As COP 26 blunders on, everybody's talking about Facebook! Ha ha, it's a
much easier conversation.

I am posting below an article from the New Left Review newsletter, on the
(highly incoherent) dynamics of energy transition, in the midst of both
devastating weather events AND acute energy shortages. As everyone knows,
natural gas and other fossil fuel prices are going through the roof, in
advance of a winter which could prove unusually cold in Europe and North
America. Can you imagine the left-right tensions which this looming
scenario could - and almost surely will - unleash? And how 'bout the
geopolitics?

The next big thing on the global horizon is not the wet potato of the
Metaverse. It's the explosive disconnect between two simultaneous
movements. On the one hand, the mounting social, political, scientific and
soon military pressure to do something about climate change. And on the
other hand, a corresponding backlash against any transformation whatsoever,
amid a context of declining incomes, economic turbulence and breakdown.

Now just clap those two hands and see what happens.

This article on the grand dilemma of our time is best read, imo, along with
a piece by Viennese sociologist Daniel Hauskonst:

https://unosd.un.org/sites/unosd.un.org/files/hausknost_2019_the_environmental_state_and_the_glass_ceiling_of_transformation.pdf

It's hardly surprising that I found a free copy of the Hauskonst article on
a UN website....

best, Brian



Energy Dilemma
Cédric Durand
05 November 2021 - Economics

https://newleftreview.org/sidecar/posts/energy-dilemma?pc=1393


The ecological bifurcation is not a gala dinner. After a summer of extreme
climatic events and a new IPCC report confirming its most worrying
forecasts, large parts of the world are now roiled by an energy crisis that
prefigures further economic troubles down the road. This conjuncture has
buried the dream of a harmonious transition to a post-carbon world,
bringing the question of capitalism’s ecological crisis to the fore. At
COP26, the dominant tone is one of powerlessness, where impending miseries
have left humanity cornered between the immediate demands of systemic
reproduction and the acceleration of climate disorders.

Prima facie, one might think that steps are being taken to address this
cataclysm. More than 50 countries – plus the entire European Union – have
pledged to meet net zero emissions targets that would see global
energy-related CO2 emissions fall by 40% between now and 2050. Yet a sober
reading of the scientific data shows that the green transition is well off
track. Falling short of global net zero means that temperatures will
continue to rise, pushing the world well above 2°C by 2100. According to
the UNEP, nationally determined contributions, which countries were
requested to submit in advance of COP26, would reduce 2030 emissions by
7.5%. Yet a 30% drop is needed to limit warming to 2°C, while 55% would be
required for 1.5°C.

As a recent Nature editorial warned, many of these countries have made
net-zero pledges without a concrete plan to get there. Which gases will be
targeted? To what extent does net-zero rely on effective reduction rather
than offsetting schemes? The latter have become particularly attractive for
rich countries and polluting corporations, since they do not directly
diminish emissions and involve transferring the burden of carbon-cutting to
low- and medium-income nations (which will be most severely affected by
climate breakdown). On these crucial issues, reliable information and
transparent commitments are nowhere to be found, jeopardizing the
possibility of credible international scientific monitoring. The bottom
line: based on the current global climate policies – those implemented and
those proposed – the world is on track for a devastating increase in
emissions during the next decade.

In spite of this, capitalism has already experienced the first major
economic shock related to the transition beyond carbon. The surge in energy
prices is due to several factors, including a disorderly rebound from the
pandemic, poorly designed energy markets in the UK and EU which exacerbate
price volatility, and Russia’s willingness to secure its long-term energy
incomes. However, at a more structural level, the impact of first efforts
made to restrict the use of fossil fuels cannot be overlooked. Due to
government limits on coal burning, plus shareholders’ growing reluctance to
commit to projects that could be largely obsolete in thirty years,
investment in fossil fuel has been falling. Although this contraction of
the supply is not enough to save the climate, it is still proving too much
for capitalist growth.

Putting together several recent events gives a taste of things to come. In
the Punjab region of India, severe shortages of coal have caused
unscheduled power blackouts. In China, more than half the provincial
jurisdictions have imposed strict power-rationing measures. Several
companies, including key Apple suppliers, have recently been forced to halt
or reduce operations at facilities in Jiangsu province, after local
governments restricted the supply of electricity. Those restrictions were
an attempt to comply with national emissions targets by restricting
coal-fired power generation, which still accounts for about two thirds of
China’s electricity. To contain the spillover of these disruptions, Chinese
authorities have put a temporary brake on their climate ambitions, ordering
72 coal mines to increase their supply and relaunching imports of
Australian coal that were halted for months in the midst of diplomatic
tensions between the two countries.

In Europe, it was the surge in gas prices that triggered the current
crisis. Haunted by the memory of the gilets jaunes uprising against
Marcon’s carbon tax, governments have intervened with energy subsidies for
the popular classes. More unexpectedly, though, gas price increases have
precipitated chain reactions in the manufacturing sector. The case of
fertilizers is telling. A US group, CF Industries, decided to shut down
production of its UK fertilizer plants, which had become unprofitable due
to price increases. As a by-product of its operations, the firm previously
supplied 45% of the UK’s food-grade CO2 – whose loss unleashed weeks of
chaos for the industry, affecting various sectors from beer and soft drinks
to food packaging and meat. Globally, the surge of gas prices is affecting
the farming sector via the increase in fertilizer prices. In Thailand, the
cost of fertilizers is on track to double from 2020, raising costs for many
rice producers and putting the planting season at risk. If this continues,
governments may have to step in to ensure essential food supplies.

The global and widespread repercussions of energy shortages and price
increases underscores the complex fallout involved in the structural
transformation necessary to eliminate carbon emissions. While a reduction
is underway in the supply of hydrocarbon, increases in sustainable energy
sources are not sufficient to meet growing demand. This leaves an energy
mismatch that could derail the transition altogether. In this context,
countries can either return to the most readily available energy source –
coal – or cause an economic contraction driven by the surge in costs and
their effects on profitability, consumption prices and the stability of the
financial system. In the short term, then, there is a trade-off between
ecological objectives and the requirement to foster growth. But does this
energy dilemma hold in the medium and long term? Will we ultimately face a
choice between climate and growth?

A successful carbon transition implies the harmonious unfolding of two
processes complexly related at the material, economic and financial levels.
First, a process of disbandment must take place. Sources of carbon must be
drastically reduced: above all hydrocarbon extraction, electricity
production by coal and gas, fuel-based transport systems, the construction
sector (due to the high level of emissions involved in cement and steel
production) and the meat industry. What is at stake here is degrowth in the
most straightforward sense: equipment must be scrapped, fossil fuel
reserves must stay in the soil, intensive cattle-breeding must be abandoned
and an array of related professional skills must be made redundant.

All things being equal, the elimination of production capacities implies a
contraction of supply which would lead to generalized inflationary
pressure. This is even more likely because the sectors most affected are
located at the commanding heights of modern economies. Cascading through
the other sectors, pressure on costs will dent firms’ mark-up, global
profits and/or consumer purchasing power, unleashing wild recessionary
forces. In addition, degrowth of the carbon economy is a net loss from the
point of view of the valorization of financial capital: huge amounts of
stranded assets must be wiped out since underlying expected profits are
foregone, paving the way for fire sales and ricocheting onto the mass of
fictitious capital. These interrelated dynamics will fuel each other, as
recessionary forces increase debt defaults while financial crisis freezes
the access to credit.

The other side of the transition is a major investment push to accommodate
the supply shock caused by the degrowth of the carbon sector. While
changing consumption habits could play a role, especially in affluent
countries, the creation of new carbon-free production capacities,
improvements in efficiency, electrification of transport, industrial and
heating systems (along with the deployment of carbon capture in some
instances) are also necessary to compensate for the phasing out of
greenhouse gas emissions. From a capitalist perspective, these could
represent new profit opportunities, so long as the costs of production are
not prohibitive relative to available demand. Attracted by this
valorization, green finance could step in and accelerate the transition,
propelling a new wave of accumulation capable of sustaining employment and
living standards.

Yet it is important to bear in mind that timing is everything: making such
adjustments in fifty years is completely different from having to disengage
drastically in a decade. And from where we are now, the prospects for a
smooth and adequate switch to green energy are slim, to say the least. The
scaling back of the carbon sector remains uncertain due to the inherent
contingency of political processes and the persistent lack of engagement
from state authorities. It is illustrative that one single Senator, Joe
Manchin III of west Virginia, can block the US Democrats’ programme to
facilitate the replacement of coal- and gas-fired power plants.

As illustrated by the current disruptions, the lack of readily available
alternatives could also hamper the phasing-out of fossil fuels. According
to the IEA: ‘Transition-related spending […] remains far short of what is
required to meet rising demand for energy services in a sustainable way.
The deficit is visible across all sectors and regions.’ In its latest
Energy Report, Bloomberg estimates that a growing global economy will
require a level of investment in energy supply and infrastructure between
$92 trillion and $173 trillion over the next thirty years. Annual
investment will need to more than double, rising from around $1.7 trillion
per year today, to somewhere between $3.1 trillion and $5.8 trillion per
year on average. The magnitude of such a macroeconomic adjustment would be
unprecedented.

>From the perspective of mainstream economics, this adjustment is still a
matter of getting the prices right. In a recent report commissioned by
French President Emmanuel Macron, two leading economists in the field,
Christian Gollier and Mar Reguant, argue that ‘The value of carbon should
be used as a yardstick for all dimensions of public policymaking.’ Although
standards and regulations should not be ruled out, ‘well-designed carbon
pricing’ via a carbon tax or cap-and trade mechanism must play the leading
role. Market mechanisms are expected to internalize the negative
externalities of greenhouse gas emissions, allowing for an orderly
transition on both the supply and demand sides. ‘Carbon pricing has the
advantage of focusing on efficiency in terms of cost per ton of CO2,
without the need to identify in advance which measures will work.’
Reflecting the plasticity of market adjustment, a carbon price – ‘unlike
more prescriptive measures’ – opens up a space for ‘innovative solutions’.

This free-market, techno-optimistic perspective ensures that capitalist
growth and climate stabilization are reconciliable. However, it suffers
from two main shortcomings. The first is the blindness of the
carbon-pricing approach to the macroeconomic dynamics involved in the
transition effort. A recent report by Jean Pisani Ferry, written for the
Peterson Institute for International Economics, plays down the possibility
of any smooth adjustment driven by market prices, while also dashing the
hopes of a Green New Deal that could lift all boats.

Observing that ‘Procrastination has reduced the chances of engineering an
orderly transition’, the report notes that there is ‘no guarantee that the
transition to carbon neutrality will be good for growth.’ The process is
quite simple: 1) since decarbonation implies an accelerated obsolescence of
some part of existing capital stock, supply will be reduced; 2) in the
meantime, more investment will be necessary. The burning question then
becomes: are there sufficient resources in the economy to allow for more
investment alongside weakened supply? The answer depends on the amount of
slack in the economy – that is, idle productive capacity and unemployment.
But considering the size of the adjustment and the compressed timeframe,
this cannot be taken for granted. In Pisani Ferry’s view, ‘Impact on growth
will be ambiguous, impact on consumption should be negative. Climate action
is like a military build-up when facing a threat: good for welfare in the
long run, but bad for consumer satisfaction’. Shifting the resources from
consumption to investment means that consumers will inevitably bear the
cost of the effort.

In spite of his neo-Keynesian perspective, Pisani-Ferry opens up an
insightful discussion on the political conditions that would allow for a
reduction in living standards and a green class-war fought along income
lines. Yet, in its attachment to the price mechanism, his argument shares
with the market-adjustment approach an irrational emphasis on the
efficiency of CO2 emission reduction. The second shortcoming of Gollier and
Reguant’s contribution becomes apparent when they call for ‘a combination
of climate actions with the lowest possible cost per ton of CO2 equivalent
not emitted’. Indeed, as the authors themselves recognize, the setting of
carbon prices is highly uncertain. Evaluations can range from $45 to
$14,300 per ton, depending on the time horizon and the reduction targeted.
With such variability, there is no point in trying to optimize the cost of
carbon reduction intertemporally. What is important is not the cost of the
adjustment, but rather the certainty that the stabilization of the climate
will occur.

Delineating the specificities of the Japanese developmental state, the
political scientist Chalmers Johnson made a distinction that could also be
applied to the transition debate:

    A regulatory, or market rational, state concerns itself with the form
and procedures – the rules, if you will – of economic competition, but it
doesn’t concern itself with substantive matters […] The developmental
state, or plan-rational state, by contrast, has as its dominant feature
precisely the setting of such substantive social and economic goals.

In other words, while the first aims at efficiency – by making the most
economical uses of resources – the second is concerned with effectiveness:
that is, by the ability to achieve a given goal, be it war or
industrialization. Given the existential threat posed by climate change and
the fact that there exists a simple and stable metric to limit our
exposure, our concern should be with the effectiveness of reducing
greenhouse gases rather the efficiency of the effort. Instead of using the
price mechanism to let the market decide where the effort should lie, it is
infinitely more straightforward to add up targets at the sectoral and
geographical levels, and provide a consistent reduction plan to ensure that
the overall goal will be achieved in time.

Morgan Stanley’s Ruchir Sharma, writing on this question in the FT, raises
a point which indirectly makes the case for ecological planning. He notes
that the investment push necessary to transition beyond carbon presents us
with a trivially material problem: on the one hand, dirty activities –
particularly in the sectors of mining or metal production – are rendered
unprofitable due to increased regulation or higher carbon prices; on the
other hand, investment for the greening of the infrastructure requires such
resources to expand capacities. Decreasing supply plus rising demand is
therefore a recipe for what he calls ‘greenflation’. Sharma therefore
argues that ‘Blocking new mines and oil rigs will not always be the
environmentally and socially responsible move.’

As the spokesperson of an institution with vested interest in polluting
commodities, Sharma is hardly a neutral commentator. But the problem he
articulates – how to supply enough dirty material to build a clean-energy
economy – is a real one, and relates to another issue with the putative
market-driven transition: carbon pricing does not allow society to
discriminate between spurious uses of carbon – such as sending billionaires
into space – and vital uses such as building the infrastructure for a
non-carbon economy. In a successful transition, the first would be made
impossible, the second as cheap as possible. As such, a unique carbon price
becomes a clear pathway to failure.

This brings us back to an old but still decisive argument: rebuilding an
economy – in this case one which phases out fossil fuels – requires
restructuring the chain of relations between its diverse segments, which
suggests that the fate of the economy as a whole depends on its point of
least resistance. As Alexandr Bogdanov noted in the context of building the
young Soviet state, ‘Because of these interdependent relationships, the
process of enlargement of the economy is subject in its entirety to the law
of the weakest point.’ This line of thought was later developed by Wassily
Leontief in his contributions to input-output analysis. It holds that
market adjustments are simply not up to structural transformation. In such
situations, what’s required is a careful and adaptative planning mechanism
able to identify and deal with a moving landscape of bottlenecks.

When one considers the economic challenges of restructuring economies to
keep carbon emissions in line with the stabilization of the climate, this
discussion acquires a new framing. Effectiveness must take precedence over
efficiency in reducing emissions. That means abandoning the fetish of the
price mechanism in order to plan how the remaining dirty resources will be
used in the service of clean infrastructure. Such planning must have
international reach, since the greatest opportunities for energy-supply
decarbonation are located in the Global South. Moreover, as transformation
on the supply side will not be enough, demand-side transformations will
also be essential to stay within planetary boundaries. Energy requirements
for providing decent living standards to the global population can be
drastically reduced, but in addition to the use of the most efficient
available technologies, this implies a radical transformation of
consumption patterns, including political procedures to prioritize between
competing consumption claims.

With its longstanding concern for planning and socialized consumption,
international socialism is an obvious candidate to take on such a historic
task. Though the poor state of socialist politics doesn’t conjure much
optimism, the catastrophic conjuncture we are entering – along with price
volatility and the ongoing spasms of capitalist crises – could increase the
fluidity of the situation. In such circumstances, the left must be flexible
enough to seize any political opportunity that will advance the cause of a
democratic ecological transition.
#  distributed via <nettime>: no commercial use without permission
#  <nettime>  is a moderated mailing list for net criticism,
#  collaborative text filtering and cultural politics of the nets
#  more info: http://mx.kein.org/mailman/listinfo/nettime-l
#  archive: http://www.nettime.org contact: nett...@kein.org
#  @nettime_bot tweets mail w/ sender unless #ANON is in Subject:

Reply via email to