-Caveat Lector-

from:
http://washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/articles/A52899-2000Nov9.html

Click Here: <A
HREF="http://washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/articles/A52899-2000Nov9.html">
Unlikely Alliance Helped Build Economic Boom (w…</A>
-----




Unlikely Alliance Helped Build Economic Boom

    Fed Chairman Alan Greenspan speaks as President Clinton looks on. (AP)





Printer-Friendly Version

By Bob Woodward

Sunday, November 12, 2000; Page W08



Federal Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan jumped at the invitation to visit the
man who would be the next president. Arkansas Gov. Bill Clinton had just won
the election in November 1992, and he wanted to reach out to the powerful Fed
chairman. So a month after the election Greenspan was asked to come to Little
Rock.

Greenspan, 66, had been chairman of the Fed for five years. A lifelong
Republican, he had first been appointed by President Reagan in 1987.
President Bush had reappointed him in 1991, even though Greenspan had had a
very uneasy and contentious relationship with Bush's economic advisers. The
chairman was determined to establish a good relationship with the new
president, though Clinton was a Democrat.

With a somewhat severe face, bespectacled, a bit hunched, narrow-eyed and
pensive, Greenspan radiated gloom. He spoke in a gravelly monotone, often
cloaking his thoughts in indirect constructions reflecting the economist's
"on the one hand, on the other hand." It was almost as if his words were
scouting parties, sent out less to convey than to probe and explore.

On December 3, Greenspan took a commercial flight to Little Rock to meet with
Clinton. As they talked alone in the governor's mansion, Greenspan found
himself quite taken with the new young leader. Clinton was totally focused,
as if he had no other care in the world and unlimited time. They ranged over
topics from foreign policy to education, and Greenspan saw that Clinton's
reputation as a policy junkie was richly deserved. The president-elect seemed
not only engaged but engrossed.

Greenspan saw an opening to give an economics lesson. The short-term interest
rates that the Fed controlled were at 3 percent, as low as they could
practically go in these economic conditions, he said. But the Fed could keep
them there.

The 10-year and longer rates were an unusual 3 to 4 percentage points higher
than the short-term rate, at about 7 percent. The gap between the short-term
rate and the long-term rate, Greenspan lectured, was an inflation premium
being paid for one simple reason: The lenders of long-term money expected the
federal deficit to continue to grow and explode. They had good reason, given
the double-digit inflation of the late 1970s and the expanding budget
deficits under Reagan. They demanded the premium because of the expectation
of new inflation. The dollars they had invested would, in the future, be
worth less and less.

Perhaps no single overall economic event could do more to help the economy,
businesses and society as a whole than a drop in long-term interest rates,
Greenspan said. The Fed didn't control them — the market did. But credible
action to reduce the federal deficit would force long-term interest rates to
drop, as the markets slowly moved away from the expectation of inflation, and
could trigger a series of payoffs for the economy.

Clinton was so sincere and attentive that Greenspan continued. He outlined a
blueprint for economic recovery. Lower long-term rates would galvanize demand
for new mortgages, refinancing at more favorable rates and more consumer
loans. This would in turn result in increased consumer spending, which would
expand the economy.

As long-term rates dropped, investors would get less return on bonds and move
into the stock market instead. The market would climb — an additional payoff.
The federal deficit was so high and cumulatively unstable, Greenspan said,
that increased government spending to increase jobs — in accordance with the
traditional Keynesian model — no longer worked. The economic growth from
deficit reduction could actually increase employment — a critical third
payoff.

Greenspan noted that the economy was rebounding from the brief recession of
1990-91, but there was no telling if it would last. As had happened in the
past, the recovering economy could fall on its face. Getting the long rates
down and keeping them down with a strong deficit-reduction program could
sustain and increase economic growth even more than the conservative
estimates that were circulating in the government or privately.

This conversation continued for 2 1/2 hours. Greenspan had not intended to
stay for lunch, but he did. From the beginning he sensed that Clinton was
different from the four Republican presidents Greenspan had seen up close —
Nixon, Ford, Reagan and Bush. The chairman left the meeting thinking, Either
this guy has a lot of the same views as I do, or he is the cleverest
chameleon I have ever run into.

On the five-hour trip back to Washington, Greenspan tried to assess what he
had observed. Clinton was what Greenspan termed an "intellectual pragmatist."
The term also applied to Greenspan himself. Clinton's campaign promises
included tax increases on the wealthy, a violation of Republican orthodoxy.
But increasing taxes reduced the federal deficit — and those deficits,
Greenspan thought, were such a threat to the future of the economy that it
might just be worth it to support Clinton's proposal.

One of the paradoxes, Greenspan realized, was that by running up the federal
budget deficits, Reagan had effectively borrowed from the period that was now
going to be the Clinton era. Clinton would have to pay it back by paying down
the deficit in some way. The irony was that Clinton probably wouldn't have
been elected if Reagan hadn't created the deficits.

Reagan had given Bill Clinton the opportunity to win the presidency, but he
had also bequeathed to the new president a major problem.







Greenspan's real connection to the new administration was Lloyd Bentsen, the
former Texas senator who was now Clinton's treasury secretary. They were
close friends and regularly played tennis together. Though a partisan
Democrat, Bentsen had been chairman of the powerful Senate Finance Committee
and was conservative on fiscal and money matters.

Bentsen arranged for Greenspan to see Clinton on Thursday, January 28, the
eighth day of the new administration. Greenspan told the president that it
would be dangerous not to confront the deficit very soon. The problem would
not make itself immediately apparent during the next several years, because
defense spending cuts would obscure the ballooning deficit. After 1996,
though, the data projections showed that the deficit and interest on the
federal debt would become explosive.

"You cannot procrastinate indefinitely on this issue," Greenspan warned.
Without action, he forecast "financial catastrophe."

Clinton made clear that he had received the message.

With Bentsen, Greenspan went further. He urged the new administration to set
ambitious deficit-reduction targets for the federal budget. On February 5,
the White House economic advisers sent Clinton a 15-page memo that summarized
budget options and Greenspan's analysis.

It read, in part: "Greenspan believes that a major deficit reduction (above
$130 billion) will lead to interest rate changes more than offsetting" the
contraction to the economy caused by less government spending. This meant
long-term rates would come down if the deficit reduction was sufficient to
have credibility in the financial markets.

On his copy, Bentsen had written with his lead pencil referring to Greenspan,
"He urges 140 or above," meaning Greenspan thought a $140 billion reduction
in the economic plan four years out (1997) would be more credible than $130
billion. It revealed their most private, confidential talks.

Bentsen urged the president to develop a personal relationship of trust with
Greenspan. He also emphasized to Clinton the importance of deficit reduction
as a catalyst for lower long-term interest rates.

In a sense, Bentsen and Greenspan were using each other. For Bentsen,
Greenspan's view on a specific deficit target was a potent weapon in the
Clinton administration deliberations. For Greenspan, a big reduction in the
federal deficit would make his job immensely easier, because lower deficits
would likely mean lower actual inflation.

Clinton adopted the $140 billion target for 1997.

When the president unveiled his economic plan at his first State of the Union
address to a joint session of Congress on February 17, 1993, Greenspan was
there in the gallery, in seat A6 — right between Hillary Clinton and Tipper
Gore, the vice president's wife, on full display as the national television
cameras swung over to get reaction. The first lady had invited him to sit in
her box for the speech, and Greenspan had accepted on the basis that protocol
dictated he not refuse.

As Clinton spoke, Greenspan applauded stiffly. He believed the White House
had given him enormous power, because if he chose to criticize the Clinton
economic plan, he could do substantial damage — even perhaps do it in. But
the large deficit- reduction portion was in part his own design, and he was
hardly going to shoot it down.

On February 19, in testimony before the Senate Banking Committee, Greenspan
said that the Clinton plan was "serious" and "credible," making headlines
with his support. Greenspan thought that Clinton had broken the gridlock on
dealing with the deficit. He couldn't say it publicly, but he believed the
president had displayed an element of political courage. He was taking a
stance that some in his own party would fight him on. In Greenspan's view,
Clinton deserved commendation if there was any justice in the crazy town of
Washington.

It had been a remarkable four months for Greenspan. His impact on the new
Democratic president was real and positive — a degree of influence he had not
begun to approach during the more than five years he had been chairman under
Reagan and Bush.

Within a week, long-term interest rates began to fall, and Clinton said in a
speech, "Just yesterday, due to increased confidence in the plan in the bond
market, long-term interest rates fell to a 16-year low." The yield on the
30-year Treasury bond had dropped below 7 percent.

Bentsen was delighted. He was all over Greenspan, peppering him with
questions about the chairman's forecast and projections for the bond market.
The long bond rate was the new talisman in the Clinton administration.







On May 18, 1993, Greenspan and the Federal Reserve Open Market Committee, the
key-interest-rate-setting body at the Fed, voted to "lean" toward higher
interest rates and gave the chairman the authority to raise rates by himself
before the next meeting. The vote — due to be made public six weeks after the
meeting — indicated that interest rate hikes were likely coming because the
economy was overheating and high growth was almost certain to trigger a new
round of inflation.

Six days later, the Wall Street Journal scooped everyone with a story
reporting that "Federal Reserve officials voted to lean toward higher
short-term interest rates." The New York Times wrote that the Clinton White
House "would view such action as a declaration of war. And it would probably
direct its heavy artillery at Mr. Greenspan."

Greenspan wanted to avoid war between the Fed and the White House at almost
any cost. He spoke with David Gergen, a longtime communications adviser to
Republican presidents Nixon and Reagan who had just joined the Clinton White
House staff in the same capacity. Greenspan had been friends with Gergen for
years, part of his Washington network. Gergen urged the chairman to give
Clinton a pep talk. Polls showed Clinton's approval rating at 36 percent, the
lowest of any new president in his first four months. Greenspan needed to
encourage Clinton to continue to push his deficit-reduction plan.

On Wednesday, June 9, Greenspan went to the White House to see the president.
The chairman was upbeat. The new consumer price index due out the next day
was expected to show an increase of only 0.1 percent, suggesting inflation
was in check, he said. They could feel some relief. The long-term economic
outlook was the best and most balanced in 40 years, he told the president. He
confirmed the authority his committee had given him to raise rates.

"If I have to do something, it will be very mild," he assured Clinton. A
small increase would signal to the markets that the Fed was on top of the
situation, and it was likely that the long-term rates would come down.

Several Democratic senators suggested publicly that Clinton drop his
five-year deficit target. This was precisely the wrong message, Greenspan
felt, and on July 20 he testified before the House Banking Committee with
unusual directness, "If you appear to be backing off, I think the markets
would react appropriately negatively."

Clinton's hands were effectively tied. He stuck with his deficit-reduction
plan, though Bentsen had to bat down an effort from populist advisers to trim
it some more.

In August, Clinton's deficit-reduction plan passed Congress by the narrowest
possible margins, 218 to 216 in the House, and 51 to 50 in the Senate, with
Vice President Gore breaking the tie. Not a single Republican had voted for
the plan, which cut $500 billion from the deficit over the next four years by
increasing taxes and cutting some federal spending. The only real Republican
support had come from Alan Greenspan.







For years there had been discussions in the media and elsewhere of the
possibility that the Fed could execute a so-called soft landing. That meant
the Fed would take preemptive action to increase interest rates months before
actual inflation showed up. This could take the top off any coming boom,
moderate and stabilize the economy and prevent inflation — and a recession.

Greenspan followed the discussion of this theory scrupulously. There was no
doubt that raising or lowering interest rates worked with a lag, having an
impact on the economy as much as a year or more later. Greenspan thought
there was persuasive evidence that the Fed needed to be ahead of the game.
Rates would have to be increased in anticipation of actual inflation. But
when? And by how much?

Earlier efforts at a soft landing had failed, including the Fed's effort in
1988. Still, Greenspan was willing to give it a try. If the soft landing
succeeded, he could see no downside for the economy. But if they failed, they
might hamper or even strangle the economic recovery. Because it was untested
and because it was not a concept rooted in economic theory, Greenspan
recognized that it was very risky. To him, it was like saying, Let's jump out
of this 60-story building and land on our feet.

Some signs of a major expansion in the economy became apparent to Greenspan
by early 1994. Lower interest rates had helped the banks make money and save
themselves from collapse. Credit was easing and businesses could get loans.
The system had been "liquefied," as he liked to say. High inflation could not
be detected, but he suspected it was around the corner. He was almost sure.

On January 21, 1994, Greenspan went to the White House to meet with President
Clinton and his economic advisers to warn them that rate increases were
likely. "We've got a dilemma, and you should understand," the chairman said.
"We haven't made a decision, but the choices are, we sit and wait and then
likely we'll have to raise short-term interest rates more. Or we could take
some small increases now."

"Obviously," the president said, "I want to keep interest rates low, but I
understand what you may have to do."

Bentsen saw that the president was reluctant. Clinton was swallowing about as
hard as he could.

"We've been flat so long," Greenspan said, referring to some 15 months of a 3
percent short-term interest rate. "We almost have to show that we can do
something, that we're willing to move."

"Wait a minute!" Vice President Gore interjected. "What about the possibility
that you introduce uncertainty?" Historically, the Fed moved in a series of
stair-step increases. Gore noted that in 1988-89 the Fed's short-term rate
increases had gone from about 6.5 percent up to nearly 10 percent in a dozen
small moves. With that expectation in the market, long-term rates could be
driven back up.

It was an interesting point, Greenspan said, but the long rates were high
because of the inflation expectation, which the administration was addressing
with its deficit-reduction plan. Even if long rates went up initially, he did
not think they would stay up.

Clinton and his advisers now had to face what potentially could be a profound
change in their relations with Greenspan. Politics was often a matter of
choosing sides. Which side was Greenspan on?

For that matter, it was difficult to determine exactly which side Clinton was
on. The president's economic policies were difficult to label. He tended to
talk liberal, especially as he pushed for his wife's health care reform,
which would extend universal health care insurance to more than 40 million
Americans. But his actions so far had been a blend.

The term Clinton liked was "New Democrat," meaning someone who was
pro-business but also concerned with the middle class and the poor.

But his policies also included the more visible deficit-reduction, bond ma
rket, free-trade Eisenhower Republicanism that was more in tune with
Greenspan than Clinton wanted to acknowledge.

The blend was embodied in Robert E. Rubin, the former head of Goldman, Sachs
& Co., the premier New York City investment banking firm, who was director of
the White House National Economic Council, the administration's coordinator
of economic policy.

Rubin had built a strong relationship with Clinton, and he reinforced
Greenspan's and Bentsen's arguments that the first order of economic business
had to be deficit reduction. Now, with interest rate hikes coming, Rubin
urged Clinton to hold off on any public criticism of the Fed. Criticism
simply would not be effective. The Fed considered itself almost religiously
independent, and any effort to influence it would be counterproductive.

Bentsen argued in turn to the president that it was better for the Fed to
move now, in 1994. Given the one-year lag in the impact, any economic
slowdown would occur in 1995, with a pickup in 1996. If the Fed waited and
raised rates in 1995, the slowdown would be in . . . Before Bentsen could get
"1996" out of his mouth, the president had grasped the point.

Greenspan himself was certain that if they did not raise rates, history and
experience dictated that at some point in 1995-96 there would be a recession.
That Clinton would be running for reelection in 1996 obviously made it easier
for Greenspan to sell an attempted soft landing. He would be taking economic
growth from 1994 — lopping off the top of an expected boom of excessive
growth — and saving it for 1995 and 1996. That is, if it worked.


Making it work had a lot to do with timing, which in turn had to do with
economic forecasting, an imprecise science that did not approach the
mathematical certainty Greenspan loved. There was no alternative to
forecasting. It wasn't guessing or fortune-telling, but the forecasters,
including himself, were going to be wrong some of the time.

On February 4, 1994, the Fed's key interest-rate-setting committee voted to
raise rates by a quarter percent. It was the first rate increase in five
years, and for the first time in history the Fed publicly announced the
increase. That day, the Dow Jones industrial average dropped nearly 100
points, to 3871, the largest single-day loss in two years. Over the next four
months, the Fed raised rates another full 1 percent.

At the White House, the president was increasingly restless. Was this
necessary? Was Greenspan going too far? Did he know what he was doing?

Rubin and Bentsen insisted everything was okay.

Clinton grew angrier and angrier. When he blew up about rising interest
rates, as he frequently did, the members of his economic team let him blow
off steam and then urged him to continue to confine his distress to the
privacy of the Oval Office. Any reasonable Fed was going to have to pull the
foot off the accelerator, they told him. The low short-term interest rate,
the so-called fed funds rate, had been pumping up the economy, so interest
rates were going to have to go up to cool things off. All the economic models
built on years of history showed there was a limit to how high growth could
go without triggering inflation. To complicate matters, the economists
believed — and recent American economic history showed — that there was a
level of so-called full employment. If unemployment dipped much below 6
percent, the pressure for wage increases would trigger inflation.

The president was skeptical and even outraged. So the problems were too much
economic growth and too many people working! It was ridiculous, he seethed.

Once, when Greenspan had an appointment to see the president, Clinton and his
economic team were assembled in the Oval Office. As they waited for Greenspan
to arrive, the president had launched into a comedic imitation of the
chairman. Speaking in a gloomy, deep voice, he mimicked Greenspan drumming on
inflation. Inflation! Inflation was all-important. Inflation was the center
of the universe. Inflation! Inflation! It was a pretty good caricature, and
his advisers were in stitches. One checked nervously to make sure the
soundproof Oval Office doors were shut tight so the chairman wouldn't hear.

Now there were no jokes coming out of the Oval Office about Greenspan.

Worse, the bond market had gone to hell. The long-term rates were shooting
up, nullifying the gains from the 1993 deficit-reduction plan. Where was the
payoff? the president wanted to know.







The Fed continued to raise rates into February 1995, taking the Fed's key
interest rate from 3 percent up to 6 percent in less than a year. By the
summer of 1995, the economy showed clear signs of slowing. Growth was
hovering at an anemic 2 percent.

On Sunday, June 11, White House Chief of Staff Leon Panetta was on "Meet the
Press" and was asked if the Fed should reduce interest rates. "Well," Panetta
said, "it would be nice to get whatever kind of cooperation we can get to get
this economy going."

Asked if he was jawboning the Fed to get rates lower, Panetta replied with
his overeager grin, "Is that what it's called?"

Bob Rubin, who had moved from the White House to become treasury secretary in
early 1995, was furious. The administration had been so disciplined, avoiding
any public or even private effort to pressure Greenspan. The soft landing
would occur because the administration and Greenspan didn't let the economy
get out of control. It wasn't science, Rubin knew, but he believed Greenspan
was making a series of highly informed judgments — the best they had. White
House pressure to cut rates could actually prevent a rate cut.

Rubin immediately went public with a rebuke for Panetta and an assurance,
almost an apology, to Greenspan. Of Panetta, Rubin said in a public
statement, "I can assure you that his comments were not intended to signal
any shift. Our policy with regard to the Federal Reserve has been consistent
from the beginning of the Administration — and that is not to comment."

President Clinton seemed to agree with Rubin. It appeared that Panetta was
briefly put in the doghouse — an unusual place for the White House chief of
staff, who was supposed to be managing the executive branch on behalf of the
president. Rubin and others knew that a side of Clinton agreed with Panetta,
but in terms of politics and public perception, Clinton's relationship with
Greenspan and the Fed were more important than his relationship with his
chief of staff.

Greenspan took Panetta's comments as a cheap and ineffective hit. Rubin had
it right, not because of their growing friendship but because Rubin saw it
was in the president's self-interest to avoid political meddling with the
Fed. What was interesting, Greenspan realized, was that his relations with
the administration were so good that the White House was more concerned about
the perception of Panetta's comments than Greenspan was himself.







Now Greenspan had a chance to practice some of his fine-tuning. Having
doubled short-term interest rates from 3 to 6 percent during 1994 and early
1995, he realized that he might have slightly overshot. To bring the economy
in for the soft landing now required a slight easing. On Thursday, July 6,
1995, Greenspan proposed a rate cut of a quarter percent. It was the first
decrease in nearly three years and the first rate cut during the Clinton
administration.

The chairman had been telling himself that he should not expect reappointment
to another four-year term. After all, he had been appointed to the job twice
by Republican presidents — Reagan in 1987 and Bush in 1991. A Democratic
president would want to choose his own chairman. If Greenspan were president,
he would want to choose his own person. It wasn't plausible that Greenspan
was going to get another chance.

By November 1995, no one at the White House had brought up his reappointment
in their frequent conversations with him. And, of course, Greenspan had not
brought it up. His term was due to expire in five months.

In the meantime, as he had from the start, the chairman worked the Washington
network — parties, private lunches and dinners, tennis matches, a steady
stream of private, off-the-record gossip, chat and court intrigue. When the
subject of his future came up, Greenspan would adopt a stance of studied
nonchalance. He would have had eight good years. If Clinton reappointed him,
he would accept. If not, that, too, would be okay. He worked at showing
neither anxiety nor pain. He wanted that to be clear. He shrugged. He smiled.
But the message was clear: He was available.

By the end of 1995, Greenspan had the economy right where he wanted it.
Inflation was low, at less than 3 percent for the year.

Unemployment was also low, steady in the 5 1/2-percent range, with the
addition of 1.8 million jobs for the year. After 3 1/2-percent growth the
previous year, the annual growth was down in the range of 1 1/2 percent.
There had been no recession. Greenspan had delivered. The economic analysis
he had given Clinton in December 1992 was turning out to be correct. The
payoffs he had anticipated were evident. By keeping inflation low and cutting
the federal deficit, the intermediate- and long-term interest rates — the key
rates for businesses, home buyers and consumers — were 2 to 21/2 percent
below their levels at the beginning of 1995. Bond prices, which move the
opposite direction as interest rates, were up substantially, and the stock
market was up about 35 percent with the Dow at 5117 — its best year in two
decades.

He was available.

Rubin never considered it a real question. Reappointing Greenspan was a
no-brainer. Rubin and Greenspan both attended a weekend meeting of the Group
of Seven major economic powers in Paris in January 1996, and the two had a
chance to speak privately. Taking advantage of a quiet moment, they walked
together toward a series of large plate glass windows at one end of the room,
with a view of Paris before them. The two men had established a feeling of
trust. For Greenspan, such friendship, closeness and agreement gave him a
sense that they were working for the same firm. Greenspan had once remarked
privately, and only half-jokingly, that he considered Rubin the best
Republican treasury secretary ever, though he was a Democrat.

"When you get back," Rubin said, "the president's going to want to talk to
you."

Greenspan could tell by the body language that it was all favorable.

"The president's quite pleased with what you've been doing," Rubin said.

The implausible had become plausible. Greenspan realized it was the soft
landing that made his reappointment possible. He knew he had helped hand
Clinton what the chairman called "a pro-incumbent type economy." Most
important, there had been no recession.

Clinton understood the power of the economy in a presidential election. The
1990-91 recession — and the economic doldrums and pessimism of 1992 — had
been the foundation of his first presidential campaign. The campaign's
memorable slogan, "It's the Economy, Stupid," devised by political strategist
James Carville, contained a pledge that Clinton would be engaged and in touch
with the forces that affected people's daily lives. The last three presidents
to lose-Ford, Carter and Bush-had failed in part because they had been
perceived to have mismanaged the economy.

On February 22, 1996, Clinton announced that he was reappointing Greenspan to
a third term. "He brings his years of experience as a prominent economist,"
Clinton said, "and, I might add, a leading Republican."







Clinton went on to win reelection, partly due to the sound economy. For the
next two years, Greenspan resisted sustained pressure from within and outside
the Fed to raise rates, increasing them only once, in March 1997, and only by
a quarter percent.

On Tuesday, May 5, 1998, Greenspan went to the Oval Office to see the
president. It was the fourth month of Whitewater independent counsel Kenneth
Starr's investigation of Clinton's relationship with former White House
intern Monica Lewinsky. There was a sense that investigators were closing in.

Greenspan had not visited the president formally for 16 months, and Clinton's
economic team wanted Clinton to bask a little in the positive domestic
economic news. In any case, an hour with Greenspan was always educational and
worthwhile, and on this occasion it would be a momentary diversion from the
president's mounting personal and legal troubles.

"This is the best economy I've ever seen in 50 years of studying it every
day," Greenspan told Clinton. There had been a boom in productive capital.
Money that businesses were spending was yielding an extraordinary return
because of increased worker productivity. The computer and high technology
investments were paying off. And those payoffs had to be real, because the
higher profits and economic growth had continued for several years now.

Greenspan said that the stock market was very high by historical standards,
but it could stay high. Despite his statements about "irrational exuberance"
18 months earlier, the chairman said, it was basically an illusion to think
that the Fed could tinker with the stock market.







In June 1999 Greenspan passed word to Rubin that a rate increase would soon
be necessary because the economy was overheating. Rubin had no real problem.

The president was not as confident. Did this have to happen? Clinton asked
his economic team. I don't see any signs of inflation, he added, asking the
same questions he had posed in 1994 when Greenspan was raising rates. Was
this another preemptive stranglehold on the economy? he asked, echoing some
liberal Democratic senators who had been his most vocal defenders during his
impeachment trial, in which he had been acquitted.

The president's advisers defended Greenspan's decision. Mr. President, said
National Economic Council Director Gene Sperling, he is just putting his foot
on the brake a little. This is good. It will keep the expansion going longer.
The risk of inflation with unemployment at 4.2 percent was too great.

Frankly, the president's advisers explained, Greenspan was on the softer side
of the Fed's key interest rate committee, a little to the left even of the
people that the president had appointed. Clinton's private objections were
muted, not as intense or as deep as they had been in 1994.







"I bet he'll stay there until they carry him out," President Clinton joked to
his economic advisers at the end of 1999, as they discussed a fourth term for
Greenspan. Larry Summers, who had taken over as treasury secretary from Rubin
that summer, recommended reappointing the Fed chairman. He and Sperling had
already sounded Rubin out as a courtesy, to see if he wanted the Fed job. But
Rubin had declined, saying, "Alan's perfect for this."

White House Chief of Staff John Podesta got permission from Clinton to call
Greenspan and offer the reappointment on behalf of the president. Greenspan
accepted.

At 73, the chairman found that his mind still functioned well. He figured he
would know he was losing it when he started to have difficulty with
mathematical relationships, and he was aware of no diminution of that mental
capacity. He was fully engaged. His only problem was that occasionally he
couldn't remember people's names.

The White House set early January 2000 for the announcement, wanting to make
the timing a surprise before Congress returned from recess. That way, Clinton
could give his annual State of the Union address later in January and fully
embrace the good economy and Greenspan, leaving no doubt about the chairman's
future role. In February, the American economy would officially have enjoyed
the longest economic expansion in its history. The White House wanted the
Clinton-Greenspan team to be part of the celebration.

Greenspan arrived at the executive mansion on January 4. Clinton, Summers,
Sperling and Council of Economic Advisers Chairman Martin N. Baily gathered
around the dining room table next to the Oval Office with Greenspan. Podesta
sat in a chair off to the side.

Clinton and Greenspan were almost glowing at each other, odd partners sitting
there around the polished wood table, linked surprisingly to each other's
greatest successes, wrapping themselves in each other's legacy.

"You know," the president said, addressing Greenspan to his immediate left,
"I have to congratulate you. You've done a great job in a period when there
was no rule book to look to."

"Mr. President," Greenspan replied, "I couldn't have done it without what you
did on deficit reduction. If you had not turned the fiscal situation around,
we couldn't have had the kind of monetary policy we've had."

"After doing so well," Clinton said, "no one would blame you for wanting to
go out now on top."

"Oh, no," Greenspan said, "this is the greatest job in the world. It's like
eating peanuts. You keep doing it, keep doing it, and you never get tired."

Clinton folded his arms, tightened his body over his crossed legs and glanced
over as if to say, I know what you mean. He seemed wistful.

The irony was palpable. Greenspan, at 73, had already served 12 years and
would get to be chairman for another four years. Clinton, 53, had served
seven years as president, and had only another year. The Constitution barred
him from seeking a third term. The younger man would have to leave office and
re-create himself, while the man 20 years older would go on.

Who would have thought, seven years before at their first meeting in Little
Rock, that such economic conditions were even possible — steady growth, low
inflation, unemployment hovering at an unheard-of 4 percent and the Dow above
11,000. More than 20 million new jobs had been created since Clinton took
office. Some economists would have put the odds of that at 1 in a million.
Greenspan, ever a stickler about probability, couldn't even calculate it.

Of all the important people in Clinton's life, nearly all — including himself
— had let him down, or not lived up to their full promise. Hillary had failed
to deliver on health care, although she had stood by him during the Lewinsky
scandal. Vice President Gore, though loyal, had not yet emerged as a vibrant
successor. Dick Morris, the chief political strategist for the successful
1996 reelection campaign, had been forced out in a scandal and then turned on
Clinton and written an informative-but-tattletale book. George
Stephanopoulos, Clinton's young and trusted adviser, had also written a book
full of inside stories of anguished decision-making and private fury.
Democratic leaders in the Senate and House had come and gone. Staff had come
and gone. Rubin, the shinning light of the Cabinet, was gone. Clinton's
vaunted campaign fundraisers had brought scandal and doubt on the presidency.
Clinton himself had not lived up to his own grand governing vision.

Greenspan alone had stood and improved his ground.

In the Oval Office, Clinton announced Greenspan's reappointment to a fourth
term. He would serve as Fed chairman until 2004. The two men showered each
other with praise. Clinton said Greenspan's willingness to stay in the job s
hould be "a cause of celebration in this country and around the world."

Greenspan, in turn, gave Clinton the highest endorsement a Republican Fed
chairman could offer a Democratic president. "And I must say you have been a
good friend to America's central bank. Thank you, sir."

© 2000 The Washington Post Company
-----
Aloha, He'Ping,
Om, Shalom, Salaam.
Em Hotep, Peace Be,
All My Relations.
Omnia Bona Bonis,
Adieu, Adios, Aloha.
Amen.
Roads End

<A HREF="http://www.ctrl.org/">www.ctrl.org</A>
DECLARATION & DISCLAIMER
==========
CTRL is a discussion & informational exchange list. Proselytizing propagandic
screeds are unwelcomed. Substance—not soap-boxing—please!  These are
sordid matters and 'conspiracy theory'—with its many half-truths, mis-
directions and outright frauds—is used politically by different groups with
major and minor effects spread throughout the spectrum of time and thought.
That being said, CTRLgives no endorsement to the validity of posts, and
always suggests to readers; be wary of what you read. CTRL gives no
credence to Holocaust denial and nazi's need not apply.

Let us please be civil and as always, Caveat Lector.
========================================================================
Archives Available at:
http://peach.ease.lsoft.com/archives/ctrl.html
 <A HREF="http://peach.ease.lsoft.com/archives/ctrl.html">Archives of
[EMAIL PROTECTED]</A>

http:[EMAIL PROTECTED]/
 <A HREF="http:[EMAIL PROTECTED]/">ctrl</A>
========================================================================
To subscribe to Conspiracy Theory Research List[CTRL] send email:
SUBSCRIBE CTRL [to:] [EMAIL PROTECTED]

To UNsubscribe to Conspiracy Theory Research List[CTRL] send email:
SIGNOFF CTRL [to:] [EMAIL PROTECTED]

Om

Reply via email to