--- On Tue, 5/5/09, Raph Frank <raph...@gmail.com> wrote: > > Btw, one way that this approach might > > somewhat simplify things is that the > > votes could be shorter than in STV. > > (There might be such shortening needs > > also to keep the votes unidentifiable > > (to avoid vote buying and coercion). > > Maybe limiting the number of entries > > in the ballot could be used in some > > cases for this reason.) > > Right, but it depends on how many choices there are. > > With 100 candidates and PR-STV, you can have potentially > 100! different votes. > > With 100 candidates, 30 groups and 10 parties and 4 ranks > allowed, you > are still looking at around 400 million different > combination. (even > if this is still much lower). > > Ofc, if most people just pick a candidate and use his list, > then there > would be much fewer possibilities.
Yes. One may need to go to quite low numbers if one wants to be sure that there will be no problems. On the other hand in most problem cases the vote must contain also the intended voting pattern, which means that the part that identifies the vote will be smaller. If the vote would e.g. allow only three codes, then one could try to mark a vote to candidate C111 by ranking also two candidates that certainly will not win. The vote could be e.g. C999>C888>C111. Pairs of candidates like C999 and C888 might be rare enough to allow some vote buyer to mark numerous ballots. The default inheritance rules will help since also short votes will carry lots of inheritance information in them. Number of candidates and size of districts whose results will be reported are also important (and existence of "hopeless" candidates too). I remember one example from open list elections. A voter was happy that she voted for her friend as she said to her since the results of different voting stations were published (to her surprise) and there was only one vote to the candidate in question from the local voting station. (=> Also voter privacy needs to be protected.) - - - Some more observations. - - Widespread use of the default inheritance paths means that parties may nominate more candidates than before (in STV) and still keep most of the voting power within the party. It may also be beneficial to nominate numerous candidates (like in open lists today). - - The named parties and groups are in a special position when compared to groupings that might exist as a result of many people voting them. E.g. votes C1>C2>C3>C4 and C2>C3>C1>C5 generate a group C1+C2+C3 that gets at least two votes. The tree structure sets some limits on what kind of groupings may exist. We may however relax the rules a bit. One could name also "orthogonal" groups that consist of candidates of different branches, e.g. "candidates of town X" or "all female candidates". This would make it easier for the voters (there may be many such voters) to vote for these groups. I noted earlier that the seat allocation rules may also observe votes that will be inherited by a certain group. This may make the treatment of named and non-named groupings somewhat different. This kind of additional named groupings will assist the voters. But on the other hand they will also corrupt the basic idea of the tree structure (to offer a clean understandable structure of the political world to the voters). If the additional groups are listed only at some special secondary place they might not be too confusing. Actually there could in principle be also alternative complete hierarchies. If the primary hierarchy is a typical political party structure the alternative hierarchy could be e.g. a geographical structure. A vote to the candidates of town X could be inherited by candidates of the surrounding district. (A candidate could have a code in more than one hierarchy.) - - One of my key points in this discussion is to demonstrate that there is a space and continuum of methods between open lists / trees and STV. The maximum number of codes per ballot may vary for various reasons. Value 1 means actually just a basic tree method (if there is only one hierarchy). Also small values thus work quite well. Larger values allow more personalized votes (a la STV). The space could cover also closed lists. It would be a quite straight forward extension to use one code to refer to a list of candidate instead of only one. 01: C1 02: C2>C3>C4 A vote to 02 would have a mandatory order of inheritance. Code 02 could represent a party that wants to decide itself which of its candidates will be elected. (Voters might or might not agree with this approach.) This structure could also allow candidate defined inheritance orders. Code 02 above could be seen as a vote to C2 with inheritance as planned by C2. C2 could have also a different code that would not include the inheritance order (to allow voters to either vote as recommended by C2 or to create their own order of inheritance). These tricks may again confuse the voters by giving lots of new thoughts and patterns to the voters (instead of relying on the basic tree structure). Candidates C3 and C4 might not have any codes of their own. - - This is enough for now. Maybe I'll one day get also to the alternative seat allocation methods. :-) Juho ---- Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info