Raph Frank wrote:
On 8/22/08, Kristofer Munsterhjelm <[EMAIL PROTECTED]> wrote:
 Having different amounts of voting power would simplify multiwinner
election systems considerably. One could, for instance, just do a FPTP count
and then elect the n highest scoring, giving them voting power equal to the
share of the total vote they got.

 Still, that doesn't happen, and no assembly is set up that way. Why? Does
it seem too unfair?

It makes things more difficult in the assembly.  It is much easier to just have
to count the Yes and No members.  With modern technology, it would be easier.
Alot of assemblies have an electronic means for legislators to vote.
The computer
could just add up all the weights.

There are problems with single members have to much power, but that is
covered by putting an upper limit on the allowed power.

A PR-STV count could be run with a max votes allowed (say double the
Droop quota) and then just keep eliminating the lowest candidate until
the correct number of candidates are left and only transfering surplus
above the max votes limit.

This upper limit might not even be needed if candidates are restricted to
one constituency.  In Ireland, getting more than 2 quotas is
extremely rare.

I think keeping the elimination rule is still a good idea
as it allows people vote for outsiders while still allowing their vote to count
for somene who is elected.

I agree. This means that "complex" proportional representation schemes may have their place even for weighted vote situations. I also think it's possible to transform an arbitrary weighted vote constrained-power PR system into a party list PR system. The transformation is simple: party list is just an election of parties where the parties have different "power", and then that power is translated into representative power with equal votes per representative by varying the number of representatives.

There are some limits to the transformation: for instance, you can't have representation below 1/(assembly size), thus the "power constraint" caveat of the transformation. Similarly, power is in steps of 1/(assembly size), and you can't have a sum power (over all representatives) higher than 1 (which is to say, the assembly can't hold more reps than its size).

But if it's true that a simple "FPTP then pick the n best" is a bad system for electing representatives with different power, and I'm right about the transformation, then it follows that ordinary list PR (which is just a FPTP vote for parties) can be a bad system as well. The STV analog would be one where voters can rank parties and then transfers are done (in some way, I'm not clear how) before translating party power into the number of representatives (usually by Webster).

If constituencies are too small and there's no national compensation, then list PR could suffer from the same problems as exist with FPTP applied to candidates: vote splitting and the familiar "worst of many evils" situation. Party list PR elections usually lead to multiparty democracy, though, so I am guessing that this effect isn't significant for real world party list districts. It can still be annoying, in particular to voters who are dissatisfied with existing parties but know that voting for a new party is "just throwing one's vote away".

If we package this up into a more general observation, I think it's the case that parties can survive if it only takes k% (for some unknown value of k) to be represented. If the method's effective threshold is greater than k%, you get two-party rule, and if it's less, you get multiparty rule. For single-winner FPTP, even without gerrymandering, the effective threshold can be very high, effects of which we all know, but with party list PR, the effective threshold is low and so multiple parties survive.

Again, it's not this simple in reality, but it's a good approximation. Some countries that have FPTP in single-winner districts have managed to keep multiple parties alive (India is an example, I think), and some of this can be attributed to regional differences where a party may be significantly stronger than its national share in some areas of the country, thus saving it from extinction of going below k%.

If only 2 ranks were allowed, this would allow each constituency to
announce its full results as a 2-d table, while still giving proportionality.

Voters would be recommended to vote for a candidate who is likely
to get elected as their 2nd choice.

I seem to remember past posts on this list about so-called "three slot methods" that would have only two ranks, but approval-like ordering within each rank. Perhaps these could be generalized to multiwinner methods as well. I know of a few multiwinner Approval methods: proportional approval voting as well as the "approval = max, disapproval = min" conversions of multiwinner Range methods like RRV and LPV0+. Neither PAV nor LPV0+ do very well in my simulations, though; badly enough that I at first wondered if I'd coded them incorrectly (and that I'm still not entirely sure).

If Range or Approval are good single-winner methods, then "pick n highest scoring" for Range and Approval may be good weighted multiwinner methods. Cardinal-3 (with +1, 0, -1) could work; inasfar as CR/Range resists cloning, so would these methods handle the problems noted above regarding FPTP party list PR (or FPTP-based weighted power multiwinner elections).

Condorcet could also be used as a weighted-power method, but only if it gives scores and not just ranking for its social ordering. Perhaps an eigenvector method?
----
Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info

Reply via email to