PERHAPS THIS IS OF INTEREST. THANK YOU.
>"Economic growth has long been considered such an obvious boon that it’s
pursued by governments across the world as a matter of course."

>"Gains in economic growth have too often buoyed the fortunes of the
richest instead of lifting all boats. Prosperity even in the most
prosperous countries hasn’t been shared. But all the attention to inequality
<https://www.nytimes.com/2023/11/03/books/review/inequality-economy-books.html>
 is just a crack in the edifice of economic orthodoxy. Now a much more
radical proposition has emerged, looming like a wrecking ball: Is economic
growth desirable at all?"

>"The realization that we hadn’t innovated our way out of our ecological
predicament, along with inequalities laid bare by the 2008 financial
crisis, fueled a more widespread distrust of the conventional capitalist
wisdom. Maybe relentless economic growth was more poison than panacea."

>"Hickel [Jason, an anthropologist who teaches in London and Barcelona and
is one of the movement’s most spirited exponents
<https://www.jasonhickel.org/blog>]
writes: 'Degrowth is about reducing the material and energy throughput of
the economy to bring it back into balance with the living world, while
distributing income and resources more fairly, liberating people from
needless work, and investing in the public goods that people need to
thrive.'”

>“'We have ceded our political agency to the lazy calculus of growth," [is] the
distinctive argument that Hickel and other degrowthers make . . . .
ultimately a moral one."

>"Yet for the vocal proponents of degrowth, the timorousness of a 'more
balanced position' is what allowed capitalist growth to run roughshod over
the earth in the first place. This is the resolute message promulgated by
Kohei Saito, a 37-year-old Japanese Marxist philosopher who has emerged as
the movement’s public face
<https://www.theatlantic.com/ideas/archive/2024/05/kohei-saito-degrowth-communism/678481/>
. 'Any attempt to blend degrowth with capitalism is doomed to fail,' he
proclaims in 'Slow Down: The Degrowth Manifesto
<https://astrapublishinghouse.com/product/slow-down-9781662602368/>.'”

>"By demanding 'capitalism’s end,' Saito is just getting started; what he
calls for is not just degrowth, but 'degrowth communism.'”

>“'Seeds of degrowth communism are sprouting all over the world,' Saito
writes, pointing to experiments in local governance in cities like
Barcelona, which has pledged to be carbon neutral by 2050
<https://www.uab.cat/web/sala-de-premsa-icta-uab/detall-noticia/barcelona-takes-stock-of-the-declaration-of-climate-emergency-advised-by-icta-uab-1345819915004.html?detid=1345885251626>,
and farming cooperatives in South Africa."

>"Whatever the profound differences between degrowth’s proponents and their
critics, the scale of the climate crisis suggests one point of convergence: We
need all the imaginative help we can get."

----------------------------------

By: Jennifer Szalai
Published in: *The New York Times*
Date: June 8, 2024
Economic growth has been ecologically costly — and so a movement in favor
of ‘degrowth’ is growing.
A rising tide and a bigger pie: Economic growth has long been considered
such an obvious boon that it’s pursued by governments across the world as a
matter of course. But in 2016, when a London professor warned an audience
in Newcastle that Brexit would lead to a precipitous drop in Britain’s
gross domestic product, that well-worn measure of economic activity, one
woman’s heckling caught him by surprise. “That’s your bloody G.D.P.,” she
shouted, “not ours!”

The eruption tapped into a suspicion supported by reality: Gains in
economic growth have too often buoyed the fortunes of the richest instead
of lifting all boats. Prosperity even in the most prosperous countries
hasn’t been shared. But all the attention to inequality
<https://www.nytimes.com/2023/11/03/books/review/inequality-economy-books.html>
 is just a crack in the edifice of economic orthodoxy. Now a much more
radical proposition has emerged, looming like a wrecking ball: Is economic
growth desirable at all?

Less than two decades ago, an economist like Herman Daly
<https://www.nytimes.com/interactive/2022/07/18/magazine/herman-daly-interview.html>
, who argued for a “steady-state economy,” was such an outlier that his
fellow economist Benjamin Friedman could declare that “practically nobody
opposes economic growth per se.” Yet today there is a burgeoning
“post-growth” and “degrowth” movement doing exactly that — in journals
<https://www.degrowthjournal.org/>, on podcasts, at conferences. Consider
some of the books published in the last several years: Tim Jackson’s “
<https://www.wiley.com/en-us/Post+Growth:+Life+after+Capitalism-p-9781509542512>Post-Growth:
Life After Capitalism,
<https://www.wiley.com/en-us/Post+Growth:+Life+after+Capitalism-p-9781509542512>
”
<https://www.wiley.com/en-us/Post+Growth:+Life+after+Capitalism-p-9781509542512>
 Kate Soper’s “Post-Growth Living,
<https://www.versobooks.com/products/929-post-growth-living>”
<https://www.versobooks.com/products/929-post-growth-living> Giorgos
Kallis’s “In Defense of Degrowth,” <https://indefenseofdegrowth.com/>Vincent
Liegey and Anitra Nelson’s “
<https://www.plutobooks.com/9780745342023/exploring-degrowth/>Exploring
Degrowth,” <https://www.plutobooks.com/9780745342023/exploring-degrowth/> Jason
Hickel’s “Less Is More: How Degrowth Will Save the World.”
<https://www.jasonhickel.org/less-is-more> The proliferation of the term is
as good an indicator as any: The literature of degrowth is growing.

In 1972, the French theorist André Gorz coined the word *décroissance* to
ask whether “no-growth — or even degrowth” in material production was
necessary for “the earth’s balance,” even if it ran counter to “the
survival of the capitalist system.” Gorz was writing the same year that “The
Limits to Growth” <https://www.clubofrome.org/ltg50/> was published, a
report by a group of scientists warning that surges in population and
economic activity would eventually outstrip the carrying capacity of the
planet. “The Limits to Growth” was initially met with skepticism and even
ridicule. Critics pointed to humanity’s undeniably impressive record of
technological innovation. As one representative economist put it, “Our
predictions are firmly based on a study of the way these problems have been
overcome in the past.”

And so degrowth remained on the fringes of the fringe for decades, until
increasing awareness about global warming percolated into public debates in
the early aughts. The realization that we hadn’t innovated our way out of
our ecological predicament, along with inequalities laid bare by the 2008
financial crisis, fueled a more widespread distrust of the conventional
capitalist wisdom. Maybe relentless economic growth was more poison than
panacea.

An Ideology of ‘Growthism’
This doubt has taken varied forms, from cautious agnosticism to categorical
doomsaying, with degrowth occupying the furthest end of the spectrum. For
advocates of degrowth, it’s a core tenet that in high-income countries the
constant expansion demanded by capitalism isn’t required to improve
people’s lives; instead, the ensuing inequality and environmental havoc
have frequently undermined them.

Take Hickel, an anthropologist who teaches in London and Barcelona and is
one of the movement’s most spirited exponents
<https://www.jasonhickel.org/blog>. Like other contemporary critics of
unfettered growth, he emphasizes the climate crisis. His book begins with
scenes of ecological devastation: dying earthworms, declining crop yields,
collapsing fish stocks. He points to the connection between growing G.D.P.
and energy use, identifying an ideology of “growthism” that he equates with
“a kind of madness.” He says that he is not promoting a deliberate
reduction in G.D.P. But if G.D.P. stagnates or declines because we conserve
energy instead of consuming it, so be it.

In what could be a mission statement for the movement, Hickel writes:
“Degrowth is about reducing the material and energy throughput of the
economy to bring it back into balance with the living world, while
distributing income and resources more fairly, liberating people from
needless work, and investing in the public goods that people need to
thrive.”

This program amounts to an overhaul of the capitalist system, not just some
reformist tinkering around the edges. Nor do its advocates place much hope
in technological fixes. “‘Green growth’ is not a thing,” Hickel asserts,
citing research he conducted with Kallis
<https://content.csbs.utah.edu/~mli/Economics%207004/HickelandKallis-IsGreenGrowthPossible.pdf>
. “It has no empirical support.”

Of course, such a sweeping pronouncement is far from uncontested.
Economists like Paul Krugman
<https://www.nytimes.com/2023/02/17/opinion/economic-growth-green-degrowth.html>
 and data scientists like Hannah Ritchie
<https://www.nytimes.com/2024/04/30/podcasts/transcript-ezra-klein-interviews-hannah-ritchie.html>
 have maintained
<https://www.hachettebookgroup.com/titles/hannah-ritchie/not-the-end-of-the-world/9780316536752/>
 that technological advances mean that economic prosperity doesn’t have to
lead to ecological degradation. But for all the debates over carbon pricing
<https://politicsofpoverty.oxfamamerica.org/carbon-pricing-the-best-answer-to-climate-change-or-a-regressive-policy-set-to-fail/>
 and parts per million
<https://www.nytimes.com/interactive/2024/04/20/upshot/carbon-dioxide-growth.html?searchResultPosition=1>
 and degrees of warming
<https://www.nytimes.com/2023/11/02/climate/james-hansen-global-warming-report.html?searchResultPosition=4>
, the distinctive argument that Hickel and other degrowthers make is
ultimately a moral one: “We have ceded our political agency to the lazy
calculus of growth.”

In other words, we have plundered the planet instead of figuring out more
egalitarian ways to live with one another. *“*The problem with growthism is
that for decades it has distracted us from the difficult politics of
redistribution,” Hickel writes. This initially looked like the opposite of
a problem. Growth’s seemingly magical ability to allow us to sidestep the
toughest moral disputes was, for generations of politicians, the very thing
that commended it.

Yet this pattern of avoidance has compounded not only our ecological
troubles but our moral ones, too. An illusory consensus held together by
economic growth has dissolved. As the economist Daniel Susskind notes in
his new book, “Growth: A History and a Reckoning
<https://www.hup.harvard.edu/books/9780674294493>,” big questions that were
pushed to the margins — about clashing notions of freedom, equality and
justice — have roared back with a vengeance. Still, he sees this as cause
for ambivalence, not despair. After all, growth has also emancipated much
of the world from “an unforgiving struggle for subsistence,” Susskind
points out. “Growth has an irresistible promise and an unacceptable price;
it is miraculous and devastating; we need a lot more and vastly less.”

Although he denounces the blithe optimism of the economic establishment,
Susskind is also highly critical of degrowthers, who are too dismissive of
capitalism for his liking. He recommends “adopting a weak degrowth
mind-set” — one that holds “*less *regard for growth” while also preserving
a “serious endorsement of growth’s merits.” Only a “more balanced
position,” he says, would “recognize the reality of a difficult trade-off
between growth and the climate.”

Abundance Without Growth?
Yet for the vocal proponents of degrowth, the timorousness of a “more
balanced position” is what allowed capitalist growth to run roughshod over
the earth in the first place. This is the resolute message promulgated by
Kohei Saito, a 37-year-old Japanese Marxist philosopher who has emerged as
the movement’s public face
<https://www.theatlantic.com/ideas/archive/2024/05/kohei-saito-degrowth-communism/678481/>
. “Any attempt to blend degrowth with capitalism is doomed to fail,” he
proclaims in “Slow Down: The Degrowth Manifesto
<https://astrapublishinghouse.com/product/slow-down-9781662602368/>.”
Capitalism
doesn’t just tend toward growth, he says, but requires it. “To demand the
cessation of all these things — to demand deceleration — is in fact to
demand capitalism’s end.”

This idea might sound extreme, but it has found a considerable audience:
“Slow Down,” which was released in the United States in January, has sold
half a million copies
<https://www.nytimes.com/2023/08/23/business/kohei-saito-degrowth-communism.html?searchResultPosition=1>
 since it was first published in Japan in 2020. In it, Saito quotes the
Swedish activist Greta Thunberg, who denounced an older generation for only
being “interested in solutions that would enable you to carry on like
before.” Saito himself was born in 1987, and suggests that because he did
not live through the Cold War, he was able to study Marxism without
“reflexively” imposing the reality of the Soviet Union onto Marx’s work. By
demanding “capitalism’s end,” Saito is just getting started; what he calls
for is not just degrowth, but “degrowth communism.”

Mind you, Saito maintains that the communism he’s proposing isn’t the
top-down, coercive, undemocratic statism of the Soviet Union, but something
that looks a lot more like communitarianism, with an emphasis on more local
measures like mutual aid, citizens’ assemblies and “face-to-face community
building.” This redefinition, he says, isn’t a repudiation of Marx — who
emphasized the necessity of state-led economic growth in “The Communist
Manifesto” — but is based on “research notes Marx kept at the end of his
life,” as he became increasingly willing to take the dangers of
environmental degradation into account.

It’s certainly an unusual rhetorical strategy: insist on repurposing Marx
and resuscitating a loaded (and arguably inaccurate) term like “communism”
by trying to purge (or ignore) its historical baggage. But Saito’s book is
written largely for a generation that has been saddled with the ecological
consequences of economic growth and therefore has little reason to respect
the likes and dislikes of its elders. He repeatedly derides the faintest
hint of moderation with a dismissive “amounts to nothing more”; his
uncompromising provocations are undoubtedly part of the appeal.

Eventually, though, Saito admits that there is “some truth” to the argument
that capitalism produces material wealth, and so he champions degrowth
communism only for rich countries, not for poor ones. “Those in the Global
North enjoy rich lifestyles enabled by the sacrifices of those in the
Global South,” he writes. Degrowth would halt this injustice and offer a
form of “reparations”: Reducing the resources and energy used by the Global
North would allow the Global South to pursue its own economic growth
instead.

Just don’t call this a sacrifice on our part. Even Saito is forced to
contend with our stubborn attraction to bounty, edging away from the
austere vocabulary of degrowth by resorting to the language of plenitude. Like
Hickel, he promises a new kind of “radical abundance,” in which a genuine
commitment to “the commons” will allow us to savor “public wealth” instead
of endlessly chasing stuff we don’t need.

‘A Poverty of Imagination’
Given how keenly the degrowth movement disavows coercion, how is this
wholesale transformation supposed to happen? “Seeds of degrowth communism
are sprouting all over the world,” Saito writes, pointing to experiments in
local governance in cities like Barcelona, which has pledged to be carbon
neutral by 2050
<https://www.uab.cat/web/sala-de-premsa-icta-uab/detall-noticia/barcelona-takes-stock-of-the-declaration-of-climate-emergency-advised-by-icta-uab-1345819915004.html?detid=1345885251626>,
and farming cooperatives in South Africa.

Even degrowth’s skeptics may find that Saito’s examples of grass-roots
organizing sound agreeably democratic and improvisational. But the prospect
of global apocalypse that degrowthers keep emphasizing also has the
perverse effect of making local measures sound acutely inadequate. Still,
Saito says that such experiments do offer something crucial: an enlarged
sense of what’s possible. Degrowth’s critics, he writes, suffer from “a
poverty of imagination that simply accepts the status quo as unchangeable.”

As it happens, Susskind says precisely the same thing but in the reverse:
that it’s degrowth’s advocates who suffer from a “lack of imagination.” The
mirrored accusations are striking. Maybe it isn’t a matter so much of
imagination scarcity as of where that imagination is directed.
Techno-optimists place their faith in innovation; degrowthers place theirs
in social movements. Both sides lay claim to being the genuine realists.
Each insists that we simply don’t have enough time to do what the other
side wants.

The intransigence of such zero-sum disputes is a reminder of why win-win
fantasies are so attractive in the first place. Whatever the profound
differences between degrowth’s proponents and their critics, the scale of
the climate crisis suggests one point of convergence: We need all the
imaginative help we can get.
Jennifer Szalai is the nonfiction book critic for The Times.

Reply via email to