On 31.5.2011, at 12.58, Peter Zbornik wrote:

> That would be, I think the smallest improvement on IRV, which could make a 
> positive change in real life and would support centrist candidates.

From the Condorcet criterion point of view, the Condorcet winner is a good, 
often "centrist" candidate. If Condorcet criterion is one of the targets to be 
met, then IRV could be modified appropriately. One simple trick that has been 
proposed is to eliminate the pairwise loser of the two candidates with least 
votes (instead of eliminating always the candidate that has least votes).

(If IRV is used to pick candidates for a second round, and if centrists are 
interesting, then maybe Condorcet winners should be kept.)

> - Using explicit cutoff just as an extra candidate that voters can use as a 
> strategic tool to generate big defeats to some candidates is more problematic 
> (you can try to bury someone under X without any risk of electing X)
> You can try to bury someone under all other candidates anyway. Introducing a 
> null-candidate as a "cuttoff" does not change that.

Yes, but in traditional burial there is always a risk that when voters "lie" 
that candidate Z is better than it is (in order to bury someone) that 
introduces also a risk of electing Z, and that is one key factor that makes 
burial strategy usually too dangerous to try. If there is a "candidate" that 
can be used for burying but that can not be elected, burying may become less 
risky and therefore more common.

> My approach to the various criteria is that one should take into account also 
> how much some method violates some criterion. No proper method meets them 
> all. Condorcet methods are very good from this point of view in the sense 
> that although they fail Later-no-harm there is "usually and by default" no 
> harm ranking also "later" candidates. Same with burial. They are vulnerable 
> to burial but "usually and by default" one need not worry about burial (=not 
> a practical strategy in typical large public elections with independent 
> voters).
>  
> OK for public elections, but for a political party, where voting strategy is 
> the name of the game?

The risk of rational strategies increases if the election is competitive (all 
political elections tend to be), the number of voters is small, their voting 
behaviour can be reliably and centrally coordinated (e.g. direct commands from 
one's own party), information on the planned strategy does not leak out to 
others, when the preferences of all voters are already known (maybe there 
already was a test vote), and when other groups are probably not going to use 
any strategies. If there are multiple parties that may apply strategies and 
counter strategies things come more complicated again. Things may become more 
complex also if some groups try to fool others or hide information by giving 
false messages and false data in polls (maybe in a coordinated way) before the 
actual election. In small elections strategies may thus become easier, but 
still, it is hard to generate any easy rules that could be followed by a 
strategic grouping to implement rational and successful strategies in Condorcet 
methods. My understanding thus is, "good for almost any competitive elections".

Actually I have asked on this list couple of times for good strategy advices 
for practical elections (i.e. 100% accurate information of the given votes + 
option of exactly one grouping to change their voting behaviour after the 
election will not do (this is how the vulnerabilities are typically described 
on this list and elsewhere)) but I have not seen any yet. (I have my own 
favourites for the weakest spots, none of them not terribly weak, but I'd like 
others to step out and tell how Condorcet methods can be fooled best when the 
available information is just few inaccurate and contradictory polls, and the 
opinions are likely to still change a bit before the election day.)

> Do you have any references for your statements concerning "usually and by 
> defaults"?

That was just my way of saying that vulnerabilities exist but they tend to be 
marginal.

> If there is a top level cycle, then people may afterwards think "I should 
> have voted that way", but it is not easy to know what to do (except to vote 
> sincerely) before the election.
>  
> I don't aggree. There is polling and the voter normally knows who is the 
> biggest competitor to the "favored" candidate. The competitor is buried. The 
> voters for the competitor bury your favorite candidate, and the winner is a 
> "nobody" that no-one cared enough about to out-maneuver and noone supports, 
> but also noone dislike. In a polarized environment that is not an unlikely 
> scenario.

Are you saying that general burying of one's competitors is a rational strategy 
for all voters? I.e. is that strategy likely to bring more benefits than 
problems? I believe that in most cases burial is harmful to the strategist.

> I do not personally like the idea of keeping the voter "uninformed" of the 
> workings of an election system and their different strategies.
> That is a path I do not want to walk.

Me neither.

Juho




----
Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info

Reply via email to