votes. F is approved by seven voters, edging D, approved by 6.

G wins in mean range voting: The mean vote for G is 13, edging D, 
with 12.7.

H wins in median range voting: The median vote for H is 14, beating 
G, which has 13.

Sources: Center for Range Voting; WSJ Research

Write to Carl Bialik at numbers...@wsj.com

Corrections & Amplifications 
Warren Smith is co-founder of the Center for Range Voting. He is no 
longer affiliated with Temple University. A previous version of this 
column incorrectly referred to him as a Temple mathematician. In 
addition, a label is incorrect in the graphic accompanying this 
column. In the final stage of the runoff, C beats A, 9-5, not 7-4.



Reply via email to