Wednesday, January 21, 2009
The Future of News, Part One: The Problem

C. Edwin Baker
University of Pennsylvania

http://balkin.blogspot.com/2009/01/future-of-news-part-one-problem.html

Massive layoffs of journalists at most newspapers, continuing and 
increasing circulation declines, sharp losses of advertising revenue, 
bankruptcies and closures create a foreboding spiral in the news 
industry. The future of professionally produced news hangs in the 
balance with no remedy in sight. Of these five problems, however, I 
put aside highly publicized bankruptcies, mostly caused not by lack 
of operating profits but by excessive debt generated by shortsighted 
recent purchases. And I put aside closures, like those threatened by 
the Seattle P-I and the Rocky Mountain News, which reflect the 
twentieth century's experience that competing dailies in two 
newspaper towns are seldom economically sustainable.

Most troubling is the loss of journalists on which news production 
depends. The San Jose Mercury has lost over half its journalists over 
the last decade. By last summer, the Philadelphia Inquirer, the 
Dallas Morning News, the Minneapolis Star Tribune had seen newsroom 
cuts of 30% to 50%. Further layoffs are continuing at most major 
papers. What should be made of this? Does it represent merely a 
historical transformation to a new cultural order? Is bemoaning the 
loss simply conservative romanticism for an inevitably by-gone era - 
nostalgia intensified by justified concern for all those who have 
devoted their career to a once glorious profession? Or, is the 
lay-off of journalists a real crisis for democracy, different in kind 
than, say, the passing of livery stables, the decline of the family 
farm, or lay-offs in the troubled, oil-dependent airline industry? 
And if a crisis for democracy, can anything be done?

Withering of public interest in news not the problem

Common wisdom blames the crisis in newspapers on a loss of people's, 
especially young people's, interest in news. This explanation is not 
only simply too easy. It is wrong. True, new online diversions 
combined with the pace of modern life - who has the time to sit and 
read a newspaper? - might explain some reduction in news consumption, 
but the evidence here is very weak. Two points must be made about the 
noted recent - and increasing - decline in newspaper circulation.

First, much of the decline of newspaper circulation relates not to 
fewer newspaper readers but to how those readers access newspaper 
journalism. The Newspaper Association of America reports that paid 
daily circulation staying at its high plateau of roughly 62 million 
between 1968 to 1990 period, but dropping off at an increasing rate 
to about 52 million in 2006. Over the last fifteen years, however, 
online readership has grown from basically zero to 63.2 million 
people (39% of active web users), who spent an average of 44 minutes 
on newspaper web sites in October 2007. Thus, the ten million loss in 
print circulation appears is largely replaced by sixty three million 
online readers. Moreover, even when people go to non-newspaper online 
sources of news, these sources have often derived, if not simply 
copied, their information from newspaper's journalism. Evidence of a 
decreasing public reliance on newspapers as either the initial or 
ultimate journalistic source of news is way overblown.

Second, circulation declines are the predictable result of selling a 
degraded product - one produced by less journalists - or the same 
product at a higher price or, often, a degraded product at a higher 
price. (In addition, some circulation declines have been engineered. 
Since newspapers have long received the bulk of their revenue from 
advertisers, paying more for ink, paper, and delivery than the paper 
receives from readers, papers have increasingly chosen to shed 
circulation from parts of town or outlying regions of the state where 
readers are not likely to be customers of, and hence are not valued 
by, local advertisers.) Despite public hand-wringing, publishers know 
how to maintain or increase their audience - if they want to. Recent 
years have seen some papers gain circulation when they avoid either 
raising their cover price or reducing their newsroom budget. Clearly, 
papers that have and keep more than average number of journalists 
(per 1000 readers) are likely to avoid or limit declines and maybe 
even increase circulation.

The trouble is that keeping or expanding circulation costs more than 
the revenue it produces. Often papers accurately calculate that 
profits increase more if it spends less on journalists (or raises the 
cover price) even if this causes circulation losses. To maintain or 
expand circulation by hiring journalists to improve its product is 
simply more expensive than it is worth in bottom line results.

Financial base and advertising support as the problem.

Advertising has always been a problematic partner in the provision of 
news. Its increasing financial role since the late nineteenth century 
created the financial rationale for objectivity to replace 
partisanship and to become the ruling norm in journalism. 
Objectivity, even though less valued and hence requiring a price 
reduction, allowed selling a less differentiated product to a broader 
audience, which produced more than compensating advertising revenue. 
The greater uniformity then became central to the collapse of 
competition of multiple daily newspapers within a town. These changes 
suppressed political participation, a suppression skewed against 
portions of the public not valued by advertisers. Advertisers 
subsequently caused not only overt violations of the newspaper's line 
dividing church and state, but also creation of advertising friendly 
copy and self-censorship, often unconscious, in the story lines 
pursued. And, of course, as the central cultural institution of 
capitalism, advertising likely contributes to American's 
over-valuation of privately owned goods and inadequate taxpayer 
support for expenditures on public goods - goods seldom promoted by 
advertisers.

Nevertheless, advertising has provided the economic foundation of 
American journalism. The current crisis in the news industry is much 
less diversion of readers to online non-traditional media sources or 
abandonment of people's interest in news than to the decreased value 
of readers to newspapers due to the diversion of advertising from 
support of journalism to support of non-news online activities. 
Newspapers have not been able, at least not yet, to squeeze near the 
advertising revenue from an online reader than from a print reader. 
People's reduced reliance on newspaper advertising is also 
significant - as illustrated by huge losses of highly profitable 
classified ads to online services. Even if a newspaper company rather 
than, say, E-bay or Craig's List owned and profited from the online 
listing service, the newspaper company has no economic incentive to 
plow that money back into their news product, into journalism.

Possibly most serious, advertising is a more or less fixed pot. Huge 
portions of advertising revenue now supports the suppliers of the 
"search" for all sorts of already-produced information (including 
product and personal information) rather than journalistic entities 
which produce news - which is the story of huge capitalization of 
Google. Internet advertising that basically did not exist thirteen 
years ago clocked in at $21.2 billion in 2007 - with 41% going to 
advertising related to "searches" - and the amount is rising rapidly. 
That compares with annual newspaper advertising of roughly $40 
billion, an amount in decline due primarily to this increasing 
diversion to online advertising. Though advertising always goes down 
even in minor recessions, even more so in anything like what the 
country is currently experiencing, the movement to online advertising 
is of historic significance for the news industry. Essentially the 
advertising that has long paid for journalism is in irreversible 
decline. Without a solution, the future may simply provide an 
inadequate financial basis for support of the journalism profession 
and for the news a democratic society needs.

Significance of problem.

Economic theory clearly predicts that free markets will not alone 
produce as much quality news content as the public - as consumers - 
want. Using willingness to pay as a criterion of what people want, 
the market would achieve this result if, but only if, producers of 
news content can receive payment for all the benefits it produces, 
payments from all those who benefit, these payments being the proper 
incentives for production.

Certainly circulation levels and corresponding revenue reflect some 
of the benefits received by individual readers. These readers pay (or 
spend time then sold to advertisers) for being better informed, more 
amused, or otherwise fulfilled from receiving the paper. But when a 
journalistic unit exposes corruption that leads to reform, 
non-readers benefit just as much from the reform and hence from the 
news production as do the readers. When reporting portrayal of 
problems leads to government (or corporate or charitable) responses, 
all those suffering from the problems the paper identifies, not just 
its readers, benefit. When a quality journalistic unit's reputation 
for casting light on misdeeds deters corruption and keeps those in 
power on their toes, once again the broader public benefits even 
though this deterrence means that the paper has no story to sell to 
its readers. Though people disagree about which political candidates 
are best, most agree that they and everyone else benefit when not 
only their own but other people's vote is well informed. But a person 
can receive this benefit of quality newspapers informing other 
peoples' votes without herself reading or paying. And she benefits 
more the better job the paper does - a job highly dependent on the 
resources the paper has. That is, I benefit greatly and in multiple 
ways from quality public radio news or solid investigative journalism 
of my local paper even if I do not listen or read - or pay!

All these potential benefits to people for which many pay nothing and 
for which no one pays fully results in the paper (or broadcaster) 
having inadequate incentives to produce the quality or amount of news 
that would provide the benefits at the level they are valued. Of 
course, the news entity does produce some journalism - its direct 
audience will pay something and advertisers add payments for access 
to this audience. This amount is, however, far, far less than the 
benefits that more and better journalism could generate at a cost 
less than the benefits it would provide. And the converse of these 
arguments applies to poor quality news - it creates uninformed, less 
informed or misinformed audiences to the detriment of the public as a 
whole.

To be sure, poor quality, misleading, or glaring absences of coverage 
can occur despite fully adequate newsroom budgets, just as bad 
judgments are sometimes made by the best physicians using the best 
medical tests and equipment. Nevertheless, the correct expectation is 
that more resources will improve quality. Any good editor will say, 
usually rightly, that she could provide better quality news if she is 
given more resources - more experienced reporters, bigger newsroom 
budgets.

[In Part Two tomorrow, Professor Baker will offer some possible solutions]

--~--~---------~--~----~------------~-------~--~----~
You received this message because you are subscribed to Mark Crispin Miller's 
"News From Underground" newsgroup.

To unsubscribe, send a blank email to 
newsfromunderground-unsubscr...@googlegroups.com OR go to 
http://groups.google.com/group/newsfromunderground and click on the 
"Unsubscribe or change membership" link in the yellow bar at the top of the 
page, then click the "Unsubscribe" button on the next page. 

For more News From Underground, visit http://markcrispinmiller.com
-~----------~----~----~----~------~----~------~--~---

Reply via email to