On Jan 10, 2010, at 1:02 PM, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax wrote:

> At 01:06 AM 1/10/2010, Jonathan Lundell wrote:
>> On Jan 9, 2010, at 9:23 PM, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax wrote:
>> 
>> > On the other hand, in one-third of nonpartisan top-two runoff elections, 
>> > which IRV supposedly simulates, the runner-up in the primary goes on to 
>> > win the runoff, a "comeback election," according to a FairVote study. It 
>> > simply does not happen with IRV.
>> 
>> It's hard to know what to make of this claim, other than, "so what?" -- if 
>> what you're comparing to TTR is the IRV candidates with the highest 
>> first-choice ballots.
> 
> I'm comparing *elections*. Yes, not all questions are addressed, but the 
> response of "so what?" misses the point, obviously. If we assume sincere 
> voting in TTR

I would not. TTR encourages favorite betrayal for much the same reason FPTP 
does.

> and IRV, and if we consider real world conditions (separate runoff, not 
> merely some simulated runoff with the same voters and the same preferences 
> and no new knowledge or shift of preference or better consideration, etc.), 
> the results are quite different. That preference order doesn't shift in 
> nonpartisan IRV elections, though the vote transfer process, was completely 
> unanticipated, as far as I know. Mr. Lundell, were you aware of it? Did 
> anyone predict this?
> 
> What this means that, with very little exception, you can use Plurality 
> instead of IRV.

Again, I would not make that assumption. In this case, not simply because of 
the difference in voter behavior and voting rule, but because the nominating 
incentives are radically different.

> And this just may explain why Plurality has remained so popular for so long. 
> In certain contexts, it works quite well.
> 
>> Presumably voters in TTR and IRV elections know the counting rules.
> 
> No. We can't presume that, in fact. Both TTR and IRV generally encourage 
> sincere first-preference votes, not in reality, but in appearance. I believe 
> that most votes in the current IRV elections in the U.S. are quite sincere, 
> they aren't being gamed, as they would need to be to maximize voter expected 
> satisfaction, in some cases. With TTR, indeed, voters may know the rules. 
> They might even know IRV rules, but the *implications* of the rules, that 
> knowledge, from what I've seen, is unusual.
> 
>> The meaning of a first-choice IRV vote is not the same as a TTR first-round 
>> vote. One plausible interpretation: if a TTR primary results in A>B, A tends 
>> to have all the votes A is ever going to get, but B, in the runoff, gets all 
>> the "anybody but A" votes, and wins.
> 
> When there is a runoff between two candidates, there is much closer 
> examination of the two candidates. Further, preference strength enters into 
> runoffs, causing results to shift toward what would be range voting results. 
> Sincere range voting! I'm assuming, here, that the runoff is a special 
> election. If the primary is the special election (seems to be common in North 
> Carolina, for example), then it is the primary results that are 
> range-shifted. That's improved election quality, Johathan. People vote when 
> they care. We cannot tell from low turnout if the turnout is low because 
> voters are equally disgusted with both candidates, equally pleased, or truly 
> don't care about who wins no matter who the candidates are. High 
> participation in a general election means a lot of noise, voters with low 
> preference strength (which may be due to lack of knowledge, or may be 
> intrinsic, i.e., they *do* know the candidates and don't care which one wins).
> 
> The proposed explanation for comeback elections, however, "anybody but A," is 
> probably rare. Much more likely is this, as one example:
> 
> B is a dark horse, wasn't expected to do as well as actually happened. When B 
> makes it into the runoff, suddenly those who supported B or who would have 
> supported be had they known about B, will turn out to vote. In the other 
> direction, those who voted in the primary and who actually have low 
> preference between A and B may not turn out to vote; perhaps A was better 
> known and got votes from these voters. So A may lose votes and B may gain 
> them. Add to this the effect of additional campaigning, where B, now being a 
> serious contender, gains more funding and more explicit support, perhaps the 
> recommendation of other candidates.
> 
> Whether or not all this is likely may depend on the margin, but if B was 
> truly a dark horse, B stands to gain votes from those who voted for other 
> candidates. To me, the really interesting situation is where a center 
> squeezed candidate doesn't make it into the runoff. What were the vote 
> margins? Are there signs that the eliminated candidate was actually the 
> Condorcet winner? By what margin and what preference strength? These would be 
> factors in determining if a write-in campaign is appropriate. Using an 
> advanced method in the runoff, even if there are only two candidates on the 
> ballot, and allowing write-ins, allows fixing this problem with top two 
> runoff! And the problem is less likely to arise if an advanced method is used 
> in the primary as well.
> 
> 
>> OTOH, A>B>... in the first round of an IRV election tells us considerably 
>> less, since the cost of voting for a non-poll-leader is considerably less 
>> than with TTR. It's entirely plausible, though of course not necessary, that 
>> the A:B first choice breakdown reflects the lower-choice breakdown of the 
>> other voters.
> 
> This is what we see in IRV elections, when they are nonpartisan. It is as if 
> the supporters of each candidate as most-preferred are a sample from the same 
> population that is otherwise similar. So if, say, those who prefer someone 
> other than A are considered as to their preference for B>C, the ratio of B>C 
> preferences will be the same for those who prefer A. This was unexpected, to 
> me, but it does make some kind of sense.
> 
> Most of our thinking about voting systems has been colored by thinking in 
> terms of factional preferences, which are roughly predictable and not at all 
> like this. We expect that a Progressive voter in Burlington will be more 
> likely to support the Democrat over the Republican, and by significant 
> margins, and we likewise expect that a Republican voter will be more likely 
> to prefer the Democrat over the Progressive. In Burlington, the Democrats are 
> in the middle, the center, they are the local moderates.
> 
> But nonpartisan elections don't seem to work like this. They are about 
> personalities, less about issues and general stances on issues, I suspect. 
> They may be about perception of trustworthiness. 


----
Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info

Reply via email to