[here's a report on creative labour that I've written for the fibreculture list. It may be of interest to nettimers in light of the recent "DISTRIBUTED CREATIVITY" threads. For those of you after "Executive summaries only", here you go:
Reflexivity and Empirical Research Creativity - What's in a Name? Intellectual Property and Creativity Intellectual Property and the Labour Contract Intellectual Property and (Dis)Organised Labour Multitudes and the Exploitation of Network Sociality Immaterial or Disorganised Labour? Conclusions For those after something more substantive, read on....] [PART 1/2] Report: Creative Labour and the role of Intellectual Property By Ned Rossiter, September 2003 Here's my report based on the survey I conducted for the fibrepower panel initiated by Kate Crawford and Esther Milne - Intellectual Property-Intellectual Possibilities (Brisbane, July 03). I wanted to explore in some empirical fashion the relationship between intellectual property and creative labour. Why? Largely because such a relationship is the basis for defining what is meant by creative industries, according to the seminal and much cited mapping document produced by Blair's Creative Industries Task Force (CITF). Despite the role IP plays in defining and providing a financial and regulatory architecture for the creative and other informational or knowledge industries, there is remarkably little attention given by researchers and commentators to the implications of IP in further elaborating conceptual, political and economic models for the creative industries. There is even greater indifference towards addressing the impact of exploiting the IP of those whose labour power has been captured: young people, for the most part, working in the creative and culture industries. Angela McRobbie's work is one of the few exceptions. At a different level, I was curious to see how a mailing list might contribute in a collaborative fashion to the formation of a research inquiry in which the object of study - creative labour and IP - is partially determined by the list itself. Finally, after levelling critiques at various times and occasions against what Terry Flew (2001) identifies as the 'new media empirics', I thought it necessary to engage in a more direct way with this nemesis-object: what, after all, can a new media empirics do and become when it is driven through what I've developed elsewhere (or rather, syphoned from larger and older media theory, informatics and philosophy debates) as a processual model of media and communications? (Rossiter, 2003b) I'll address this question in the concluding section of this report. As I noted in an earlier paper (Rossiter, 2003a) posted to fc: The list of sectors identified as holding creative capacities in the CITF Mapping Document include: film, music, television and radio, publishing, software, interactive leisure software, design, designer fashion, architecture, performing arts, crafts, arts and antique markets, architecture and advertising. The Mapping Document seeks to demonstrate how these sectors consist of '... activities which have their origin in individual creativity, skill and talent and which have the potential for wealth and job creation through generation and exploitation of intellectual property' (CITF: 1998/2001). The CITF's identification of intellectual property as central to the creation of jobs and wealth firmly places the creative industries within informational and knowledge economies. In posting the survey questionnaire to the list, I was interested in ascertaining the following: 1. the extent to which respondents perceived their primary activities (i.e., activities other than eating, sleeping, watching TV, having sex, substance abuse, etc -- though I guess many would argue that they are indeed primary activities, and perhaps also creative ones!) to correspond with "creativity", however that term might be understood (n.b., the survey synopsis clearly framed creativity in relation to the Creative Industries discourse, so the latitude for interpreting the term creativity was relatively circumscribed). 2. whether a very partial mapping of the fc network produced results similar to the sectors identified in the CITF Mapping Document. Whatever the results, I was interested in what they might then say about national, regional or State manifestations of the creative industries: is Australia's CI the same as the UK? Is there a temporal factor at work? (i.e., given the time of development, incubation, etc., would a mapping exercise produce different results depending of when and how it was conducted?) 3. to establish whether respondents perceived or understood an extant relationship between their labour and intellectual property. 4. to find out whether IP in the workplace makes work a political issue. At the time of the survey, the fc list had just over 700 subscribers (June, 03). All responses came on the same day I posted the survey, most within a few hours of it appearing on list. (This in itself perhaps says something interesting about the 'attention economy' of email lists and the time in which any posting may receive a response: i.e., while the Stones could sing about the redundancy of newspapers after a day, do list postings have a life of 3 or so hours? Not so bad actually, though it's probably much less - more like seconds, depending on whether a post is read or not.) Of the 700 or so subscribers then, I received 7 responses. That's 1% of all list subscribers, a lovely sample to be sure. One of the respondents provided a follow-up response as well. There was one other query from someone asking whether they could do the survey even though they thought they weren't a creative worker; they were a copyright lawyer - a category Richard Florida assigns to 'creative professionals' - 'business and finance, law, health care and related fields") as distinct from the core Creative Class: 'people in science and engineering, architecture and design, education, art, music and entertainment, whose economic function is to create new ideas, new technology and/or new creative content' (2002: 8). Curiously, there is no mention - at least in this initial definition - of the role intellectual property plays in constituting a 'creative class'.1 No doubt there are national-cultural and socio-political explanations for the differences between how creative workers are perceived and constituted in the UK and North America. To my knowledge, there is yet to be a study that inquires into the different national and regional formations of creative industries/classes/economies/cultures. One could argue that OECD research papers and reports along with those by neo-conservative, libertarian think-tanks such as Demos and the Cato Institute do such work; however, while they certainly compile statistics and bring a dual mode of commentary and hyperbole to such figures, they do very little by way of historical, political economy and cultural analysis of the variable conditions that have led to the emergence of creative labour and its attendant industries across these geopolitical regions. REFLEXIVITY and EMPIRICAL RESEARCH While the sample I'm drawing on is most certainly small, it is not insignificant. Indeed, I think its minutiae corresponds to larger patterns of creative labour in Australia, and most probably elsewhere, as I extrapolate below. Interestingly, I'm told by a psychologist friend researching the formation of depression in migrants that current, more reflexive literature on quantitative, empirical research argues that the fuss over sample sizes (i.e., the need to have a large sample if the claims/results are to have any scholastic purchase on the phantasm of veridicality) is problematic in all sorts of ways (see Edwards, 1997; Silverman, 2001). For instance, at what point can one say a sample is representative of the community, user-consumers, demographic, socio-technical network, etc. under analysis? As Pierre Bourdieu (1973) argued so acutely and with such verve, public opinion does not exist. What exists, for Bourdieu, is the discursive form of the survey or opinion poll, the interests that drive it, and the ends to which it is put. Of course my own survey is not immune from the sort of critical, theoretical and political interests I bring to the analysis of responses. Then there's the whole pseudo-scientific language of "observation", as though there might have ever been some sort of impartiality underpinning the process of enacting the survey. Scott Lash associates such a paradigm with "reflective modernisation" and the work of Giddens, Habermas and Parsonian structural functionalism and linear systems theory: 'The idea of reflective belongs to the philosophy of consciousness of the first modernity.... To reflect is to somehow subsume the object under the subject of knowledge. Reflection presumes apodictic knowledge and certainty. It presumes a dualism, a scientific attitude in which the subject is in one realm, the object of knowledge in another' (2003: 51). In contrast to a reflective first modernity, Lash posits a reflexive second modernity and non-linear systems of communication and risk comprising of quasi-objects and subjects and their theorisation by the likes of Luhmann, Beck and Latour, along with Castells' network logic of flows: 'Second modernity reflexivity is about the emergent *demise* of the distinction between structure and agency altogether.... Second-modernity reflexivity presumes a move towards immanence that breaks with the [ontological] dualisms of structure and agency.... The reflexivity of the second modernity presumes the existence of non-linear systems. Here system dis-equilibrium and change are produced internally to the system through feedback loops. These are open systems. Reflexivity now is at the same time system *de*-stabilization' (2003: 49-50). The extent to which reflexive non-linear systems wholly dispense with or depart from a constitutive outside in favour of a logic of immanence is a problematic I have begun to question with other fc members in an earlier posting to the list (Rossiter, 2003a).2 Like the question of and tension between new media empirics and processual media theory, it is a problematic I'll return to in my concluding remarks. I think one reason I received even 7 responses had much to do with prior knowledges and trust established between myself as "observer" and the "participants" in this survey: ie, I had either met or knew very well 6 of the 7 respondents. Here, it is worth turning again to Bourdieu (1992), who frames the concept of reflexivity in particularly succinct terms: 'What distresses me when I read some works by sociologists is that people whose profession is to objectivize the social world prove so rarely able to objectivize themselves, and fail so often to realize that what their apparently scientific discourse talks about is not the object but their relation to the object' (68-69). Put in terms of non-linear systems theory, the on- and off-line relationships, trust and symbolic economy I had established largely through an online network operated as a feedback loop into the call for interest in and responses to this current survey. Obvious as it may sound, this very historical and social dimension to a communicative present actively destabilises any rhetorical claims that I might attempt in the name of conducting a survey that follows the scientific principles of objectivity and impartiality and methodologies befitting quantitative research. The only thing that is remotely impartial about this survey is the anonymity of the respondents as I present them here. Feedback loops further destabilise the very object-ness of this report as a discrete posting to a mailing list insofar as anyone who responds to this report breaks up components of the report by way of selective quoting or paraphrasing and interjecting their own critiques or comments. Many of us do this when we reply to an email, separating the sender's text from our own; in so doing, we are translating or mimicking the effect of dialogue. Such a process is registered in a material, symbolic form in the dissipative, non-linear structure of discussion threads as they appear in the mailing list's archives. Further registration of feedback loops are made in the googlisation of this combinatory knowledge and information formation, where any particular posting has the potential to move up the vertical scale of "hits" depending on the key words used in the user's search, the online links made to the posting, and the popularity of the posting: in short, the coding of the google software program plays a determining role in the hierarchisation of information that is then further shaped by the interests and habits of users. The economy and architecture of the google search engine has been subject to considerable debate and discussion in lists such as fc and nettime, along with many other online fora, print and electronic media. If this posting, for example, were made on any number of web conferencing systems, collaborative text filtering sites or blogs, such as slashdot.org, indymedia.org, makeworld.org or discordia (http://discordia.us), then a very different information architecture of feedback loops would prevail. Ok, time now to get to some substance of the survey. CREATIVITY - What's In a Name? When I asked respondents what creative activities they engaged in, a list of 4-6 fields, practices or sectors of creativity by any one person was compiled. These included writing, performing and producing music; writing academic and policy papers (considered by one respondent and assumed by others as 'creative endeavours'); photography; design (interactive, information, education); publishing and editing; new media arts (dv, net.art, print, electronic music); painting; and creative writing. Three things stand out for me here: 1) Irrespective of whether or not respondents went on to identify themselves as part of the Creative Industries project, however that might be understood, the range of creative activities any single person might undertake suggests that diversity rather than specialisation is a defining feature of creative workers. This isn't to say that specialisation doesn't occur in any particular idiom of creativity - I think it's safe to assume that it would, but rather that respondents were not limited to one particular set creative skills, trainings, or passions. Thus these respondents are clear exemplars of the so-called fragmented postmodern subject, traversing a range of institutional locations and cultural dispositions. 2) Many of the respondents are engaged in academic work either on a full-time, continuing basis or as sessional, casual teachers. In both cases, university related activities and non-university related activities were assumed to hold creative dimensions. If nothing else, the diversity of creative activities identified by respondents indicates the complexity of labour in the contemporary university, further suggesting that: a) the university cannot accommodate the diverse interests and economic necessities of its constituent labour power, and/or b) that individuals wish to distinguish between the kind of work they do at university and its concomitant values and the kind of work they do outside the university, or c) that there is zone of indistinction, if you will, between the university and its so-called outside, given that all sectors of cultural production and intellectual labour are today subject to market economies. The extent to which tensions exist between these realms, or whether they are better characterised as a sort of zone of indistinction that cannot be reduced in such a manner, varies, I suspect, according to the contingencies of time, interests, values, labour conditions, age, class, gender, etc. of individuals as they are located in different institutional settings. Each of the above possibilities corresponds with the economic and labour conditions peculiar to the creative industries operating in the UK, as McRobbie explains: 'Those working in the creative sector cannot simply rely on old working patterns associated with art worlds, they have to find new ways of "working" the new cultural economy, which increasingly means holding down three or even four "projects" at once. In addition, since these projects are usually short term, there have to be other jobs to cover the short-fall when the project ends. The individual becomes his or her own enterprise, sometimes presiding over two separate companies at the same time' (2002: 519; see also Beck, 1992: 127-150; Bauman, 2001: 17-30). 3) There is much overlap between this list of creative activities and the CITF's list of creative sectors, with the exception that traditional arts and crafts and antiques do not figure in the former; this comes as no surprise, given that the survey was conducted on a listserve for critical Internet research and culture. As for how this list relates to Richard Florida's composition of the Creative Class in the US, there is an obvious absence in my survey of engineers and scientists. Again, you might say this should come as no surprise; one could, however, describe software programmers, "codeworkers", game designers, etc. as computer scientists or information engineers - though no doubt there'd be some disciplinary and perhaps ontological dispute over this. Having established that they all are engaged in creative activities of one kind or another, there were then considerable differences amongst respondents as to whether they perceived themselves as engaged in the Creative Industries. Two respondents said they didn't - one being a bit hesitant as to whether they did or not, the other indifferent, implying the term was no more than a 'tag' associated with 'official places' and 'certain faculties'. Four respondents stated that they did associate their activities with the Creative Industries, some more emphatically so than others. One of those responded by writing that 'Yeah, but I'm a special case :)', indicating that creativity, at least for this person, comes with a sense of individuality, difference and exception. Yet such subjectivities carry more baggage than this. As Angela McRobbie notes, 'Individualization is not about individuals *per se*, as about new, more fluid, less permanent social relations seemingly marked by choice or options. However, this convergence has to be understood as one of contestation and antagonism' (2002: 518). Much of this report seeks to unravel various tensions that underpin labour practices within the creative industries. A seventh respondent took a more reflexive, marxian and historically informed position, choosing to problematise and open up the question in the following way: 'All industry is creative; all human activity creates something; and nearly all human activity is subsumed under industrial imperatives (including the consumption of media and other products). Therefore I think this is probably a question whose answer is presupposed in the historical facts of its own terms'. On these grounds, then, irrespective of whether respondents did or didn't identify their creative activities with Creative Industries, there is a sense amongst these respondents - perhaps unconscious - that there is an "idea" of what constitutes the creative industries, and respondent's identification with those industries is based, perhaps, on whether one meets the criteria or fits into the discursive boundaries, categories, or ethos of the Creative Industries, as established in part in the survey's preamble. INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY and CREATIVITY The importance of intellectual property (copyrights, patents, trademarks) as a source of income was met with a mixed response. For one person it was important, for the rest it wasn't, at least in an exclusive sense: labour was paid for on an hourly basis or IP was assigned to the company or publisher commissioning the work; in other instances remuneration from IP contributed to a respondent's income, but wasn't relied upon as a primary source of income. Creative workers were thus primarily alienated from their intellectual property in one form or another. Such a response clearly signals a tension and power relationship with regard to the CITF definition of creative industries as those activities that have 'the potential for wealth and job creation through generation and exploitation of intellectual property'. Thus despite all the rhetoric around informational and creative labour consisting of "horizontal" and "fluid" modes of production, distribution and exchange, clearly there remains vertical, hierarchical dimensions within the "New Economy". If IP is to function as the mainstay of capital accumulation within informational economies, it doesn't take much imagination to foresee industrial, legal and political dispute focussing on the juridico-political architecture of IP. The extent to which workers are able to mobilise their potential power in an effective manner (i.e., in a way that protects and secures their interests whilst inventing new information architectures) depends, I would suggest, on their capacity to organise themselves as a sociopolitical force. I'll address this issue in relation to the problem of immaterial labour in more detail below. Respondents found IP a source of tension not only at the level of financial remuneration; a tension prevailed around the concept of IP as well. In response to the question of whether intellectual property is important as a principle - that is, as a system or framework consisting of rules and beliefs that enables the transformation of labour into legal, moral and potentially economic values - one person stated that they found it of no importance at all. All others found it was, though the response, as expected, was mixed: 'Yes, but in a negative sense. The whole structure of IP has turned into a perversion of its intended principles: namely, that alienation rather than one's inalienable rights in one's own work is the guiding principle of IP law. Put differently, rights are seen to exist only so that they can be sold. That is a function of capital, long since dead. I would prefer a rights structure that existed to ensure the free flow of ideas'. In a similar vein, though without the libertarian overtone, another respondent writes: 'It is important to me as a principle to be critiqued, developed and (in some cases) rejected. The arm of IP is extending in several directions and in many industries - and it's that reach that needs to be reviewed with some urgency'. A third respondent strongly rejected the idea that IP might be understood in terms of principles: 'No', they write, 'It's important to me as a discursive field!' By my reading, such a statement suggests that the respondent understands principles as holding some kind of unchanging, transcendental and universal status, while a discursive field is historically and culturally mutable and holds the potential for local intervention by actors endowed with such capacities. (A similar distinction is often made in philosophy between the universality of morals and the contingencies of ethics.) The idea of IP as a discursive field rather than a principle is also interesting in relation to the second response tabled above, which implies that limits need to be established with regard to IP and the extent to which it governs areas of life previously outside a market economy. Current debates around patenting the human genome, database access to DNA information on sperm and embryo composition and their relationship to insurance premiums and future employment possibilities (see Gattica for the filmic version of this scenario), the pressure on developing countries to import GM food coupled with uneven, neo-colonial trade agreements along with conditions imposed by the World Bank and IMF's structural adjustment programs, and so forth are the most obvious examples that come to mind here. INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY and the LABOUR CONTRACT The tension associated with IP was further extended to the workplace, with all but one of the respondents noting that they had heard of and in some instances personally experienced conflicts over IP issues. If such accounts are the norm rather than the exception, this clearly signals a need for much greater attention to be given to the role of IP in the workplace, and the status it holds as a legal and social architecture governing the conditions of creative production, job satisfaction, employer-employee relations and thus life in general. While only two respondents reported of losing a job or contract for refusing to assign IP to their employer, many commented on the problems of such a condition - as one person noted: 'This is common in film music now: if you don't sell your rights to the film maker, you are not given the contract'. Another highlighted the legal and institutional distinction between private and state sectors. Addressing the Australian situation, this respondent notes that government bodies such as councils and departments 'are exempt from recognising author rights under the current copyright act - therefore to refuse to hand over intellectual rights in these cases is to refuse to work'. Here is a curious and paradoxical case in point in which the call to a 'refusal of work' - derived from 1960s radical workers' movements of the 1960s by Italian autonomists such as Paolo Virno - is jerry-wired into the system itself, albeit with a significant proviso of political proportion. The autonomists seek to liberate work from relations of waged labour and the capitalist State; to unleash 'a mass defection or exodus' and in so doing subtract the labour power which sustains the capitalist system, affirming the 'creative potential of our practical capacities' in the process (see Hardt, 1996: 6). There's a bit of a different rub, however, in a capitalist logic of post-Fordist flexible accumulation, whose modes of social and political regulation set the scene for our current informational paradigm. While the worker within Fordist systems of assembly-line mass production and mass consumption conditions the possibility of, to refer to the classic example, the assemblage of motor vehicles that, ideally, are then sold to the consumer who built the vehicle in their 8 hour working day, the case of IP and creative labour operates in substantially different ways. Within an informational paradigm, the appropriation of labour power by capitalists does not result in a product so much as a potential. This potential takes the "immaterial" form of intellectual property whose value is largely unquantifiable and is subject to the vagaries of speculative finance markets, "New Economy" style. Thus, in the case of government institutions that don't recognise an individual's IP rights, there is nothing to 'hand over' in the first instance. That is, the right to a refusal of work is not possible; or put differently, the creative potential or work, as registered in and transformed into the juridico-political form of IP, is undermined by the fact that such a social relation - the hegemonic form of legitimacy - is not recognised. As noted by another respondent: 'I don't think you "lose" a contract for refusing to sign IP over ... it's more like you never had it in the first place if you do work for hire'. Instead, one does not so much refuse to work as decline to provide a service, whose economic value as wage labour - that is, labour separated from its product (Marx in Harvey, 1990:104) - bears no relationship to the potential economic value generated by the exploitation of IP. In effect, then, "creativity" goes right under the radar. Prostitution functions in a similar manner. One does not buy "love" from the prostitute, one acquires a "service" in the form of an orgasm, or "little death", with no value in and of itself. The prostitute's love does not figure in the relationship; love is off the radar. Like intellectual property, the expression of the orgasm in a given form - sperm, for the male who appropriates the labour power of the prostitute - nevertheless holds the potential to translate into economic, social, political and biological values if its eruption is arranged under different conditions - the normative ones peculiar to heterosexual couplings living in advanced economies, for example. A couple of respondents, both now working in the higher education sector, had mixed responses to the kind of conditions such a setting enabled vis-à-vis labour and IP. Respondent 1: 'I would always give in [and sign over IP] when I was self-employed, now I only take jobs where I'm happy with the IP arrangements'. Such a position is possible when, as noted earlier, IP is not the primary source of income. Interestingly, the other respondent anticipates conflicts over the assignation of IP within university settings - Respondent 2: 'as i continue to collaborate in university settings, the problem will arise'. The problem of job security arises where IP policies can vary substantially from university to university and at an intra-university level depending on the kind of contract an individual is able to negotiate with management as universities undergo increasingly deregulation toward a system that destroys the legal concept fought for by unions of collective wage agreements. At my own university, to take a typical example of someone working in the higher education sector, the subject materials I produce are the intellectual property of the university. These educational materials will often incorporate parts of articles I have written or am in the process of writing. (They will also include lists of references to articles and debates located in open-access online repositories, as found in the fibreculture and nettime archives, for example.) And here, a curious institutional tension over IP emerges: depending on the publisher, the IP of articles and books I write belongs to the publisher. One of the respondents noted how this problem of proprietary rights of academic IP has been dealt with in recent legislation in Australia: 'the new IP rules (e.g., the one which came into effect on 14th March) gives the university ownership of all IP created by staff (with a 'scholarly work' exception). This creates major problems - for example, academics moving to different universities who intend to use educational materials they have developed previously'. Thus the extent to which IP functions as an architecture of control is and has always been dubious at the level of the everyday. Just think of what happened with the appearance of the xerox machine in university settings - in effect it became a free license to appropriate the property of writers, with myriad staff and students reproducing the pages of otherwise copyright protected materials. Even if the legal aspects of IP are frequently difficult if not impossible to regulate, there are important symbolic dimensions to IP that have implications and impacts at the level of subjectivities and their degree of legitimacy within institutional and national settings. Here I am thinking - yet again - of that rather chilling line in the CITF's definition of the Creative Industries in which IP is not only generated, but more significantly, it is *exploited*. The exploitation of IP is not simply a matter of extracting the potential economic value from some inanimate thing; the exploitation of IP, let us never forget, is always already an exploitation of people, of the producers of that which is transformed from practice into property, which in its abstraction is then alienated from those who have produced it. While there are clear problems with such a system, IPRs are not necessarily a bad thing. As I've argued elsewhere, to simply oppose IPRs is not a political option (Rossiter, 2002). Individuals and communities must look for ways in which IPRs can be exploited for strategic ends. Such a political manoeuvre is possible, for instance, in efforts to advance Indigenous sovereignty. To return to the relationship between the exploitation of IP and the political status of subjectivity, it should be noted that QUT holds a policy in which students retain control of all IP they produce, with some exceptions.3 Such a policy initiative seems to be the exception within an environment of "enterprise universities" (Marginson and Considine, 2000) whose economic viability depends upon obtaining the maximum leverage possible within a political economy of partial deregulation. INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY and (DIS)ORGANISED LABOUR Most of the respondents corrected the assumption in my question on the relationship between collaborative production and the difficulty of assigning IP rights to individuals or joint-authorship. Respondents noted that corporations own the creative efforts of both individuals and collaborations, since the corporation has paid for that work. This brings me to the final component of the survey - the relationship between IP and the problem of disorganised labour. It seems to me that unions are among the best placed actors to contest the seemingly foregone conclusion that corporations have an a priori hold on the appropriation of labour power. As Castells has noted in a recent interview: '... with the acceleration of the work process [enabled by new ICTs], worker's defense continues to be a fundamental issue: they cannot count on their employers. The problem is that the individualization of management/worker relationships makes the use of traditional forms of defense, in terms of collective bargaining and trade union-led struggles, very difficult except in the public sector. Unions are realizing this and finding new forms of pressure, sometimes in the form of consumer boycotts to press for social justice and human rights. Also, individual explosions of violence by defenseless workers could be considered forms of resistance' (Castells and Ince, 2003: 29). However, there is an impasse of paradigmatic proportion to the potential for unions to assist workers - particularly younger workers - within creative industries or knowledge and information economies. The so-called strategy of consumer sovereignty is a relatively weak one, and only further entrenches the problem of individualisation inasmuch as the potential for a coalition amongst workers is only further sidelined in favour of that mantra urged on by our politicians who are so keen to protect "the national interest" -- yes, the national economy is fragile, so enjoy yourself and go out and shop! There is a general perception that unions and their capacity to organise labour in politically effective and socially appealing ways are a thing of the past. To address this issue I will first table comments from respondents. I will then move on to the thesis of "immaterial labour", as presented by Lazzarato, Hardt and Negri, and argue why the condition of "disorganised labour" more accurately describes the circumstances in which labour finds itself within an informational paradigm. Three of the respondents stated they did not belong to a union, one with perhaps a degree of ironic self-affirmation characteristic of what Lash and Urry (1994) term 'reflexive individualization': 'Nope', writes one person, 'I'm a manager and self-employed :7'. In his book on globalisation, Ulrich Beck identifies a nexus between those who work for themselves - a mode of coordination he attributes to "life-aesthetes" in particular - and their desire for 'self-development'. He goes on to suggest that such dispositions lend themselves to 'self-exploitation': 'People are prepared to do a great deal for very little money, precisely because economic advantage is individualistically refracted and even assigned an opposite value. If an activity has greater value in terms of identity and self-fulfilment, this makes up for and even exalts a lower level of income' (2000: 150). Richard Caves prefers to explain the condition of non-union labour in more economic terms. Citing the example of independent filmmaking, Caves notes that '30 to 35 per cent of production costs [can be saved] by operating a nonunion project' (2000:133). In productions involving union labour, most of these additional costs are a result, so Caves claims, of inefficient and interventionist management practices and regulations, which sees workers being paid for standing around doing nothing. Caves casts unions as manipulative entities who have a propensity to 'hold-up' production unless their wage demands are met (132). Issues of creative governance are always going to have local, national peculiarities, and will vary from industry to industry. In every case, however, the challenge for creative workers is, it seems to me, to create work that holds not only the maximum potential for self-fulfilment and group cooperation on a project, but just as importantly, creative workers need to situate themselves in ways that close down the possibility of exploitation. The other respondents belonged to various unions or professional organisations: NTEU (2), MEAA/AJA (2), the College Arts Association (USA) and APRA, 'which is not really a union, but it primarily concerned with IP'. All these respondents were aware of their union's policy on IP issues, though one respondent held a high level of cynicism: 'I've never heard a union take a credible position on IP'. The follow up question on the efficacy of unions in instances of dispute with management over IP elicited further cynicism from another respondent: 'Unions are too stupid to do this properly. They are as much a part of the problem since they agree to perverse work relations. Unions are corporations'. Others noted that disputes of this nature were 'an ongoing battle on many fronts' and that 'the MEAA/AJA newsletter often has such stories. Most of it is so thoroughly covered in case law that the major players don't bother to buck the system. The case of US freelance Journos seeking payment for new media republication of their stories seminal'. To summarise: while the majority of respondents did belong to one or more unions, a good proportion of these respondents did not seem satisfied with or have any great faith in the efforts of unions to negotiate disputes over IP in the workplace. [end part 1/2] # distributed via <nettime>: no commercial use without permission # <nettime> is a moderated mailing list for net criticism, # collaborative text filtering and cultural politics of the nets # more info: [EMAIL PROTECTED] and "info nettime-l" in the msg body # archive: http://www.nettime.org contact: [EMAIL PROTECTED]