Capitalism, Socialism and Crisis
By Prabhat Patnaik  
http://www.politicalaffairs.net/article/articleview/8201/

 Original source: People's Democracy (India) 

A common view of the current financial crisis of capitalism holds
 that it is essentially an aberration. Some attribute this aberration to 
specific mistakes committed in the past, for instance by the US Federal Reserve 
with regard to monetary
 policy. Some hold the lack of adequate regulatory mechanism as being 
responsible for this aberration. Paul Krugman, the current year’s Nobel 
laureate, blames it on
 insufficient supervision of the financial system. And even Joseph Stiglitz, 
the well-known radical economist and Nobel laureate, characterizes it as a 
“system failure,” a term which makes the crisis a phenomenon that in principle 
could have been avoided with impunity.
 This entire perception however is untenable. The crisis is a result not of the 
failure of the system but of the system itself; it is a part of the mode of 
operation of contemporary capitalism rather than being unrelated or extraneous 
to it. 

Massive speculation 

In a “free market” regime, asset markets tend to be subject to
 speculation. Speculators buy assets not because of the yield on these assets 
but because they expect its price to appreciate in the coming days. They have 
no long term
 interest in the assets and are concerned exclusively with capital
 gains. Since buying today to sell tomorrow entails carrying the asset during 
the intervening period for which a “carrying cost” has to be incurred, the 
assets most suitable for speculation are those whose carrying costs are low; 
and these are typically financial assets
 which have virtually zero carrying costs (requiring only a few taps on 
computer keys to effect all necessary transactions). Financial asset markets 
therefore are
 always subject to massive speculation. 

Speculation generates bouts of euphoria or “speculative excitement” 
which have the cumulative effect of pushing up asset prices. An initial rise in 
some asset prices, caused no matter how, gives rise to expectations of a 
further rise, and hence
 to an increase in the demand for the assets in question which actually raises 
their prices further; and so the process feeds upon itself and we have asset 
price “bubbles.” 
Such “bubbles” typically characterize financial assets, which, as already 
mentioned, are particularly prone to speculation; but they are not confined to 
financial assets
 alone (as the housing market “bubble” in the United States has just 
demonstrated). 

Such “bubbles” have an obvious impact on the real economy. The 
rise in asset prices fed by speculative euphoria improves for individuals who 
own these assets the estimation of their wealth position, and hence causes an 
increase in 
their consumption expenditure, and thereby in employment. Likewise such a rise 
in asset prices, where the assets in question are producible, causes an 
increase in
 investment expenditure on these assets, which leads to their larger 
production, and hence to larger employment. In short, speculative euphoria in 
the asset markets makes
 the boom in the real economy, stimulated by whatever had caused the initial 
rise in asset prices, more pronounced and prolonged. 

Precisely because of this however if for some reason the asset price
 increase wanes or comes to a halt, speculators attempt to get out of the 
assets in question causing a crash in the asset prices. This causes a fall in 
aggregate expenditure
 on goods and services; a collapse in the state of credit, as banks face 
insolvency; and a possible collapse even in the inclination of depositors for 
holding bank deposits (since they fear banks’ insolvency), as had happened 
during the Great Depression. In short
 there is a collapse of the state of confidence all around, and hence a 
corresponding increase in liquidity preference; i.e. there is a disinclination 
to hold any asset other than 
pure cash, or in extreme cases only currency, and of course claims upon the 
government, which is considered to be the only safe and reliable borrower. Not 
all crises display
 this severity; but to a greater or lesser extent these features mark any 
crisis. 

Speculation therefore has the effect of making the boom more pronounced
 and prolonged; but it has also the effect of precipitating a severe crisis, as 
distinct from a mere cyclical downturn. In the absence of speculation the boom 
in the real economy will 
be a much more truncated and tame affair. But precisely because it is not a 
tame affair, it is followed by a crisis. 

Two conclusions follow from the above analysis. First, since speculation
 is endemic to modern capitalism, where financial markets play a major role, 
speculation-engendered euphoria and the consequent pronounced booms, together 
with the crises
 that invariably follow, are also endemic to modern capitalism. “Bubbles” 
constitute in other words the mode of operation of the system. “Bubbles,” 
together with the crises that
 follow their collapse, are not a “system-failure”; they are the system. 
Secondly, if “bubbles” are to be eliminated and speculation is to be curbed, 
then it is not enough to put 
in place some regulatory mechanisms; an alternative instrument for generating 
pronounced booms in the real economy has to be found, for otherwise the economy 
would remain
 perennially sunk in stagnation and large-scale mass unemployment. 

The alternative instrument suggested by John Maynard Keynes, the 
well-known English economist, was State intervention through fiscal measures to 
ensure that the level of demand remained as close to full employment as 
possible. Keynes’ suggestion, made in the 1930s during the Great Depression, 
was strongly opposed by finance capital,
 which always opposes all State intervention that does not promote its own 
exclusive interest. The Keynesian remedy got accepted only in the post-war 
period when the
 balance of class forces had shifted, with the working class, which had made 
immense sacrifices during the war, acquiring greater social and political 
weight, and finance capital,
 experiencing a corresponding weakening of its position, forced to make 
concessions. 

Over time however this balance changed once again. “Centralization of
 capital” and the formation of larger and larger blocs of finance capital, 
during the period of Keynesian demand management itself, forced open the 
barriers imposed on cross
 border financial flows. Finance capital consequently acquired the nature of 
international finance capital, through a process of “globalization of finance.” 
Since the whims of
 international finance capital necessarily had to triumph over the autonomous 
predilections the nation-State, in order to avoid capital flight, Keynesian 
“demand management” 
was rejected, and neo-liberal capitalism emerged triumphant again, bringing 
back the era of speculative financial crises, leading to real crises, in the 
capitalist world. This is the
 phenomenon we are currently witnessing, a phenomenon that has been compared 
with the Great Depression of the 1930s. 

Socialist economy immune to crises 

One of the hallmarks of the 1930s Great Depression is that the 
Soviet Union, the only socialist economy of the time, had been completely 
unaffected by it. In fact, when capitalism had been afflicted by the severe 
crisis, the Soviet Union 
had experienced such unprecedented economic construction that it had completely 
got rid of unemployment. This fact, as is well-known, had so impressed a 
whole generation of Indian freedom fighters, like E. M. S. Namboodiripad, that 
they had embraced Communism because of it. 

This contrast arises owing to a fundamental difference between the 
mode of operation of the two systems. A socialist economy is fundamentally 
immune not just to speculation-induced crises but to all crises arising from a 
deficiency
 of aggregate demand. This fact is recognized even by staunch opponents of 
socialism like the Hungarian economist Janos Kornai who calls capitalism a 
“demand-constrained system” and socialism a “resource-constrained system” where 
the available resources are fully utilized without being constrained by 
insufficient demand. 

A socialist economy of course has the usual fiscal instrument 
suggested by Keynes for overcoming deficiency of aggregate demand, unlike a 
capitalist economy where the use of this instrument requires overcoming 
opposition from
 finance capital, and where, even when the instrument is perchance used, there 
is a limit to its use arising from the fact that the system, being based on 
antagonism,
 needs a sufficiently large reserve army of labour to prevent inflation and 
maintain “work discipline.” But even apart from this, a socialist economy can 
overcome deficiency of aggregate demand in another way which brings out its 
basic character. 

In any economy where in any period the money wages are given, 
the production of a certain output requires a certain unit cost of production 
to be incurred. The term “deficiency of aggregate demand” or “insufficient 
demand” simply 
means that the level of demand in the economy is such that this output can be 
sold only at a price that falls below this unit cost of production plus the 
customary profit margin.
 When this happens, then in a capitalist economy firms cut back on output, so 
that there is unemployment; and this gives rise to a further reduction in 
demand 
since the workers’ demand shrinks owing to unemployment; and this causes a 
further reduction in output and employment; and so the process, referred to as 
the “multiplier” 
effect of the initial output/employment decline, goes on and the economy is 
caught in a crisis. 

In a socialist economy however since firms are socially owned, the 
State can issue a directive asking them to lower prices when they initially 
find that the demand for output at the base price, i.e. at the price equal to 
the unit cost plus profit
 margin, is less than the output. While issuing this directive it can assure 
the firms that any losses they make will be covered from the State budget. In 
such a case, firms
 simply lower their prices to clear the market, and there is no question of any 
unemployment to start with, and hence no question of any “multiplier effect.” 
Putting it differently,
 in a capitalist economy any decrease in demand gives rise to “output 
adjustment” and hence “employment adjustment”; in a socialist economy it can 
give rise only to “price adjustment” and keep output unchanged. 

Why does this difference arise? When price adjusts downwards, since
 the money wage rate is given, there is an increase in the real wage rate. So, 
a socialist economy, faced with a decline in aggregate demand, gets rid of it 
by raising real wages
 of workers, i.e. by raising the demand of the workers. But a capitalist 
economy, precisely because it is based on class antagonism, where the slightest 
increase in the wage
 rate is bitterly opposed by capitalists, will never raise real wages to get 
rid of demand deficiency. This is why any such deficiency gives rise to output 
adjustment, and hence mass unemployment. 

But now we come to the real crux of the matter. It was mentioned 
above that the socialist State, while directing firms to reduce prices to clear 
markets, would assure them that any losses they incur would be covered by the 
State budget, i.e.
 that they would get a State subsidy to cover their losses. The question may be 
asked: how does the State finance these losses? And the answer interestingly is 
that for all the firms taken together there will be no losses. In other words, 
while the State issues this directive it will never be actually called upon to 
make any additional budgetary provisions for subsidies. True, 
firms in the aggregate will make less profits after price adjustment than they 
otherwise would have done in the absence of the original deficiency of 
aggregate demand; but they will make profits in the aggregate all the same. The 
State may at the most have to divert the profits
 of some firms to cover the losses of others, but it will have to make no 
additional provisions. This follows from the fact that since profits in any 
period in a socialist economy 
are more or less synonymous with the savings of the economy, and since 
(ignoring external borrowing/lending), investment in any period must equal 
savings, 
as long as investment remains positive, profits in the aggregate must remain 
positive no matter what the level of aggregate demand. 

A socialist economy, being both free of antagonism (so that real 
wages can be raised) and free of anarchy (so that some firms’ profits can be 
diverted to cover others’ losses), has thus a mode of functioning that makes it 
in principle
 immune to crises, caused by the deficiency of aggregate demand, which afflict 
capitalism. 

In the present context 

So far we have discussed the inner workings of a socialist 
economy that is unconnected with world capitalism through trade and financial 
relations. Since the Soviet Union in the 1930s was unconnected with world 
capitalism, and even later had only tenuous links, it remained actually immune 
to crises of aggregate demand. But what can be said of a socialist economy that 
is closely linked to the capitalist world through trade and financial 
relationships? Does such an economy continue to remain immune to crises of 
aggregate demand, especially those emanating from the capitalist world? 

In an economy where all important means of production are socially
 owned, the answer in principle should still be “yes.” When exports of such an 
economy decline, it is always open to it to raise domestic demand, either 
through the fiscal route suggested to capitalism by Keynes, i.e. through larger 
State expenditure, or through larger workers’ 
consumption via a rise in the real wage rate, caused by the lowering of prices 
for a given money wage rate, as discussed above. Since the rationale of the 
socialist economy’s
 participation in the world market is that it has generally lower prices than 
the capitalist world (at the prevailing exchange rate), which after all is why 
it is able to out-compete the capitalist countries and have burgeoning trade 
with them, any further lowering of its domestic prices in 
response to the reduced demand owing to world recession, should cause no 
“leakages” in the form of larger imports. Such reduction in other words should 
boost its own 
domestic demand, and, if anything, even help somewhat in countering export 
decline. Likewise, if it provided a larger fiscal stimulus, as China has 
announced it would, then
 the main impact of such a stimulus should be on its own domestic demand. In 
short the socialist weapons against crises mentioned earlier remain intact even 
when the
 socialist country has trade relations with the capitalist world. 

Of course switching from export production to production for the home market 
may take some time, during which there may be transitional unemployment, but 
this is very
 different from the unemployment encountered in capitalist countries during a 
crisis. 

The problem however may arise from a different source, namely when
 in the process of entering into relations with capitalist countries, the 
socialist economy has also accommodated within its midst a large private 
sector, owned by
 powerful capitalists from home and abroad. There would be resistance from them 
to the use of the standard socialist weapons against crises, just as there is 
resistance from capitalists in capitalist countries to the use of similar 
weapons, and indeed for the very same reasons.
 It follows in such a case that the capacity of the socialist economy to thwart 
a crisis arising from the deficiency of aggregate demand, depends upon the 
strength of the
 socialist State in confronting the opposition of the internal capitalists to 
the socialist measures against the crisis. 

_______________________________________________
Marxism-Thaxis mailing list
Marxism-Thaxis@lists.econ.utah.edu
To change your options or unsubscribe go to:
http://lists.econ.utah.edu/mailman/listinfo/marxism-thaxis

Reply via email to