-Caveat Lector-

Polyconomics

Jan 3 2003


Supply-Side University
SSU Lesson #15: Ibn Khaldun, Part III (Empires in Decline)

To: Students of Supply-Side University
From: Jude Wanniski
Re: Ibn Khaldun, Part III

This is the third and last lesson drawn from Ibn Khaldun's history of philosophy
in the 14th century, the three-volume Muqadimmah. It originally ran in the fall
semester of 1998. You will notice political references to Newt Gingrich and Al
Gore that now seem dated, but that is because I decided the examples are still
good and work in context. This trio of lectures is meant to whet your appetite not
only for Khaldun, but also for the classical works of Plato and Aristotle. The
more things change, the more they stay the same. What I hope you can extract
out of these three guest lectures is an appreciation of the timelessness of
human society -- in its origins, development and goals. In Lesson #12
(November 26), Ibn Khaldun sketched out the origins of society, the whys and
hows. Lesson #14 (December 20) developed the concept of the leader/
sovereign and his assistants, the "bureaucracy." In this last part, Khaldun
discusses the signs of deterioration or decay of an empire, all valuable and
generally familiar. The most exciting and new to me is his discussion of the ideal
ruler and the importance of his gentleness.

Also bear in mind in reading this that it suggests ways in which the United States
might think of its responsibilities as the new global sovereign as we move by trial
and error toward a management of the new world order. What we experienced
in Seattle this past week [April ‘98], with demonstrations and rioting against the
World Trade Organization, should be understood as part of this trial and error
process. The established order has decided to transfer political power to an
international organization in a way that increases the power of the
establishment, but at the definite expense of ordinary people. What expense?
The one thing the masses have that is equal to all that of the individuals who
comprise the establishment is their electoral franchise, the vote. The masses
have fought for this power for millennia and those who complain in Seattle are
clearly unhappy at what they are being asked to give up. Ibn Khaldun would
probably agree with them.

Topics:

Use of Clients and Dependents



The Concentration of Authority Heralds the End of the State



Reform of Political Institutions



Territorial Limits of the State



The Ideal Ruler








Use of Clients and Dependents <back>

Know, then, that, as we said before, the instrument by which a ruler achieves
domination is his own people. For it is they who band about him and give him
support; they who help him put down rebellions; it is they whom he appoints as
ministers and entrusts with the collecting of revenue and the governing of
districts. For they are his helpers in victory and his partner in public matters,
sharing his work with him.

All this is true of the state in its first stage, as we said before; in the second
stage, however, when the king shows despotic inclinations, monopolizes glory,
and keeps his former associates away from it, they become in reality enemies of
his. In order, then, to keep them out of public affairs and to prevent their sharing
in his power, he has recourse to other, foreign, dependents on whom he can rely
for support. These foreigners therefore are nearer to him than are his own
people; it is they whom he keeps close to him and takes into his service; they on
whom he showers favours and honours; for they are ready to die for him and
help him keep his own people away from the posts which the latter once
occupied and from the positions they used to fill in the days when they had their
share of power. The ruler therefore honours and favours his foreign clients...and
chooses his minister, governors, generals, and financial agents from among
them. And it is they who constitute his closest dependents and his trustiest
advisers.

This change heralds the downfall of the state and is a symptom of the grave
disease from which it is suffering. For it marks the disappearance of that
solidarity which had secured domination; it also marks the hatred and enmity felt
for the king by the original conquerors, who now wait for an opportunity to get rid
of him, all of which causes grave harm to the state. This disease is incurable,
increasing with time until finally it brings the state to an end.

Consider, as an example, the Omayyad dynasty whose kings relied, for their
wars and administration, exclusively on Arabs, such as ‘Amr ibn Sa‘d....

[At the beginning of the Abbaside dynasty too the king’s helpers were also
chosen from among the Arabs.] When, however, the kings of that dynasty began
to concentrate power in their hands, they began to check the Arabs and to rely
on Persian ministers and helpers, such as the Barmecide family...and on
Turkish clients such as Bugha....

In short, the state soon comes to belong to others than those who founded it,
and power passes to others than those who first grasped it.

[Vol. I, p. 330]




The Concentration of Authority Heralds the End of the State <back>

Once the concentration of power in one person has been achieved and luxury
and inaction have spread, the state approaches its decay.

This is due to several causes:

First because of the concentration of power. For to the extent that glory is
equally shared by all the members of a group, they all strive equally for it and
make great efforts to overcome others and to defend what they have, spurred
on by a collective ambition and force. They all aim at power and find death
sweet in the pursuit of glory, and in truth would rather face annihilation than the
disruption of their group.

When, however, one man concentrates power in his hands, he tries to curb the
wills of the others and destroy their feeling of solidarity; moreover, he tends to
appropriate wealth, excluding them. As a result they become lazy and unwilling
to conquer, and soon get accustomed to humiliation and slavery. The second
generation is brought up in that atmosphere, regarding the king’s gifts to them
as rewards for the protection and help they give him, and unable to conceive of
any other state of affairs. And it becomes rare to find anyone hiring himself out
in a service which may lead to his death.

All this means a weakness in the state and a decrease in its power; for solidarity
is weakened by the loss of these virile qualities and the state approaches its
decay.

The second reason is that the establishment of a state leads to luxury, as we
said before, with an increase in wants and a resulting excess of expenditure
over receipts. The poorer among the people die off, while the richer spend all
they receive on luxuries. This goes on increasing with successive generations
until finally the whole income cannot meet the expenditure to which their habits
of luxury have accustomed them, and thus they fall in need. When the kings
demand that their subjects reduce their expenditure, in times of wars and
invasions, the latter are no longer able to do so; whereupon the kings punish
them and confiscate the wealth of many of them, keeping it for themselves or
giving it to their own families or officials. All of this weakens [the ruling group]
and consequently the power of the ruler himself.

Another possibility is that, as luxury increases and their [i.e., the ruling group]
income is unable to meet their expenditure, the king finds himself compelled to
increase the allowances he grants them, to enable them to balance their budget
and put themselves once more on a sound footing. Now the amount collected in
taxation is fixed, showing neither increase nor decrease; even should new taxes
be imposed, the increase would only be limited. If, therefore, the proceeds of
taxation are distributed in allowances, and the scale of allowances is raised,
because of the greater luxury and the increase in expenditure of the recipients,
the number of the armed forces must necessarily be cut down. When this
process goes on repeatedly the number of soldiers greatly diminishes, which
weakens the protection afforded by them, lowers the power of the state, and
emboldens its neighbours, or the tribes and bands in its territory, to rise against
it, until finally God decrees for it the extinction which is the lot of all his 
creatures.

Moreover, luxury corrupts morals, by inducing evil and depraved habits, as will
be mentioned in the chapter on civilization. The good qualities of people, which
were a sign of domination, now disappear and are replaced by contrary qualities
of evil, which herald decay. The state then begins to decay and totter; it is visited
by grievous and incurable diseases of old age; finally it passes away.

The third reason is that the nature of the state demands docility, as we
mentioned before. Now once men have accustomed themselves to docility and
inaction, these qualities develop into a second nature, as with all habits. The
younger generations [of the ruling group] are then brought up in luxury, ease and
inaction; the old habits acquired in their free life are shed, and forgotten the
nomadic ways which had secured for them dominion, such ways as firmness of
character, predatoriness and the capacity of going out and roaming in the
wilderness. In short, they become indistinguishable from the subject sedentary
masses except for their culture and insignia. Their power is weakened and their
value as soldiers decreased, all of which harms the state, causing it further to
decay. And so civilization increases and with it the habits of luxury, docility and
inaction, and the people move ever farther from nomadic roughness and forget
the courage they previously had, which enabled them to protect and defend
themselves, until they eventually become dependent upon some garrison [of
mercenaries], if they should have one. Consider only the history of those states
whose records are at hand and you will see the undoubted truth of what I have
told you.

And it may well happen, when this luxury and inaction and decay have come
about, that the ruler of the state may seek the support of hardy foreign soldiers,
who can show themselves more enduring in wartime and better able to bear
hunger and rough living. This may preserve the state from decay for a further
period of time, until God finally dooms it to extinction.

This is what happens in the Turkish kingdom of the East, most of its soldiers
being Turkish slaves. And the kings choose from these imported Mamelukes
both their horsemen and their foot soldiers, who show themselves hardier and
more enduring than the sons of the Mamelukes who were there before them,
and who have been brought up in luxury and the shadow of the sultan. This, too,
is the case in the kingdom of Al Muwahhidum, in North Africa, where the ruler
often chooses his soldiers from among the Zenata and Arabs, leaving out his
subjects who are used to luxury. And by this means the state may acquire a new
lease of life.

[Vol. I, p. 302]



Reform of Political Institutions <back>

....The ruler then begins to modify the regulations which have been followed up
till then in the military, financial, and provincial administrations. He thinks he can
regenerate the state by balancing the budget, reorganizing the army on a
sounder basis, reforming the provincial administration, and changing the basis
of taxation. With this object in view, he follows faithfully the methods and
ordinances which prevailed during the early years of the dynasty.

Yet in spite of all these changes the causes of the evil still persist, threatening
the state on all sides. The empire still has to face the same tribulations as before
and the ruler to fight against the same difficulties. He makes use of methods
which have been tried before, hoping thus to ward off an evil which keeps on
returning and threatening the integrity of the empire. Finally, he establishes a
new frontier less advanced than the preceding one. But the same disorders
which have marked the preceding reigns reappear.

All rulers who change the political regulations observed by their predecessors
may be said to found a new kingdom and establish a new empire....

[Vol. II, p. 115]



Territorial Limits of the State <back>

Each state has its apportioned share of territories which it cannot exceed. The
reason for this is that the state must distribute its troops and armed forces
among the kingdoms and frontier posts which have been conquered, in order to
protect these territories against the enemy, enforce the orders of the state, raise
taxes, awe the population, and so on. Once all the troops have been so
distributed and there are no reserves left, the state will have attained its limits;
should it then seek to expand further it cannot garrison the newly acquired
territories, which are liable to be seized by its enemies or neighbours with a
resulting loss of prestige which is harmful to the state. As long, however, as
there remain some troops which have not been distributed among the frontiers
and provinces, there remains in the state the power to seize what lies beyond its
frontiers, until it shall have attained its limits.

The natural explanation of that lies in the force of social solidarity, which is like
other natural forces; for every force gives rise to certain effects.

Now the state is stronger at the centre than at the periphery, weakening at the
borders and becoming inoperative outside them, like light rays and beams
radiating from a centre, or like circles spreading out on the surface of the water
from the point at which it has been impinged upon.

And when old age and weakness overtake a state it begins to contract at the
extremities, the centre remaining preserved until God decrees the total
extinction of the state, whereupon the centre, too, is wiped out. And should a
state be defeated at the centre it is of no avail to it that its provinces should
survive; it will surely be wiped out. For the centre is like the heart, from which the
soul is diffused, and once the heart is seized the extremities are soon
overpowered.

Consider the Persian Empire, whose capital was Ctesiphon; once Ctesiphon
had been captured by the Muslims the total power of the Persians was wiped
out; nor were the remaining outlying provinces of any use to Yazdegerd.

Consider, on the other hand, the Byzantine Empire whose capital was
Constantinople. When the Muslims defeated the Byzantines in Syria and
wrested the province from them, they retired unscathed to their capital. Their
empire continues at the centre until God shall have decreed its extinction.

Consider too, the Arabs at the beginnings of the Muslim conquest. Thanks to
their numerous troops they quickly overran Syria, Iraq, and Egypt and soon
overflowed into Scinde, Abyssinia, Tunisia, and Morocco, and then still further
into Spain. They were then dispersed, as garrisons, to the provinces and frontier
posts; as a result they had no further reserves and could not go outside their
limits. Nay the borders of the state began to contract, until God decreed its
extinction. And this was the fate, too, of the states that followed.

[Vol. I, p. 291]




The Ideal Ruler <back>

Know, then, that the use of the ruler to his subjects lies not in his person, his fine
figure or features, his wide knowledge, his excellent penmanship or the
sharpness of his intellect, but solely in his relationship to them. For kingship and
rule are relative terms, implying a certain relation between two objects: the ruler
being the possessor of his subjects and the manager of their affairs. The ruler
is, then, he who has subjects and the subjects are those who have a ruler, the
ruler’s relationship to his subjects being one of possession.

If this possession, and the consequences flowing from it, be excellent [i.e., if
proper use is made of it] the object of rulership is perfectly fulfilled. For if [the
power arising from] possession be applied in a just and beautiful way, the
interests of the subjects will be promoted; if on the other hand it is applied in an
evil and oppressive way, the subjects will suffer much harm and may even
perish.

Now the excellence of rulership arises out of gentleness. For if the king is harsh,
prone to inflict heavy punishments, always searching for the defects of his
subjects and enumerating their misdeeds, they will be seized by terror and
humiliation and will seek to protect themselves from him by lying, trickery and
deceit until these qualities become ingrained in them and ruin their character.
They may desert him in wartime, thus imperilling the country or else may
conspire to kill him, ruining the state and its defences. And if such a condition
should persist, their solidarity will be weakened and with it the very basis of
protection of the state.

Should the ruler however be gentle with his subjects and willing to overlook their
shortcomings, they will have confidence in him, rely on him for protection, love
him, and be prepared to fight unto the death against his enemies, thus bringing
about a general improvement in conditions.

As for the requirements of good rule, they are that the ruler defend his subjects
and be generous towards them. Defence is indeed the raison d’être of rulership,
while generosity is one aspect of the ruler’s gentleness towards his subjects and
one means by which he can increase their welfare; it is also one of the chief
ways of gaining their affection.

Now it is rare to find gentleness in men who have keen intelligence and
awareness; rather is it to be found among the duller people. For an intelligent
ruler is apt to impose upon the subjects more than they can bear, because he
sees further than they, and can, thanks to his intelligence, foresee the
consequences of any act or event; all of which spells ruin to the subjects. This is
why he [i.e., Mohammad], peace be upon him, said: "Follow the pace of the
weakest among you." This is why, also, the Lawgiver does not require excessive
intelligence [in a ruler]...for this may lead to oppression, misrule and the driving
of the people beyond what they are accustomed to, as will be shown at the end
of this book, and "God is the best of rulers."

[This is an extremely important insight, one I’ve never seen expressed as well as
it is here by Khaldun. The leader, by virtue of his superior wisdom, sits atop the
pyramid and from that point can see more of the surrounding terrain than any of
his people. He may know exactly the direction they should carry the pyramid
beneath him, but if he tries to move them faster than they are able to go, they
will rebel against him and cast him out of favor. The best, most recent example
is that of House Speaker Newt Gingrich following his ascent to the peak of
leadership in the Republican Party after it won control of Congress in 1994.
Determined to move the government as far and as fast as he could from his
legislative leadership position, Gingrich outran the ability of his followers to
follow, and the electorate turned to the "gentleness" of President Clinton for
protection. After he won re-election in 1972, Richard Nixon decided "no more
Mr. Nice Guy," and declared war on the federal bureaucracy. It was of course
his own palace guard that turned against him and the bureaucracy that fed his
adversaries in the press corps and Democratic Party. In the Islamic world, the
Shah of Iran clearly outran his people in 1978, and they ejected him in favor of
the Ayatollah Khomeini. This insight applies not only to governance of a nation,
but also to any pyramidical institutional hierarchy -- including families and
multinational corporations. JW]

It has thus been shown that intelligence and foresight are defects in a politician,
for they represent an excess of thought, just as stupidity is an excess of stolidity.
Now in all human qualities both extremes are reprehensible, the mean alone
being commendable: thus generosity is the mean between extravagance and
niggardliness, and courage between rashness and cowardice, and so on, for
other qualities. And that is why those who are extremely intelligent are described
as "devils" or "devilish" or something analogous. "And God creates what He
pleases and He is the all-knowing and all-powerful."

[Vol. I, p. 341]



* * * * *




Intelligence and foresight are defects in a politician. But not in a theoretician.
Sometime in the spring of 1980, a young reporter from Boston named Sidney
Blumenthal asked me who I thought was smarter, Jimmy Carter or Ronald
Reagan. I told him that Carter’s IQ was surely much higher than Reagan’s, but
that Reagan would make a better President. Both might confront an automobile
that would not run, I said. Carter could take the machine apart and put it
together blindfolded while Reagan would not know how to lift the hood. Reagan,
though, would more quickly check to discover that it was simply out of gas. After
the famous debate in 1996 between Jack Kemp and Al Gore, the opinion polls
showed Gore had easily won the debate. I told Kemp not to worry about it, that
Gore had studied debating at Oxford. More important was a secondary question
in the same opinion poll that said Kemp’s ideas were better than Gore’s. By the
same token, I could win a debate with Gore on almost any subject, but I’ve
always known I’d make a terrible politician, while Kemp is one of the best, in
Reagan’s league. I scarcely have the patience to be a political theologian. And
I’m awed by Ibn Khaldun, as I guess you can tell.



Today's Related Links:

Own this work of genius, The Muqadimmah or purchase Charles Issawi's
selections from the Prolegomena (Amazon).

"An American Empire," the U.S. as benevolent Global Sovereign(JW).

Read Plato, Aristotle, and other classic political theorists at MIT's Classics
Archive.

http://www.polyconomics.com/PrintPage.asp?TextID=2360
A<:>E<:>R
~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
Forwarded for your information.  The text and intent of the article
has to stand on its own merits.  Therefore, unless I am a first-hand
witness to any event described, I cannot attest to its validity.
~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
In accordance with Title 17 U.S.C. section 107, this material
is distributed without charge or profit to those who have
expressed a prior interest in receiving this type of information
for non-profit research and educational purposes only.
~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
"Do not believe in anything simply because you have heard it.
Do not believe simply because it has been handed down for
many generations.  Do not believe in anything simply because
it is spoken and rumoured by many.  Do not believe in anything
simply because it is written in Holy Scriptures.  Do not believe
in anything merely on the authority of teachers, elders or wise
men.  Believe only after careful observation and analysis, when
you find that it agrees with reason and is conducive to the good
and benefit of one and all.  Then accept it and live up to it."
The Buddha on Belief, from the Kalama Sutra

<A HREF="http://www.ctrl.org/";>www.ctrl.org</A>
DECLARATION & DISCLAIMER
==========
CTRL is a discussion & informational exchange list. Proselytizing propagandic
screeds are unwelcomed. Substance—not soap-boxing—please!  These are
sordid matters and 'conspiracy theory'—with its many half-truths, mis-
directions and outright frauds—is used politically by different groups with
major and minor effects spread throughout the spectrum of time and thought.
That being said, CTRLgives no endorsement to the validity of posts, and
always suggests to readers; be wary of what you read. CTRL gives no
credence to Holocaust denial and nazi's need not apply.

Let us please be civil and as always, Caveat Lector.
========================================================================
Archives Available at:
http://peach.ease.lsoft.com/archives/ctrl.html
 <A HREF="http://peach.ease.lsoft.com/archives/ctrl.html";>Archives of
[EMAIL PROTECTED]</A>

http:[EMAIL PROTECTED]/
 <A HREF="http:[EMAIL PROTECTED]/";>ctrl</A>
========================================================================
To subscribe to Conspiracy Theory Research List[CTRL] send email:
SUBSCRIBE CTRL [to:] [EMAIL PROTECTED]

To UNsubscribe to Conspiracy Theory Research List[CTRL] send email:
SIGNOFF CTRL [to:] [EMAIL PROTECTED]

Om

Reply via email to