Hi Forest,

>________________________________
> De : Forest Simmons <fsimm...@pcc.edu>
>À : EM <election-methods@lists.electorama.com> 
>Envoyé le : Mardi 8 octobre 2013 16h59
>Objet : [EM] IA/MPO
>
>Kevin,
>
>I'm afraid that IA/MPO does fail Plurality:
>
>33 A
>17:A=C
>17:B=C
>33 B
>
>The IA/MPO ratio for both A and B is 50/50 = 1, while the ratio for C is 
>34/33, which is greater than 1.
>
>But this is about the worst violation posssible, and it doesn't seem too bad 
>to me.
>
>If equal top ranking were not allowed, then Plurality would not be violated.  
>Or (in other words) the method satisfies a weaker version of Plurality that 
>says if C is ranked on fewer ballots than X is ranked top but not equal to) C, 
>then C cannot win.
>
>
>I don't know if that is helpful.

Actually, we are OK here because Plurality only counts strict first 
preferences. This aspect is useful when trying to make proofs about it. In this 
particular case, I say that if Plurality disqualifies some candidate X to due 
another candidate Y, I know that pairwise opposition to X exceeds X's approval, 
so X's score is below 100%. (And the same sentence is true if you swap in 
SDSC/MD for Plurality.) Since we know somebody will have >=100% as a score, X 
won't win.

I think the question for methods like this is how far away you can get from the 
ideal strategy resembling approval strategy. I feel optimistic because the role 
given to MPO is large. In MDDA and MAMPO majority threshold rules are 
hard-coded and key to seeing any ranking sensitivity. They satisfy SFC 
(basically a weak LNHarm) but I think IA/MPO is awfully close to satisfying 
that as well.


Basically:
Let a be the approval of candidate X
Let b be the approval of candidate Y and also Y's opposition to X
Let c be the maximum opposition to Y

Then IA/MPO violates SFC when a/b > b/c and a > b > 0.5 > c. Possible to do, 
but it would hardly ever happen, I think.

Kevin Venzke

----
Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info

Reply via email to