salah satu buku Samuelson ttg ekonomi ( kalo gak salah judulnya economics) 
adalah bacaan wajib bagi mahasiswa ekonomi pada era 90 an...
Entah sekarang....

Salam toto setiawan

--- Sent with System SEVEN - the new generation of mobile messaging

- original message -
Subject: [ob] Paul Samuelson's Legacy
From: "Eddi Wahyudi" <yuditia2...@yahoo.co.id>
Date: 22/12/2009 7:24 AM

Paul Samuelson's Legacy
http://seekingalpha.com/article/179140-paul-samuelson-s-legacy?source=hp_wc
Paul Samuelson died a week ago Sunday, at 94. For some historical perspective 
on the role he played, consider that, for the entire history of modern 
economics, all 250 years of it, from its beginnings during the Enlightenment of 
the eighteenth century to the present day, the discipline has been dominated by 
five canonical textbooks – and only five (though, of course, each had many 
imitators). Those who found compelling the authority of these texts became 
economists. Those who didn’t became something else – sociologists, political 
theorists, anthropologists, psychologists, historians, lawyers, reformers, 
businessmen, religious leaders.
The first of these texts, in 1776, was An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of 
the Wealth of Nations, by Adam Smith. Smith explained the mechanisms underlying 
Great Britain’s long consumer boom – the world’s first — with a clarity that 
still rings true today. His book wasn’t the first word about these topics; 
instead it was, in some sense, the last. Before Wealth of Nations, there were 
philosophers and pamphleteers. Afterwards, there was a community of scholars 
around the world working collaboratively on a set of problems that they called 
political economy.
Forty years passed before David Ricardo’s The Principles of Political Economy 
and Taxation appeared in 1817 — “to correct the errors in Smith,” the author 
explained. The world had changed. England had suffered through nearly twenty 
years of population explosion and desperate war with France. Ricardo (and his 
friend Thomas Robert Malthus, coming at it from a slightly different angle) 
envisaged a world soon running out of natural resources, of arable land, of 
food itself. Their ideas were taken up with great excitement in London. Within 
the newly-formed Political Economy Club they won disciples; outside of it, they 
sparked criticism and ridicule.
The third great text, Principles of Political Economy, by John Stuart Mill, was 
published in 1848. It was apparent by then that Great Britain was again growing 
rich. The idea was to update Smith’s vision in light of the Industrial 
Revolution. But, as Jürg Niehans has written, “whereas Adam Smith’s synthesis 
had conquered the world, Mill’s synthesis… conquered only the classrooms.” 
Mill’s book eclipsed Ricardo; it shouldered aside the upstart Karl Marx, as 
well; and established the author as the great economist of his age, at least in 
the popular mind. But behind the scenes, in a dozen nations around the world, a 
small corps of analysts went to work on a more rigorous formulation. New 
sciences with new methods were springing up. Economists aspired to better 
analytic tools.
In 1890, Principles of Economics, by Alfred Marshall, of Cambridge University, 
supplied them. Marshall was the first master teacher to be a university 
professor (Mill had worked for the East India Company, Ricardo as a wealthy 
stockbroker, and Malthus was a country parson). Still writing almost entirely 
in literary terms, he gathered together strands of work from thinkers on three 
continents in a tradition that in time would be called “marginalism.” With 
these doctrines economists could focus on changes, not in aggregate quantities, 
but in small increments of quantities, a little more of one thing, a little 
less of another, such as to permit the application of differential calculus to 
economic theory. This was economics of the Victorian age, sufficiently 
different from what Adam Smith and the others had done before as to require 
differentiation from the classics – it was “neoclassical” economics. Marshall’s 
text went through eight editions,
 the last in 1924. So well-crafted was it that its influence would last another 
quarter century, sixty years altogether, through many revolutions and two world 
wars.
The fifth great text appeared in the years just after World War II, except that 
this time two books were required, not just one, both of them written by the 
32-year-old Paul Samuelson, who was already recognized as a leader, perhaps the 
leader of his generation. Foundations of Economic Analysis, which appeared in 
1947, was written for first-year graduate students.Economics: An Introductory 
Analysis, which followed the next year, was written for the masses – at least 
those who took a college economics course. The new split-level approach was 
necessitated by the development of the field. In the years since Marshall, 
economics had finally become thoroughly professionalized. Economists now wrote 
mainly for each other.
Samuelson’s thesis had carried the subtitle, The Operational Significance of 
Economic Theory. Both books were an elaboration of Keynesian ideas about 
national income and its fluctuations that Samuelson and others had developed in 
response to the Great Depression and the demands of wartime finance during the 
1930s and early 1940s. Samuelson was not bashful about describing his findings 
as scientific, or apologetic for the way he expressed them. “Mathematics is a 
language,” stated the frontispiece of Foundations, attri

Kirim email ke