>From The Jobs Letter, with permission.

>F E A T U R E
>------------------
>from
>T H E   J O B S   L E T T E R   1 0 2
>a subscriber-based letter
>published in New Zealand 29 June 1999
> -------------------------------------
>
>INSECURITY AND THE CORROSION OF CHARACTER
>RICHARD SENNETT on the personal consequences of work in the new
>economy.
>
>ON FLEXIBILITY
>*    The emphasis is on flexibility. Rigid forms of bureaucracy are
>under attack, as are the evils of blind routine. Workers are asked to
>behave nimbly, to be open to change on short notice, to take risks
>continually, to become ever less dependent on regulations and
>formal procedures.
>
>This emphasis on flexibility is changing the very meaning of
>work, and so the words we use for it.
>
>"Career", for instance, in its English origins meant a road for
>carriages, and as eventually applied to labour meant a lifelong
>channel for one's economic pursuits. Flexible capitalism has blocked
>the straight roadway of career, diverting employees suddenly from
>one kind of work into another.
>
>The word "job" in English of the fourteenth century meant a
>lump or piece of something that could be carted around. Flexibility
>today brings back this arcane sense of the job, as people do lumps of
>labour, pieces of work, over the course of a lifetime.
>
>*    It is quite natural that flexibility should arouse anxiety;
>people do not know what risks will pay off, what paths to pursue. To
>take the curse off the phrase "capitalist system" there has developed
>in the past many circumlocutions, such as the "free enterprise" or
>"private enterprise" system.
>
>Flexibility is used today as another way to lift the curse of
>oppression from capitalism. In attacking rigid bureaucracy and
>emphasising risk, it is claimed, gives people more freedom to shape
>their lives. In fact, the new order substitutes new controls rather
>than simply abolishing the rules of the past --    but these new
>controls are also hard to understand. The new capitalism is an often
>illegible regime of power.
>
>ON CHARACTER
>*    Perhaps the most confusing aspect of flexibility is its impact
>on personal character. Character is the ethical value we place on our
>own desires and on our relations to others. The character of a man
>depends on his connections to the world.
>
>Character particularly focuses upon the long-term aspect of our
>emotional experience. Character is expressed by loyalty and mutual
>commitment, or through the pursuit of long-term goals, or by the
>practice of delayed gratification for the sake of a future end.
>Character concerns the personal traits which we value in ourselves
>and for which we seek to be valued by others.
>
>*    These are the questions about our character posed by the
>new, flexible capitalism:
>
>How do we decide what is of lasting value in ourselves in a
>society which is impatient, which focuses on the immediate moment?
>
>How can long-term goals be pursued in an economy devoted to
>the short-term?
>
>How can mutual loyalties and commitments be sustained in
>institutions which are constantly breaking apart or continually being
>redesigned?
>
>ON NO LONG TERM
>*    Business leaders and journalists emphasise the global
>marketplace and the use of new technologies as the hallmarks of the
>capitalism of our time. This is true enough, but misses another
>dimension of change: new ways of organising time, particularly
>working time.
>
>The most tangible sign of that change might be the motto "no
>long term". In work, the traditional career progressing step by step
>through the corridors of one or two institutions is withering; so is
>the deployment of a single set of skills through the course of a
>working life.
>
>Today, a young American with at least two years of college can
>expect to change jobs at least eleven times in the course of working,
>and change his or her skill base at least three times during those
>forty years of labour.
>
>"No long term" is a principle that corrodes trust, loyalty and
>mutual commitment. The short time frame of modern institutions
>limits the ripening of informal trust. Strong ties depend, in
>contrast, on long association. And, more personally, they depend on a
>willingness to make commitments to others.
>
>*    Short-term capitalism threatens to corrode our characters,
>particularly those qualities of character which bind human beings to
>one another and furnishes each with a sense of sustainable self.
>
>Transposed to the family realm, "no long term" means keep
>moving, don't commit yourself, and don't sacrifice. How can we
>protect family relations from succumbing to short-term behaviour,
>and above all the weakness of loyalty and commitment which mark
>the modern workplace? In the place of the chameleon values of the
>new economy, family values emphasise formal obligation,
>trustworthiness, commitment, and purpose. These are all long-term
>virtues.
>
>This conflict between family and work poses some questions
>about adult experience itself. How can long-term purposes be
>pursued in a short-term society? How can durable social relations be
>sustained? How can a human being develop a narrative of identity
>and life history in a society composed of episodes and fragments?
>The conditions of the new economy feed instead on experience which
>drifts in time, from place to place, from job to job.
>
>*    Through most of human history, people have accepted the
>fact that their lives will shift suddenly due to wars, famines or
>other disasters, and that they will have to improvise in order to
>survive.
>
>What is peculiar about uncertainty today is that it exists without
>any looming historical disaster; instead it is woven into the everyday
>practices of a vigorous capitalism. Instability is meant to be normal,
>the entrepreneur is served up as an ideal Everyman. "No long term"
>disorients action over the long term, loosens bonds of trust and
>commitment, and divorces will from behaviour.
>
>ON "RE-ENGINEERING" FANTASIES
>*    The most salient fact about "re-engineering" is the
>downsizing of jobs. Estimates of the numbers of American workers
>who have been downsized from jobs in the major corporates, from
>1980 to 1995, vary from a low count of 13m people, to as high as 39m.
>Downsizing has had a direct connection to growing inequality, since
>only a minority of the middle-aged workers squeezed out have
>found replacement labour at the same or higher wages.
>
>The declaration of "re-engineering" evokes efficiency --  doing
>more with less  --  conjuring up a tighter operation achieved by
>making a decisive break from the past. But the overtones of efficiency
>can be misleading. Irreversable change occurs because "re-
>engineering" can be a highly chaotic process.
>
>*    It became clear to many business leaders by the mid-1990s
>that only in the highly paid fantasy life of consultants can a large
>organisation define a new business plan, trim staff and re-engineer
>itself to suit, then steam forward to realise the new design.
>
>       Many, even most, re-engineering efforts fail largely because
>institutions become dysfunctional during the people-squeezing
>process: the morale and motivation of workers drop sharply in the
>various plays of downsizing. Surviving workers wait for the next
>blow of the axe rather than exulting in competitive victory over those
>who are fired...
>
>       Institutional changes, instead of following the path of the
>guided arrow, head in different and often conflicting directions:
>business plans are discarded and revised; expected benefits turn out
>to be ephemeral; the organisation loses direction, a profitable
>operating unit is suddenly sold, for example, yet a few years later
>the parent company tries to get back the business in which it knew how
>to make money before it sought to reinvent itself..."
>
>*    In the early 1990s, the American Management Association
>conducted studies of firms which had engaged seriously in
>downsizing. The AMA found that repeated downsizings produce
>"lower profits and declining worker productivity..." Another study
>by the Wyatt Companies found that "less than half the companies
>achieved their expense reduction goals; fewer than one-third
>increased their profitability and less than one third increased their
>productivity..."
>
>*    Inefficiency or disorganisation does not mean, however, that
>there is no rhyme or reason to the practice of sharp, disruptive
>change. Because institutional re-structurings signal to the finance
>markets that change is "for real", the stock prices of institutions in
>the course of re-organisation often rises, as though "any changes are
>better than continuing on as before." In the operation of modern
>markets, the disruption of organisations becomes profitable.
>
>       While the disruption may not be justifiable in terms of
>productivity, the short-term returns to stockholders provide a strong
>incentive to the powers of chaos disguised by that seemingly
>reassuring word "re-engineering". Perfectly viable businesses are
>gutted or abandoned, capable employees are set adrift rather than
>rewarded, simply because the organisation must prove to the market
>that it is capable of change.
>
>ON MOVING SIDEWAYS
>*    As pyramidal hierarchies are replaced by looser networks,
>people who change jobs experience more often what sociologists
>have called "ambiguously lateral moves". These are moves in which
>a person in fact moves sideways even while believing he or she is in
>fact moving up in the loose network. This crablike motion accurs
>even though incomes are becoming more polarised and unequal, and
>job categories are becoming more amorphous.
>
>*    People often experience "retrospective losses" in a flexible
>network. Since people who risk making moves in a flexible
>organisation often have little hard information about what a new
>position will entail, they realise only in retrospect they've made bad
>decisions. They wouldn't have taken the risk if only they'd known.
>But organisations are so often in a state of internal flux that its
>useless to attempt rational decision-making about one's future based
>on the current structure of one's company.
>
>ON FLEXIBILITY AND THE OLDER WORKER
>*    The new economy places an emphasis on youth, and a
>consequence of this is the compression of working life.
>
>The number of men aged 55-64 at work in the United States has
>dropped from nearly 80% in 1970 to 65% in 1990. The figures for the
>United Kingdom, France and Germany are similar. There is also a
>slight abridgement at the beginning of a working life, the age young
>people enter the labour force has been delayed a few years because of
>the increased emphasis on education.
>
>The sociologist Manuel Castells predicts that "the actual
>working lifetime could be shortened to about 30 years (from 24 to
>54), out of a real lifetime span of about 75-80 years". That is, the
>productive life span is being compressed to less than half the
>biological life span, with older workers leaving the scene long before
>they are physically or mentally unfit.
>
>*    For older workers, the prejudices against age send a
>powerful message: as a person's experience accumulates, it loses
>value. What an older worker has learned over the course of the years
>about a particular company or profession may get in the way of new
>changes dictated by superiors. From the institution's vantage point,
>the flexibility of the young makes them more malleable in terms of
>both risk-taking and immediate submission.
>
>ON OVERQUALIFICATION
>*    Overqualification is a sign of the polarisation which marks
>the new regime. There are, to be sure, solid material reasons to get a
>degree. American data shows that increases in income in the last
>decade were about 34% more for workers with a college degree than
>for workers with a high school diploma. Yet only a fifth of jobs in
>the labour force in America require a college degree, and the
>percentage of these highly qualified jobs is only slowly rising.
>
>ON WINNERS TAKING ALL
>*    An immense shift is taking place in society: a huge transfer of
>wealth from lower-skilled middle-class workers to the owners of
>capital assets and a new technological aristocracy. Under these
>conditions, a kind of extreme risk-taking takes form in which large
>numbers of young people gamble that they will be one of the chosen
>few.
>
>Such risk-taking occurs in what economists call "winner-take-all
>markets". In this competitive landscape, those who succeed sweep
>the board of gains, while the mass of losers have crumbs to divide up
>amongst themselves.
>
>Flexibility is a key element in allowing such a market to form.
>Without a bureaucratic system to channel wealth gains throughout a
>hierarchy, rewards gravitate to the most powerful. In an unfettered
>institution, those in a position to grab everything, do so.
>
>*    Failure is the great modern taboo. Popular literature is full of
>recipes for how to succeed, but largely silent on how to cope with
>failure.
>
>Failure is no longer the normal prospect of facing only the very
>poor or disadvantaged. It has become more familiar as a regular
>event in the lives of the middle classes. The shrinking size of the
>elite makes achievement more elusive. The winner-take-all market is a
>competitive structure which disposes large numbers of educated
>people to fail.
>
>Downsizings and re-engineerings impose on middle-class
>people sudden disasters which were in an earlier capitalism much
>more confined to the working classes. The sense of failing one's
>family by behaving flexibly and adaptively at work is more subtle,
>but equally powerful.
>
>[sidebox]
>
>RICO AS EVERYMAN
>*    Richard Sennett begins his book with an interview with
>"Rico", a man who knows all about downsizing, company "re-
>engineering", teamwork and short contracts. According to Sennett,
>Rico and his wife are the "very acme of the adaptable, mutually
>supportive couple", but "both often fear that they are on the edge of
>losing control over their lives" in a world where there is only short-
>term work and short-term profits.
>
>Rico's experiences of changing jobs and becoming a consultant
>where he has no fixed role and never really belongs to a company
>have "set his inner and emotional life adrift." He is haunted by a
>sense that he cannot provide his children with the ethical discipline
>that his parents instilled in him.
>
>Rico's working life, with its constant changes, doesn't provide
>his children with examples of values such as loyalty, trust and
>service. Rico told Sennett: "You can't imagine how stupid I feel when
>I talk to my kids about commitment. Its an abstract virtue to them,
>they don't see it anywhere ..."
>
>*    For Sennett, Rico is Everyman whose dilemmas show how
>"short-term capitalism threatens to corrode his character,
>particularly those qualities of character which bind human beings to
>one another and furnishes each with a sense of sustainable self ...
>the flexible self which has brought him success is weakening his own
>character in ways for which there exists no practical remedy..."
>
>The Corrosion of Character
>-- The Personal Consequences of Work in the New Capitalism
>by Richard Sennett
>(pub 1998 by W.W.Norton and Company)
>ISBN 0-393-04678-8
>available on www.amazon.com
>http://www.amazon.com/exec/obidos/ASIN/0393046788/thejobsresearc
>tr
>
>
>SENNETT LECTURE ON THE INTERNET
>A RealVideo lecture (60 mins) by Richard Sennett on "The New
>Work Ethic" was given to an audience at the New York Public
>Library on the 20th March, 1999. This talk is part of the American
>Perspectives lecture series hosted by c-span.org
>
>link for the RealVideo lecture by Richard Sennett
>http://38.217.109.100/ram/amerpers/ap032099v3.ram
>
>American perspectives link at c-span.org
>http://38.217.109.100/guide/society/perspectives/ap032099.ht
>m
>
>link for free RealVideo player
>http://www.real.com/
>
>V O I C E
>------------------
>ON INSECURITY AND RE-DEFINING WORK
> "Rising unemployment can no longer be ascribed to cyclical
>economic crises; it is a consequence of the success of a
>technologically advanced capitalism. We have to change our economic
>language. Economic growth, for example, is no longer a valid indicator
>of job creation, just as job creation is no longer a valid indicator
>of employment and employment is no longer an indicator of income
>levels and secure status.
>
>"Even the life of the affluent is becoming insecure and today's
>success is no guarantee against tomorrow's fall. The job miracle in
>the US hides the political economy of uncertainty: the US is the only
>advanced society in which productivity has been steadily rising over
>the past two decades while the income of the majority -- eight out
>of ten -- has stagnated or fallen. This has happened in no other
>advanced democracy.
>
>"Endemic insecurity will in future characterise the lives, and the
>foundations of the lives, of the majority of the population -- even in
>the apparently affluent centre of society. If this diagnosis is
>basically right then we face two political options.
>
>"First, there is the "nevertheless" policy, which enforces full
>employment after the end of normal full employment. This "New
>Labour" policy believes that only work guarantees order and the
>inclusive society. In this view, waged work has the monopoly of
>inclusiveness.
>
>"The second option is to rethink and redefine work as we have
>done with respect to the family. But this also implies rethinking how
>we deal with the risks of fragile work ...
>
> "Has work always had the monopoly of inclusiveness? If the
>ancient Greeks could listen to our debates about the anthropological
>need to work in order not only to be an honourable member of
>society but a fully valued human being, they would laugh. The value
>system that proclaims the centrality of work and only work in
>building and controlling an inclusive society is a modern invention of
>capitalism and the welfare state.
>
> "We need to see that there is a life beyond the alternatives of
>unemployment and stress at work. We need to see that the lack of
>waged work can give us a new affluence of time. We need also to see
>that the welfare state must be rebuilt so that the risks of fragile
>work are socialised rather than being borne increasingly by the
>individual.
>
>"I would argue for a citizen's (or basic) income. My argument is
>that we need a new alternative centre of inclusion -- citizen work
>combined with citizen income -- creating a sense of compassion and
>cohesion through public commitment. The decoupling of income
>entitlements from paid work and from the labour market would, in
>Zygmunt Bauman's words, remove "the awesome fly of insecurity
>from the sweet ointment of freedom".
>
>"We must, in short, turn the new precarious forms of
>employment into a right to discontinuous waged work and a right to
>disposable time. It must be made possible for every human being
>autonomously to shape his or her life and create a balance between
>family, paid employment, leisure and political commitment. And I
>truly believe that this is the only way of forming a policy that will
>create more employment for everybody ..."
>-- German sociologist Ulrich Beck, from "Goodbye To All That
>Wage Slavery" New Statesman 5 March 1999.
>
>
>
>C R E D I T S
>-------------------
>edited by Vivian Hutchinson for the Jobs Research Trust
>P.O.Box 428, New Plymouth, New Zealand
>phone 06-753-4434 fax 06-759-4648
>Internet address --  [EMAIL PROTECTED]
>
>The Jobs Letter -- an essential information and media watch
>on jobs, employment,  unemployment, the future of work,
>and related economic and education issues.
>
>The Jobs Research Trust -- a not-for-profit Charitable Trust
>constituted in 1994 to develop and  distribute information that
>will help our communities create more jobs and reduce
>unemployment  and poverty in New Zealand.
>
>Our internet website at
>
>          http://www.jobsletter.org.nz/
>
>contains our back issues and key papers,
>and hotlinks to other internet resources.
>
>ends
>------
>
>The Jobs Letter
>essential information on an essential issue
>[EMAIL PROTECTED]
>phone 06-753-4434 fax 06-759-4648
>P.O.Box 428
>New Plymouth, Taranaki, New Zealand
>
>visit The Jobs Research Website at
>http://www.jobsletter.org.nz/
>



Reply via email to