At 02:13 PM 5/17/2013, David L Wetzell wrote:
Thank you Abd,

I agree consensus is feasible when there are few people and they are committed to working together.

Right. We learned how to accomplish this with modest-sized groups in the 20th century. Scaling this up has been thought impossible.

It's not. Indeed, it is *necessary*.

I'm focusing on US elections and more so "more local" elections that tend to be chronically non-competitive.

Great. It's the place to start. The goal that I see as realizable is that voting systems, and, more importantly, the *political process* can be designed to increase connectivity and trust between the people and government. When I started this, I felt like a voice crying in the wilderness. I don't feel that way any more. Lots of people are getting it. Structures are being built.

I agree we all use short-cuts in voting and that that shd be considered in thiinking about what sort of election rules we should use.

The interesting possibility, to me, is that the *simplest* system, vote-for-one, can be used in Asset as a ballot, and handling votes for more than one can easily be done without harm. Voting strategy is so simple it's hard for people to understand?

"What do you mean, vote for the single candidate you most trust? How would I know who this would be out of what might be thousands of candidates?"

People get it backwards. Identify the person in your community you most trust, talk to them and ask them to register as a candidate, and vote for them! And if you don't know anyone, well, that's the source of your sense of isolation and disempowerment right there! Meet some people! Or find someone else like yourself, do what it takes, and cooperate.

(People think that the "you most trust" is about comparing all the candidates and finding the one who most matches your opinions. A difficult task indeed! Trust is not about matching opinions, though it may correlate with them in some ways. And if we don't know what trust is, again, *there is what stops us!*)

For simulations, I could generate utilities like Warren Smith did, or I could sample from historical data.

For complete work, do both.

Either way, my goal wd be to refute the notion that a Droop quota is needed for 3-seat elections, when the purpose of the droop quota is served by another means, like the use of an at-large seat.

That's a goal that will distort your results. Do some real science here. It starts with exploration. Find some historical data, I suggest. Become familiar with how the methods work in actual practice. Then design simulations, see if you can predict the behavior of real elections with them. The advantage of simulations is that you can observe how absolute utility profiles create results, and then you can, for the simulations, measure Bayesian regret. Real performance as to a measure of overall social satisfaction, known because the profiles were *defined.* That's what you cannot do with real elections, or at least not generally. There might be some ways to do it.

If you believe that the Droop quota is not needed, try to prove you are wrong, by designing tests. If you try to prove that your theory is true, you can always make up evidence to prove it.

What's likely is that the Droop quota has functions and the Hare quota has functions. I always suggest the Hare quota for Asset elections because it's thoroughly fair, all seats fully and without compromise represent a quota of voters. However, the Droop quota does the same thing, *if one may elect an extra seat*. That seat might have some difference in funciton; it represents what I call "dregs." Left over votes from elected seats, isolated electors who haven't found a compromise. Attempting to complete the election immediately is what leads to wasted votes and wasted votes means people who aren't represented.

Essentially, the quota can be arbitrary, it simply will produce a different number of seats if all votes are used. Is there harm in this? *How much harm*?

If you look at what seems like unfairness, I suggest it will be found in the rules that attampt to reqiure completion in a fixed time. What if the results of elected seats are announced, and not all seats have been elected, and over the next weeks and months, electors get it together to create more seats? If enough seats have been elected initially, the Assembly can begin to function, and it could simply decide to consider the threshhold for substantive motions to pass to be the majority of electoral votes. It could even allow electors to vote directly, while still restricting the right to introduce motions and debate on the floor to elected seats.

There are creative ways to address the problem that could transform the entire way we look at politics. Asset elections complete through *cooperation,* not competition. Every seat is *unanimously elected by a quota.* For N seats, that's the Hare quota.

Single-winner elections use the Droop quota! (That is, when a majority is required. This is the origin of the Droop quota, really.) Single-winner elections *require* wasted votes. The equivalent of using the Hare quota in a single-winner election would be a requirement for unanimity.

For those that don't know, the Hare quota in an N-winner election with V voters casting one vote -- or having one vote active -- is V/N. The Droop quota is V/(N+1). The methods we are considering, when a candidate is elected with votes in excess of the quota, the remaining votes after the quota is substracted are then available to be assigned to another caniddate. In Asset, votes held by the candidate may be assigned at will by the candidate, as if they were the candidate's "assets," hence the name. In STV, the transfers are assigned by a ranked ballot, the elected candidate is "eliminated" from the remainder of the election, and all ballots with a vote for that candidate drop to the next rank, and are given a fractional consideration so that the remaining sum is the left-over vote. At least that's one method.

The stunning power of asset comes from the transfers being under intelligent control, and available for negotiation. The voters assign trust to electors, who then operate publically as to any re-voting. The electors can use any process they choose to decide how to rassign their votes. I expect that seats will be elected chaotically, essentially one at a time, as electors find agreement to assign a quota of votes to a seat.

This is actually what happened with the ESF Steering Committee election. I was elected immediately, the only candidate with more than a quota of votes (Hare or Droop). I then elected the second of three seats, assigning him, beyond his own votes, enough to take him to the Droop quota, with, as I recall, still having enough votes to give him a Hare quota if necessary. (I don't remember exactly. The rules had been imperfectly and, my opinion, incorrectly specified, but the Asset concept is so powerful that we, as the candidates, could create a *unanimous election,* and with unanimity, is anyone gong to complain that we did not follow the announced process?). And then the second-highest vote-getter transferred his votes to a candidate who had only one vote of his own, giving him a Droop quota.

So, to make the election unanimous, I asked the remaining candidate -- he had two votes, as I recall -- if he would approve the election. He did. Now, *this could have been a contentious election*. Asset turned it into consensus. I happen to think that is *way cool*.

For a City Council, what would it be like? *I don't know.* But there is a very good chance that it would have the same effect. With a larger voting population and many more electors, some might be unable to find a place to put their votes, but as the remaining pool gets smaller, electors holding votes, still, will become more and more visible. They will find each other and find ways to cooperate, because, until they do, they do not gain access to the Assembly floor. There need be no rush.

Two electors with a half quota each who say to each other, "You should give your votes to me" could do that for a long time, until they get it together to make a common decision. It might be to elect someone else! (I would allow the electoral college to elect anyone legally eligible for the position, and willing to serve. Very much, it need not be an elector with votes.)

That's true, in fact, if one has 2/3 of a quota and the other 1/3. Neither can coerce the other. The whole competitive premise of politics is undermined. With Asset, "campaigning for a seat" will quite properly be seen as suspicious. No, the electors will *draft* winners through the process. The electors will have, all of them, real power. When I started to understand these concepts over the last few decades, it blew me away.

(In Asset, "candidates" are actually electors, public voters. Because asset wastes no votes, I expect to see *many* electors. It's really as many people as are willing to participate in public life, as people who will vote in public, as distinct from secretly, and to create and advise an elected assembly. In a fully open system, registering as an elector would be almost trivial. Ballots would not have candidate names on them, at all. I'd expect there to be a publication available at the polling place that gives a unique code to enter on the ballot. (Written names would be way too difficult to misidentify, currently many write-in votes are not recognized even where completely legal, which is why some jurisdictions require that write-ins be registered.)
----
Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info

Reply via email to