Abd ul-Rahman Lomax wrote:
> At 10:38 PM 5/12/2006, Simmons, Forest wrote:
-snip-
>> So most of the time, in the context of Candidate Published Orderings, 
>> Concorcet will 
>> yield an unambiguous social ordering of the candidates, with no cycles to 
>> resolve.
-snip-
>> I would say that's amazing, and extremely relevant to the topic of this 
>> thread.
-snip-

I think an assumption undergirding that conclusion is questionable. Given a 
voting method
that tends to elect a candidate within the sincere top cycle, candidates trying 
to win
will tend to position themselves more closely on more issues than they do under 
existing
voting methods.  With smaller distances between candidates, other quirky 
effects that are
hard to predict or analyze will become relatively stronger.  If candidates (and 
their
supporters) do not agree on the importance of the issues--for example, some may 
care much
more about abortion, some may care much more about taxes, some may care much 
more about
health care, some may care more about corruption, etc.--then cycles may not be 
so rare.

-snip--
> I'd prefer the flexibility of Asset Voting to the fixed process of Candidate 
> Published 
> Ordering, for the latter could still create a minority winner, unless the 
> rules 
> prohibited that.
-snip-

I'm unsure what the writer meant here by "Candidate Published Ordering" and by 
"minority
winner."  When I wrote weeks ago about candidates' publishing pre-election 
orderings, I
didn't specify how the votes should be tallied, so in my mind we're writing 
about a family 
of voting methods.  I wrote then that tallying by MAM would be good, and in 
some later 
messages mentioned a simple system using candidate withdrawal and plurality 
rule.  On the 
other hand, some methods in this family would be quite poor, such as tallying 
by Borda, 
which would encourage nomination of a farcically large number of inferior 
clones.

I don't know where the dividing line is between "rules prohibiting a minority 
winner" and 
rules that define a member of this large family of voting methods.

Is a "minority winner" a candidate not in the sincere top cycle?

Assuming he was referring to tallying using candidate withdrawal and plurality 
rule, I
believe I understand his point: Some candidates might "perversely" refuse to 
withdraw
even though staying in elects an inferior or extremist candidate.  Although we 
could 
abandon the simplicity of "withdrawal//plurality rule" for something like MAM 
(under which 
candidates wouldn't need to withdraw to defeat inferior or extreme candidates) 
or 
"withdrawal//Instant Runoff" (under which only some major candidates would need 
to 
withdraw), I don't see this as a big issue.  The incentives on the candidates 
to do the 
right thing look fairly strong.  If exceptions will be few, why worry?  A 
legislature 
composed of a supermajority of centrists ought to perform well; a few extremist 
legislators would be irrelevant.

I apologize for not knowing what Asset Voting is.  I can glean something from 
the context,
though.  So, let me say this: A positive aspect of the "fixed process" of having
candidates publish orderings of the candidates prior to the election is that it 
will help
focus attention on the candidates' and voters' relative preferences regarding 
the various
compromise positions on the issues.  I think it's more important to elicit this 
info, when
making collective decisions, than to elicit the candidates' and voters' favorite
positions.  Elections should be about making decisions in the near term; there 
are plenty
of other forums in which current minorities can argue that the elected 
compromise
positions are inferior, to try to make their preferred positions popular enough 
to be
adopted in the future.  If I were choosing a proxy to represent me, I'd want to 
choose
someone who would relatively order the plausible compromises similarly to how I 
would,
since ultimately one of the compromises is going to be chosen.

Contrast candidates' published orderings with a more familiar method, 
parliamentary
proportional representation systems (PPR).  In PPR, each party or candidate 
adopts
positions favored by a significant segment of the voters, to win some seats. 
(Typically a
minority of the seats.)  After the election, the elected representatives 
negotiate to pick
the governing executives; assuming no faction won a majority of the seats, some 
sort of
compromise will be reached.  My (limited) understanding of the behavior under 
PPR is that
how the parties/candidates will negotiate after the election is not scrutinized 
much
during the period prior to the election, when the focus is more on preferred 
positions.

--Steve
----
election-methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info

Reply via email to