http://www.geocities.com/CollegePark/Center/9898/renref/chapter11.html
***
Accompanying the changes in commerce, industry, and agriculture and to some
extent making them possible was the continued growth of banking and finance.
The greatest financial power of the sixteenth century was the house of
Fugger in Augsburg. The history of its rise is in itself a sort of synopsis
of the development of the European economy.

The founder of the family fortunes was Hans Fugger, a weaver, who, in about
1380 came to Augsburg from the countryside, where he had probably worked
under the domestic system for an Augsburg merchant engaged in international
trade. In the city, he expanded his activities, importing cotton and selling
cloth made by himself and by other weavers. Soon he began to trade in other
wares, and the business was continued by his descendants. They dealt in
fruits, spices, and jewels as well as textiles, and they became involved in
dealings with the Hapsburgs and with the papacy.

The greatest of the Fugger’s was Jacob Fugger II, called Jacob Fugger the
Rich (14591525). Though the business was already prospering when he took it
over, he greatly expanded it. From 1511 to 1527, under his direction, the
capital of the business rose tenfold (from 196,791 gulden to 2,021,202). The
greatest of Jacobs interests was mining. The family had become involved in
this field as early as 1481, when in return for a loan to a member of the
Hapsburg family, they received mining rights in the Tyrol. The mining
activities of the Fuggers increased in the time of Jacob, who profited in
this respect from the favor shown him by Emperor Maximilian I. He enjoyed
important rights in the silver and copper mines of the Tyrol, the chief
source of these metals before the opening up of the mines in the New World.

The Fuggers also acquired complete control of the copper production of
Hungary. In addition to the mines, they owned the plants that processed the
ore, and employed hundreds of workers. Jacob Fugger attempted, though unsucc
essfully, to achieve a world monopoly in copper and to use his monopoly to
keep prices high.

He was a Catholic, as a young man he had planned for a while to be a priest,
and did much business with the papacy. He completely controlled the
financial relationships of the pope with Germany; this included a monopoly
on sending to Rome the proceeds from indulgences. In this way the activities
of the Fugger’s were at least indirectly connected with the early career of
Martin Luther. Because of his importance to the papacy, Jacob was able to
influence the appointment of bishops.

With his far-flung interests, it was necessary for him to be informed of
events throughout Europe. He had agents in all the main business centers who
supplied him with a constant flow of information, which has been compared to
a press service.

Contemporaries, aware of his wealth and power, were frequently opposed to
him. There was a great deal of public sentiment that would have supported
legal restraints against the power of the great merchants, but Jacob Fugger
was protected by the favor of Charles V, to whom he was very valuable, even
indispensable.

It was his relationship with Charles that involved Fugger in the most famous
event of his career. When Charles became a candidate for the throne of the
Holy Roman Empire upon the death of Maximilian I in 1519, he borrowed a
great deal of money from the Fugger bank in order to influence the electors
in his favor. It was generally believed that these loans were responsible
for his success in being chosen emperor. This is shown in an extraordinary
letter of 1523 from Fugger to the emperor, in an attempt to collect the
money Charles owed him. In the letter Fugger plainly states that without his
help, Charles might not have been elected.

As security for the loan, and for later loans to the emperor, Fugger
received some of the revenues of the Spanish crown. Three great Spanish
religious orders were under the control of the king, and for over a century
the house of Fugger controlled the income from their property, which
included large agricultural holdings and mercury mines.

Under Jacobs nephew Anton the firm reached its height, with a capital of
about five million gulden by 1546. However, the connection with the
Hapsburgs proved fatal in the end to the prosperity of the house. Later in
the century and in the succeeding one, the Hapsburgs were unable to meet
their obligations, and most of the firms money was lost. Yet the career of
the family, and especially of Jacob Fugger, clearly indicates that the power
of capital was making itself felt. In some ways, Jacob was the most powerful
man of his time.

The career of Jacob Fugger also set in relief the importance of political
factors, especially the state, in the economic life in the sixteenth
century. As the national state was asserting its involvement in, and control
of, numerous fields of human endeavor, its activities more and more affected
economic activities as the governments sought, wisely or otherwise, to
direct economic life for the increase of national strength.

The emerging nations suffered under handicaps in managing economic policy.
One of these lay in the fact that their financial needs had outgrown their
ability to meet them; that is, a system of raising money that had been
devised to meet the needs of a more or less decentralized feudal society was
inadequate for the expanded requirements of the larger and more concentrated
units of political power that were now becoming dominant. This problem was
aggravated by the general ignorance of economics and public finance.

These factors combined to bring about such expedients as debasing the
coinage, which proved to be harmful to the economies of the countries
concerned. During the Hundred Years War, the French crown had resorted on
numerous occasions to this practice. In sixteenth-century England, Henry
VIII did the same thing, and it was not until the reign of Elizabeth I in
the second half of the century that the coinage value was restored. Such a
policy militated against a country’s prosperity; in the case of England it
helps to explain why, in spite of encouraging developments in trade,
industry, and agriculture, the country suffered from more or less depressed
economic conditions for much of the century.

Perhaps the most obvious way in which political events affected the economy
was through war. The wars of the sixteenth century, as will be seen in
subsequent chapters, were frequent; international conflict and civil
struggle fill the history of the period and had a tremendously destructive
effect. A few examples will illustrate the point. The Sack of Rome in 1527
and the Sack of Antwerpo, the Spanish Fury of 1576 were terrible blows to
the cities affected. Antwerpo had been one of the greatest centers of trade
and finance; indeed, it had stood as the key city in the European economy.
After the Sack of 1576 although there were additional factors it never
regained its former position.

Similarly, the wars of Charles V and Philip II of Spain, although they were
not fought on Spanish territory, were financed largely by Spanish, and in
particular by Castilian, resources. They had the effect, again combined with
other factors, of directing the resources of Spain to unproductive uses, of
stifling the development of the economy, and of preventing prosperity. The
decline of Spain from its status as one of the great European powers, a
decline from which it has never recovered, was the result of this as much as
of any one factor.

Those countries that enjoyed an abundance of resources and basic economic
strength recovered from the damage done by war. The revolt of the
Netherlands was costly to Spain and to that part of the Low Countries that
remained under Spanish control, but the new nation of the United Netherlands
or Dutch republic went on to become one of the most prosperous of the
European states in the next century. The French Wars of Religion were among
the most terrible of the century because they were primarily civil wars, and
they caused great devastation; but France was, nevertheless, to become in
the seventeenth century the dominant power in Europe.

In a general sense, the growth of the nation-state, with increasingly
unified control over a territory larger than that of earlier political
units, responded well to the needs of the expanding economy and formed
mutual alliances between monarchs and merchants. Rulers and businessmen had
a common interest in peace and security, in breaking down local and regional
restraints on the movement of goods, and in subduing the nobility. It may be
said that kings identified themselves socially with the nobles, since they
were of the same class; and that the wealth of the great nobility depended
largely on the favor of their rulers, who often endowed them with rich
estates to enable them to maintain their social prominence. At the same
time, when it came to political power, monarchs quite often took care to
keep their greatest nobles out of positions of power and to choose as their
closest advisers men of undistinguished origin whose position depended
entirely on royal favor.

For example, two of the most important advisers of Henry VIII of England
were Thomas Wolsey, son of a butcher and innkeeper, and Thomas Cromwell,
whose father was a brewer, blacksmith, and fuller. Philip II of Spain
followed the policy of using great nobles for positions that took them out
of the country, preferring to appoint professional men and priests to
positions of importance nearer home. Philips father, Charles V, had relied
for many years on a man of humble origin, Francisco de los Cobos, as the
chief figure in the Spanish administration. In France, where the old
nobilitynoblesse dá‚ápá‚áe (the nobility of the sword)did remain important,
it was supplemented by the noblesse d’robe (nobility of the robe) men of
middle-class extraction who owed their noble status to judicial office. In
England, the gentry, a class of non-noble landowners, was becoming dominant
in the nations affairs; one sign of their increasing importance is found in
the fact that members of this class formed the great majority of the House
of Commons.

What the members of the non-noble business, professional, and landholding
classes had to offer their rulers was not only loyalty and service but also
money. Methods of acquiring money available to the monarchs of the time were
primitive. Taxation was in its infancy and was not yet regarded as the chief
way to acquire funds for the conduct of public business. In England the
monarch was expected to live of his own that is, to meet expenses with such
resources as the income of crown lands and the receipts from customs duties.
In time of war or other critical situations, Parliament might be induced to
grant taxes, but there was a limit to its willingness to part with money. In
France, the taille, a combined income and property tax, was levied
throughout the country, but the rate varied. In the more recently acquired
provinces, where representative bodiesb – estates still existed, these
estates served as a means of protecting the inhabitants of their provinces
against excessive royal demands, and the taille had to be negotiated
annually between the royal officials and the estates. Where the estates no
longer survived, the taille was levied directly on the defenseless
inhabitants, and the rate was higher.

Fiscal burdens were often unequally distributed. In France, the First and
Second Estates – clergy and nobility respectively were privileged classes,
which means that they were exempt from many of the payments required of the
bulk of the population. The French church sometimes granted the king a free
gift, which was a good deal less than it would have paid if the wealth of
the church had been taxed at the rate levied on the unprivileged. In
Castile, which supplied the bulk of the revenues of the king of Spain, the
nobles and clergy achieved the goal of exemption from taxes in the reign of
Charles V, and stopped attending the Cortes the representative assembly so
that only delegates from the towns continued to be present at meetings.
Deprived of the support of the other classes, these townsmen were not strong
enough to put up a successful resistance to the steady growth of royal
power.

Thus tax systems were defective for various reasons. Another problem that
arose in connection with raising taxes was that much of the revenue tended
to remain in the pockets of officials engaged in the collection process. One
of the reforms of Sully, the finance minister of Henry IV of France at the
end of the sixteenth century, was to take measures that would suppress this
sort of speculation and bring the royal revenue to the royal treasury.

There were consequently numerous reasons why the tax structures of the
European states failed to meet their expanding needs and why various other
expedients, generally unhealthy, were tried. Reference has already been made
to the debasement of coinage. Another was the sale of titles of nobility. A
good or bad example of the results of this practice is found in the
experience of France, where the sale of titles came in the sixteenth century
to be carried on extensively. For centuries thereafter, individuals of the
middle class who had succeeded financially sought to rise socially by buying
their way into the aristocracy. This was fiscally disadvantageous in the
long run, because elevation into the privileged ranks of the nobility also
meant a large degree of exemption from taxation. In this way, many persons
who were especially well qualified to contribute to the financial support of
the state were relieved of the necessity of carrying their fair share of the
burden.

Not only titles but also offices were sold. Here again the case of France is
especially instructive. It was customary by the sixteenth century for
judicial offices not only to be sold, but also to be passed down from
generation to generation in the same family. In 1604 this practice received
official status when a tax, called the Paulene, was imposed at the time an
office was transferred. Thereafter an annual fee was paid that made the
office virtually the property of its holder. Interestingly enough, this did
not create a body of mediocrities holding positions for which they were not
fitted because the jobs had become family possessions. On the contrary,
there came to exist distinguished legal families, proud of their status,
competent, and conscientious in carrying out their professional and official
duties. Nevertheless, the practice of selling offices came in time to create
a vast body of functionaries with overlapping positions, who had bought
their posts and intended to recoup their investments at the expense of the
citizenry. This oversized bureaucracy also came to hamper the crown and
complicate the problem of efficient government.

Some taxes in France were farmed; that is, the right to collect them was
sold to corporations of tax-farmers at a fixed sum. The tax-farmers, having
bought the privilege of collecting the tax, were primarily interested in
making a profit, and they were pretty much given a free rein in doing so. In
fact, the coercive force of the state was at their disposal in dealing with
recalcitrant taxpayers. These tax-farmers were often guilty of extortionate
practices in squeezing money from the hapless French taxpayer, who, it must
always be remembered, was a peasant or a town dweller of either the working
class or middle class, unprotected by noble or clerical status.

We have had occasion to note that governmental officials and functionaries
quite generally managed to acquire for themselves some of the funds that
should have gone into the public treasury. This sort of corruption, or
graft, was so widespread that it is almost unfair to refer to it in such
unflattering terms. Public officials, at least in some cases, were more or
less expected to reward themselves from pubic funds. Cardinal Wolsey, a man
of modest origin as we have seen, acquired wealth of vast proportions; the
magnificence with which he surrounded himself excited the envy of the great
nobles of England, and he even ventured, very imprudently, to rival the king
himself in the lavishness of his entertainments and banquets. In the
following century, Cardinal Richelieu, whose family was not a wealthy one,
left so large an estate at his death in 1642 that his will was several pages
long. Indeed, Thomas More and Niccola Machiavelli, so different from one
another in many respects, were alike in that they could both truly assert
that they had not profited financially by holding public office; each seems
to have realized that he was different from his contemporaries in this way.

In the field of commerce, governments were involved from a number of angles.
Customs duties, on both imports and exports, were used both to regulate
trade and to add to revenues. Organizations of merchants were encouraged by
governments, and officials of government often associated themselves with
mercantile enterprises by investing in them. The companies that were being
formed to open up and carry on trade in the newly discovered parts of the
world received charters from their governments that assured them of
monopolies on the trade of specific areas. In England a number of companies
of this nature were formed during the sixteenth century. The Cathay Company,
chartered in 1576 for the Chinese trade, failed. Others were more
successful: the Muscovy Company (1555) for the trade with Russia; the
Eastland Company (1579) for the Scandinavian and Baltic trade; the Turkey
Company (1581), later known as the Levant Company; and, most famous of all,
the English East India Company, chartered in 1600, which was to have a long
and amazing career. The new Dutch republic formed its own East India Company
in 1602. Numerous other companies were chartered by these governments and
others for a long time to come and enjoyed varying degrees of success.

The companies were formed on the joint-stock principle, which had been
familiar in Italy for centuries, but which was adopted in northern Europe in
the sixteenth century. By this arrangement, ownership was divided into
shares of stock, which could be purchased in small or large quantities. Each
individual shareholder was an owner of the company in proportion to the
number of shares he held. The shareholders chose the officers and directors
of the company who carried on business on behalf of the membership. This
form of organization had numerous advantages over earlier ones. It made it
possible for a larger number of persons to participate in mercantile
enterprise, including many who could never have done so on their own; it
facilitated the accumulation of large quantities of capital; and it lessened
individual risk. In the older partnership form of organization, each partner
had unlimited liability for the losses and debts of the firm.

In seeking out and exploiting trade opportunities, joint-stock companies did
important work in exploring new lands and sometimes in the fields of
conquest, settlement, and government. Students of the history of the United
States and of India will be familiar with this fact.

By the sixteenth century, it may be said that a European economy had emerged
in which the various parts of Europe were bound together by an intricate
network of economic and financial relationships. During the first half of
the century and part of the second, the city of Antwerp was the financial
and commercial center for the European economy, showing once again how the
economic center of gravity had shifted from the Mediterranean to the
Atlantic. When the preeminence of Antwerp became a casualty of the war for
Dutch independence, its place was taken for a while by Amsterdam and later
by London.

The sixteenth century saw not only the rise of new economic powers but also
the decline of old ones. In addition to the gradually decreasing importance
of the Italian city-states, the period also witnessed a falling off of the
power and position of the Hanseatic League, or Hansa towns. This was an
organization of cities in northern Europe, formed for the purpose of
carrying on trade; it had been one of the great powers in the fourteenth and
fifteenth centuries. It secured special trading privileges with numerous
countries, fought wars to maintain its privileges, and had settlements of
merchants from London to Novgorod. The chief city of the League was
Lá-ábeck, but many other great cities belonged to it. It could flourish only
in a period when central governments in some areas were weak enough to
permit the existence of virtually self-governing city-states. With the rise
and consolidation of the nations of Europe, its decline was inevitable. By
the sixteenth century its greatest days were over, though many causes
contributed to its decline and the decline did not come suddenly. Something
of the atmosphere of the Hanseatic towns as it came down to our own century
is preserved for us in the writings of a descendant of the prosperous
merchant class of a Hanseatic city, Thomas Mann.






Reply via email to