March 6, 2008
Bernstein, Luxemburg and Desai
Filed under: Introduction to Marxism class — louisproyect @ 5:28 pm 

http://louisproyect.wordpress.com/2008/03/06/bernstein-luxemburg-and-desai/

(This post was a contribution to the Introduction to Marxism mailing list, an 
online class.)

Over the next few days I will be posting material by and about Marxists in the 
“under-consumptionist” tradition. While reviewing this material for the past 
week or so, I was surprised to see how much the debates of the early 1900s 
paralleled debates within Marxism over the past 50 years or so. Given the 
similarities between the turn of the 20th and the turn of the 21st century, 
perhaps it should have not been a surprise at all.

In the late 1800s, there was little evidence that capitalism was a system that 
had reached its limits, especially in those countries that Karl Marx and 
Frederic Engels had regarded as most susceptible to socialist revolution. 
Despite having a powerful working class, Germany, France, the U.S. and Great 
Britain had seemed to discover a way to manage crisis and to offer workers 
improved wages and working conditions within the system. If socialism could be 
achieved piecemeal within the capitalist system, what need was there for risky 
revolutionary bids that might result in the destruction of the trade union 
movement and socialist parties.

These illusions were fostered by the long expansion of the capitalist system 
under imperialism. From the 1880s until the outbreak of WWI, there was little 
evidence of the system facing the kind of terminal conditions described in The 
Communist Manifesto of 1848:

The productive forces at the disposal of society no longer tend to further the 
development of the conditions of bourgeois property; on the contrary, they have 
become too powerful for these conditions, by which they are fettered, and so 
soon as they overcome these fetters, they bring disorder into the whole of 
bourgeois society, endanger the existence of bourgeois property. The conditions 
of bourgeois society are too narrow to comprise the wealth created by them. And 
how does the bourgeoisie get over these crises? On the one hand by enforced 
destruction of a mass of productive forces; on the other, by the conquest of 
new markets, and by the more thorough exploitation of the old ones. That is to 
say, by paving the way for more extensive and more destructive crises, and by 
diminishing the means whereby crises are prevented.

Just as the 1960s produced a New Left that questioned the viability of 
socialist revolution in the face of a seemingly crisis-free capitalist system, 
there were socialist thinkers in the earlier period that drew similar 
conclusions. Eduard Bernstein was the most important of them.

He lays out his perspectives in “Evolutionary Socialism“, including a sharp 
rebuke  to Rosa Luxemburg’s “under-consumptionist” economics:

But Marx himself has also occasionally pronounced very sharply against the 
derivation of crises from under-consumption. “It is pure tautology,” he writes 
in the second volume of Capital, “to say that crises rise from a want of 
consumers able to pay.” If one wished to give this tautology an appearance of 
greater reality by saying that the working classes receive too small a portion 
of what they produce, and that the grievance would therefore be redressed if 
they had a larger share, it can only be observed that “the crises are each time 
preceded by a period in which the workers’ wages rise and the working classes 
actually receive a relatively greater share than usual of the yearly produce 
destined for consumption.” It thus would appear that capitalist production 
“includes conditions independent of good or evil intentions – conditions which 
only permit of temporarily relative prosperity for the working classes and then 
always as a stormy bird of a crisis.” 

As was the case with the Russian legal Marxists, Bernstein draws upon the 
chapters in Volume Two of Capital that deal with “reproduction”, one of which 
John Imani described on Marxmail as “long and exceedingly difficult and 
boring”. There really is no point in trying to wend our way through Karl Marx’s 
formulas. The main point is that he was trying to describe what amounted to a 
business cycle in modern terms.

Bernstein writes:

In another passage of this second volume [of Capital], which had been written 
by 1870, the periodic character of crises -which is approximately a ten-year 
cycle of production-is brought into conjunction with the length of the turnover 
of fixed (laid out in machinery, etc.) capital. The development of capitalistic 
production has a tendency on the one hand to extend the bulk of value and the 
length of life of fixed capital, and on the other to diminish this life by a 
constant revolution of the means of production. Hence the “moral wearing out” 
of this portion of fixed capital before it is “physically spent.” Through this 
cycle of connected turnovers comprehending a series of years in which capital 
is confined through its fixed portion, arises a material cause for periodic 
crises in which the business passes through periods following one another of 
exhaustion, medium activity, precipitancy, crisis.

In this instance, the word crisis has an entirely different meaning than it 
does in Rosa Luxemburg. When Bernstein says that “business passes through 
periods following one another of exhaustion, medium activity, precipitancy, 
crisis,” he is simply describing what amounts to a business cycle in terms that 
you see in the NY Times business section. The U.S. is always going though some 
crisis or another (savings banks, LTCM, dot.com, subprime mortgage, etc.) but 
is always resolving it in anticipation of the next uptick in the business cycle.

In the chapter on “Simple and Expanded Reproduction” in The New Palgrave 
Marxian Economics, Meghnad Desai writes:

The result given in Capital 2, Chapter 21 aroused a long debate among Marxists. 
How could one reconcile this picture of an economy in perpetual balanced growth 
with Marx’s prediction elsewhere in his work of a capitalist economy riddled 
with crises and liable to breakdown as a result of increasing contradictions 
including a falling rate of profit despite growth and accumulation? Was Marx 
portraying the improbability of this outcome in absence of a planning mechanism 
that could order capitalists to invest a given proportion? Was this another 
example of a glaring inconsistency between different parts of Capital, as had 
been argued in the case of the value-price relationship by Bohm-Bawerk?

In the long debate that followed the publication of Capital Vol. 2, many 
attempts were made to alter the numerical magnitudes of Marx’s example to 
generate business cycles. The notion that disproportionality in the investment 
in and/or growth of the two sectors could cause cycles was developed by 
Tugan-Baranovsky. The centrality of Dept I investment decisions, although 
arbitrarily imposed by Marx, led to the development of theories of business 
cycle emphasizing the capital-goods industries as the source of these 
fluctuations (Aftalion, Spiethoff). But the most searching critical analysis of 
Marx’s scheme came from Rosa Luxemburg. The Accumulation of Capital offers both 
a survey of the pre-1914 debate in this area and an attempt to probe the 
reasons for the puzzle of a balanced growth equilibrium in a Marxian model.

That Marx is open to multiple and contrary interpretations should come as no 
surprise to anybody. When confronted by a misinterpretation of his thought, 
Marx was prompted to say something to the effect of “If that is Marxism, I am 
no Marxist.”

Part of Bernstein’s polemic against Rosa Luxemburg in “Evolutionary Socialism” 
involved a defense of the growth of cartels. Unlike Lenin and Luxemburg, 
Bernstein viewed such monopoly combinations as having the effect of controlling 
the excesses of the free market and creating conditions more favorable for the 
socialist system, which would also favor combinations of competing firms into 
state-owned enterprises. Bernstein wrote:

But so far as it is a means of a hothouse forcing of over-production, the 
associations of manufacturers meet this inflation of production in separate 
countries, and even internationally here and there, ever more frequently, by 
trying to regulate production as a Kartel, a syndicate, or a trust. Without 
embarking in prophecies as to its final power of life and work, I have 
recognised its capacity to influence the relation of productive activity to the 
condition of the market so far as to diminish the danger of crises.

Within fifteen years, these very syndicates would plunge Europe into the 
bloodiest war in human history. Bernstein’s confidence in the ability of 
cartels to “diminish the danger of crises” seems misplaced, to say the least.

A glance at Meghnad Desai’s subsequent career will reveal his affinity with 
Bernstein and Tugan-Baranovsky. As the author of the 2002 Verso book “Marx’s 
Revenge”, Desai took the rather novel position that Karl Marx would have 
favored “globalization”. On the Verso website, you can find this description of 
Desai’s book: “Desai argues that globalization, in bringing the possibility of 
open competition on world markets to producers in the Third World, has proved 
that capitalism is still capable of moving forwards.” Bernstein could not put 
it better.

And a May 19, 2002 Observer review of “Marx’s Revenge” finds Desai in 
accordance with the view presented in the Palgrave article, namely that Karl 
Marx was a prophet of “business cycle” economics:

Marx developed some pioneering economics. He was the first economist to 
incorporate an explanation of boom and bust within his theory. He constructed a 
simple model to show how profit came from the exploitation of the ’surplus 
value’ of labour. This led to the ups and downs of profitability. But in volume 
II of Das Kapital Marx calculates a numerical scheme of a capitalist economy 
which does not run into crisis and enjoys perpetual growth.

When you read that according to Desai Marx calculated a “numerical scheme of a 
capitalist economy which does not run into crisis and enjoys perpetual growth,” 
you really wonder what prompted Verso to publish such a silly book. This is not 
Marx the socialist revolutionary, but Marx the spiritual grandfather of Paul 
Krugman.

In my next post, I will deal with Rosa Luxemburg’s attitude toward colonialism, 
which she saw as a kind of pressure valve to deal with the contradictions of 
over-production. Needless to say, it has nothing to do with Desai’s assurance 
that “open competition on world markets to producers in the Third World” proves 
that capitalism is moving forward.

2 Comments » 
 
Did you mean to say “how much the debates of the early 1900s paralleled debates 
within Marxism over the past FIVE years or so” ?

Comment by Ruthless Critic — March 6, 2008 @ 7:34 pm 

 
Alain Badiou, in his new New Left Review article, says something similar to 
your analogy between the current 40-year “dry spell” and the 1871-1914 “dry 
spell” — but draws conclusions different from yours. I quote:

“Between the end of the first sequence and the beginning of the second there 
was a forty-year interval during which the communist hypothesis was declared to 
be untenable: the decades from 1871 to 1914 saw imperialism triumphant across 
the globe. Since the second sequence came to an end in the 1970s we have been 
in another such interval, with the adversary in the ascendant once more. What 
is at stake in these circumstances is the eventual opening of a new sequence of 
the communist hypothesis. But it is clear that this will not be—cannot be—the 
continuation of the second one. Marxism, the workers’ movement, mass democracy, 
Leninism, the party of the proletariat, the socialist state—all the inventions 
of the 20th century—are not really useful to us any more. At the theoretical 
level they certainly deserve further study and consideration; but at the level 
of practical politics they have become unworkable. The second sequence is over 
and it is pointless to try to restore it.

“At this point, during an interval dominated by the enemy, when new experiments 
are tightly circumscribed, it is not possible to say with certainty what the 
character of the third sequence will be. But the general direction seems 
discernible: it will involve a new relation between the political movement and 
the level of the ideological—one that was prefigured in the expression 
‘cultural revolution’ or in the May 68 notion of a ‘revolution of the mind’. We 
will still retain the theoretical and historical lessons that issued from the 
first sequence, and the centrality of victory that issued from the second.”

Comment by Ruthless Critic — March 7, 2008 @ 4:10 pm 



_______________________________________________
Marxism-Thaxis mailing list
Marxism-Thaxis@lists.econ.utah.edu
To change your options or unsubscribe go to:
http://lists.econ.utah.edu/mailman/listinfo/marxism-thaxis

Reply via email to