We offshored it.

http://www.washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/content/article/2009/02/17/AR2009021702769_pf.html

The Dysfunctional Duo

By Harold Meyerson
Wednesday, February 18, 2009; A13

We are hemorrhaging jobs just now, but by historic standards,
unemployment may look a little low. The official unemployment rate
(which understates actual unemployment, to be sure) is at 7.6 percent,
a far cry from the 10 percent-plus during the downturn of the early
1980s. In those years, Midwestern manufacturing shed more jobs than it
is shedding today. Where's the comparable unemployment now?

It's out there, and then some. Only, it's in East Asia. We've offshored it.

In China, where exports dropped 17.5 percent in January, tens of
thousands of factories have closed, and the government estimates that
20 million migrant workers -- rural Chinese who moved to manufacturing
zones for the work -- have lost their jobs. Japan, Hong Kong,
Singapore and Taiwan all project declines in their gross domestic
products this year.

The problem is that East Asia is one big export platform, and its
mega-importer -- the United States -- has stopped buying. If the
emblematic image of the Great Depression was that of Americans lined
up for bread or living in urban shantytowns, the signature image of
the current collapse is the acres of Japanese-made cars gathering dust
in the immense parking lots abutting the Los Angeles and Long Beach
harbors. According to Morgan Stanley economists, exports account for
47 percent of the output of East Asia's developing economies. Here in
the United States, consumption accounted for more than 70 percent of
our GDP on the eve of our consumer meltdown.

The solution for East Asia, and China in particular, is to change its
economic strategy. Instead of relying so heavily on exports, China
will have to increase its domestic consumption. It will have to invest
in upgrading its infrastructure and establish social insurance
programs so that its citizens, instead of hoarding money, will be able
to spend more. It will have to allow wage levels to rise, creating a
more stable domestic market for its goods.

Devising a successful economic strategy for the United States is a
good deal trickier. When our economic elites offshored much of our
manufacturing sector to East Asia and other cheap-labor lands, and
took arms against union labor here at home, they ensured that most of
the American jobs created over the past quarter-century would come in
retail and service sectors that paid less than manufacturing. Every
year for the past couple of decades, we've added lots more
sales-clerk, cashier and fast-food jobs than we've created in high
technology or energy. Yet Americans have been able to maintain
middle-class living standards -- not through rising income but through
rising debt, available to us because China has funneled the immense
revenue it amassed selling us goods back to us in the form of loans
that we can no longer repay.

At the center of the global meltdown, then, is the misshapen economic
codependency of the United States and China. Each has followed a
fundamentally unstable economic model, with one nation suppressing
wages so that it could export more and the other living on borrowed
funds so that it could purchase more. Despite the sharply different
roles that each nation carved for itself, though, a shared
characteristic allowed them to chart their ultimately disastrous
course.

What do the United States and China have in common? They are the only
two major economic powers that are resolutely hostile to unions. In
China, any unions not controlled by the state are outlawed, which is
why so many protests about unpaid wages and the like take the form of
riots; there's no legal way to enforce workers' rights. In the United
States for the past 30 years, business has been implacably opposed to
labor, routinely violating the National Labor Relations Act rather
than permitting employees to join unions.

Over the past few years, as global alliances of unions have begun to
win agreements with global corporations, there's been one major
impediment to such accords. "I always look at the percentage of a
company's revenues from two nations, China and the U.S.," says Ron
Oswald of the International Union of Food Workers, "in deciding
whether to push for an international agreement." That's what happens
when worker organizing is all but forbidden.

But suppose that China and the United States did have powerful unions.
In China, such unions might have pushed for higher wages, social
insurance and more domestic consumption. Here, such unions would have
preserved more of a manufacturing sector and boosted wages in the
service and retail sectors, so that American consumers could have
relied more on income than on credit to make their purchases. The two
nations would have had more sustainable economic strategies. And the
world economy might not now be plunging into what, so far, appears to
be a bottomless pit.

meyers...@washpost.com

Reply via email to