A very timely and interesting text… It also relates to the question whether 
issues of a peer-to-peer economy, a co-operative economy, networked labour, 
digital labour, etc. fit better into a Grexit/Euroexit-communist or a 
Euro-communist strategy… 
Christian

Communist Dilemmas on the Greek Euro-Crisis: To Exit or Not to Exit?
Christos Laskos, John Milios and Euclid Tsakalotos
http://www.workersliberty.org/system/files/milios.pdf 

One section of the Greek left converged on a strategy of default and exiting 
the euro, together with restructuring the economy through devaluation, 
nationalization of the banks and the renationalization of public utilities, 
industrial policies etc. At the intellectual level this approach gained 
powerful support from a number of Greek academics working abroad. At the 
political level the exit strategy was promoted as a central policy plank by the 
extra-parliamentary left, especially Antarsya, but also found a strong, albeit 
minority, support within some sections of Syriza (see Kouvelakis, 2011, p. 
30)[1] . The forces coalescing around the exit strategy obviously had internal 
differences and we cannot hope to do justice to all the nuances here. Rather we 
shall focus on the arguments as presented by those providing the intellectual 
gravitas to the exit strategy.

The exit strategy has two main elements. The first relies on a deconstruction 
of any argument that the EU provides any privileged terrain for left wing 
strategies. The second relies on showing how debt default and withdrawing from 
the euro provide the indispensable starting point for such strategies. Thus the 
first report published in 2010 from the Research in Money and Finance Group, 
based in SOAS, argued that the “good euro” option (for instance introducing 
eurobonds, enlarging the EU budget to include larger fiscal transfers between 
states or transforming the ECB into a lender of last resort) was politically 
infeasible (Lapavitsas et. al., 2010). Europeanists, whether “reluctant” or 
“revolutionary”, Lapavitsas (2012) argues, are widely overoptimistic at what 
can be achieved on the supranational level. Why should “the main powers” accept 
major losses from a fundamental restructuring of debt at the EU level (p. 292)? 
Is it surprising that the “eurozone establishmen
 t” has given short shrift to proposals for direct ECB financing of public debt 
(p. 293)? Moreover is it likely that we could arrive at a coordinated 
European-level response to macroeconomic imbalances? After all “There is no 
capitalist class that would systematically aim at raising the wages of its own 
workers since it would then be ruined in competition. If wage restraint was 
broken in Germany, the monetary union would become a lot less attractive to the 
German ruling class, raising the issue of its own continued euro membership” 
(p. 294-5).

It is difficult to know what to make of this style of argumentation. 
“Revolutionary Europeanists”, to accept for the sake of the argument 
Lapavitsas’ widely misleading term for those he disagrees with, are hardly 
likely to believe that the “main powers” and the “eurozone establishment” will 
accept willingly either debt restructuring or monetary financing of public 
debt. Nor do they think that it is somehow in the interests of German, or any 
other for that matter, capital to increase the wages of their workers. Nor, to 
take a final example, are they likely to be unaware of the fact that German 
capital is committed to the euro as a hard currency whose credibility is 
crucial to providing the framework for capital accumulation[2] . A radical 
strategy for the Left that gives more weight to the European-wide level is just 
as likely to point to the need for a fundamental shift in the balance of class 
forces as is one that places more emphasis on the nation state.

Thus Syriza, which did not support the exit strategy, was fully aware of the 
scale of the task in changing the balance of class forces at the supra-national 
level. But it considered that building alliances with radical forces in both 
the PI(I)Gs and in the Northern economies was a critical component of any 
response; not just to respond to the rising debt crisis, but to seek common 
ground to challenge ruling ideas and practices concerning both production and 
redistribution. It was under no illusion about the scale of the resistance to 
be expected to any restructuring of debt, but its analysis maintained that the 
global nature of the capitalist crisis presented severe limitations for any 
merely national response. In any case Syriza’s internationalist interventions 
were supplemented with national-level initiatives, calling for a radical 
redistribution of income, socialization of the financial sector and many of the 
policies supported by those in the exit camp. Moreover Syriza was in s
 ome sense more radical in its skepticism with respect to leftist strategies 
that relied on the “reconstruction of the national economy” as a stepping stone 
towards socialism, thereby somewhat sidelining the issue of the relations of 
production.
In other words, the issue at stake is not the need to think about the balance 
of class forces, but, rather, where the more favourable terrain for the Left 
lies, or where should the emphasis be, given that “revolutionary Europeanists” 
do not ignore national struggles, and nor do supporters of the exit strategy 
neglect the need for supra-national interventions. Without such an analysis it 
is difficult to work out why TINA does not hold at the national level, as the 
entire Left has argued throughout the dark years of neo-liberalism, but somehow 
the mainstay of capitalist ideology, that there is no alternative, is perfectly 
correct once we move to the supra-national level. But it turns out that the 
analysis required opens up nearly the whole gamma of issues concerning Left 
strategy: from the nature of present day imperialism to that of the state, from 
the feasibility of national roads to socialism to the nature of leftist 
alternatives for the economy, from the sources of capitalist i
 deological hegemony to class strategies for changing the balance of forces. It 
is for this reason that we believe that the Greek debates are of interest the 
wider Left.

The Eurozone crisis facing the Ghosts of Dependency Theory: A False Dilemma?


Influenced by the anti-colonial struggles many neo- Marxist approaches to 
imperialism in the post-war period were premised on the idea that ex-colonies 
and developing economies were subordinated to imperialist countries through 
relations of dependency. This notion of dependency, together with the related 
concept of world capitalism, shaped the centre-periphery theories which 
conceived global economic relationships as relationships of exploitation and 
polarization between countries, with a developed imperialist “centre” and a 
dependent “periphery”, with a “semi-periphery” in between these two major 
poles. The approach was most influential in the 1970s, and it played some role 
in the thinking of PASOK in its earlier radical phase before its first 
administration in 1981[3] .

The marginalization of this approach is best explained by the failure of this 
approach to explain contemporary developments in capitalism: the rise of 
East-Asian capitalist social formations and later China and the other “BRIC” 
countries, despite the marginalisation of most sub-Saharan, Latin-American and 
Asian countries (Milios and Sotiropoulos, 2009, ch. 2). But there is a strong 
element of the centre-periphery schema in many of the supporters of the exit 
strategy:

The European Monetary Union (EMU) has created a split between core and 
periphery, and relations between the core and periphery, and relations between 
the two are hierarchical and discriminatory. The periphery has lost 
competitiveness in the 2000s, therefore developing current account deficits 
with the core and accumulating large debts to the financial institutions of the 
core. The result has been that Germany has emerged as the economic master of 
the Eurozone. [...] the Eurozone also has an external periphery in Eastern 
Europe which has presented similar tendencies to the internal periphery [...] 
Italy [...] occupies an intermediate place between periphery and core [...] But 
what alternative is currently on offer to peripheral countries? Trapped within 
the Eurozone, they are threatened with continued austerity, low 
competitiveness, high unemployment, growing social tensions, and loss of 
national independence
Lapavitsas et. al. (2011, p. 5 ff.)

The general tenure of the argument suggests that that the competitive 
capitalist countries of the European “centre” – especially Germany – have 
experienced gains in competitiveness by achieving low labour costs, primarily 
through a squeeze on wages and a slowing down of inflation. In this manner they 
have improved their exports within the Eurozone, while at the same time 
destroying the “productive base” of the periphery which seems to be caught in 
an “underdevelopment” trap. The persistent current account imbalances are 
thought to be the immediate results. For those accepting this line of 
argumentation, monetary union seems to have been converted into an area for the 
exploitation of the countries of the periphery by the economic “steam- engine” 
of the centre.

Such an approach displaces a major element of Marx’s problematic, namely 
class-struggle as the motive force of historical evolution, in favour of a 
bourgeois theoretical schema, according to which contradictions and 
exploitative relations between capitalist social formations move history. It 
has no conception of the state as the political condensation of class relations 
of domination, the factor that underwrites the cohesion of capitalist society. 
It therefore fails to grasp that capital is a social relationship that is 
reproduced in a complex way (politically and ideologically over-determined) in 
the framework of a specific (national) social formation.

The economic development of capitalism, and its crises, does not depend on the 
“desire” or the “strategies” of powerful states, but on the class struggle as 
reproduced within the various national state links of the global economic and 
political order, which through their inter- articulation comprise what may be 
described as the global imperialist chain (Milios & Sotiropoulos 2009, ch. 10). 
This is a way of conceptualizing the complex economic, political and 
ideological links that develop between the different social formations which 
over-determine the class struggle in each country but never acquire priority 
over it. The imperialist chain provides, on the one hand, the field of 
constitution of different, often contradictory national strategies, patently 
unequal in strength. But at the same time the unequal links in the imperialist 
chain have a common strategic interest: reproduction of the capitalist system 
of power. Each state as it forges its own strategy in the internation
 al arena, on a terrain of shifting correlations of power, also contributes to 
the reproduction of capitalism at the global level. The EU comprises the 
integration of capitalistically developed European countries: a strategic 
coalition of their ruling classes, seeking to strengthen their position both 
against the USA and other developed capitalist formations and, primarily, 
against their “own” (the European) working classes. The key prerequisite for 
unimpeded capital accumulation is that there should be favourable conditions 
for the valorization of capital, and capitalist competition is to be included 
among such conditions. Exposure to international competition is the most 
appropriate strategy for organizing bourgeois power, as a model for continuing 
reorganization of labour and the elimination of non- competitive individual 
capitals to the benefit of overall social capital.

Exit strategy supporters rightly consider that the EU is a powerful and 
authoritarian construction furthering capitalist interests. However, what we 
challenge here is the claim that that the EU essentially a construction which 
serves the interests of the Northern economies – as if there are no class 
relations within northern economies. The exposure to international competition, 
effected through the single market programme and monetary union, imposed 
significant restructuring to the benefit of capital in all member states. 
Significantly, this integration secured higher rates of profit, satisfactory 
rates of growth, and a rise in average productivity, for the less competitive 
countries, before 2008 at least, went a long way towards closing the gap in per 
capita GDP that separated them from the more advanced countries of the European 
north. And all this in an environment of “free” movement of goods and capital 
is an index of competitiveness!

During the period 1995-2008 Greece experienced a real increase in GDP amounting 
to 61.0%, Spain 56.0% and Ireland 124.1%. Conversely, GDP growth over the same 
time period was 19.5% for Germany, 17.8% for Italy and 30.8% for France (see 
OECD, Economic Outlook, Volume 2009/2, IMF & See Milios and Sotiropoulos 2010, 
p. 228). We note that during the same period, and contrary to what happed in 
Spain, Italy and some other European economies, the growth of Greek GDP was 
more heavily based on investment and on a high growth of employment and 
productivity, rather than government consumption [4] . The higher growth rates 
in the “peripheral” European economies were accompanied by both a fast 
reduction in the cost of domestic borrowing and a significant inflow of foreign 
investment (of various forms). This caused lasting surpluses on the financial 
account. However, the imbalances in the financial accounts within the eurozone 
shaped an unstable and vulnerable context of symbiosis which quickl
 y unraveled after the 2008 crisis.

One of the most noteworthy features of the first decade of the euro is the 
persistent current account imbalances: certain countries show chronic surpluses 
while others invariably suffer deficits. Nevertheless, the causality between 
these two “givens” may not be what it is often casually asserted to be in the 
relevant discussions. The current account deficit, in other words, may not be 
simply the immediate result of a corresponding “deficit” in competitiveness. On 
the contrary, it is quite possible that both could be the outcome of a 
different deeper cause, namely, the considerable differences in the levels of 
capitalist growth and of the specific mode of “symbiosis” within the euro.
Two other basic parameters seem pertinent in this respect. On the one hand, the 
higher rates of profit at the “periphery” boosted financial yields as a whole, 
with the result that international investors became ever keener to finance 
these high rates of growth, particularly in an environment where exchange-rate, 
and other, risks seemed, at the time, so much smaller. The countries of the 
“periphery” thus recorded strong surpluses on their financial accounts. 
Investments of various kinds in these countries rendered them attractive to 
capital from the centre. On the other hand, eurozone economies, with their 
different rates of growth and different rates of profit, were incorporated into 
the same regime of uniform nominal interest rates set by the ECB. These 
interest rates were considerably lower for the countries of the “periphery” 
than they had been prior to the introduction of the single currency. This fact, 
in conjunction with the higher rates of inflation prevailing in t
 hese countries, translated into even lower real interest rates for the local 
banking sector, laying the ground for the explosion of (private and public) 
borrowing.

These two factors strengthened borrowing and contributed to a further heating 
up of the “peripheral” economy, orienting production to the needs of a 
considerable domestic demand [5]. This had the effect of further reinforcing 
inflationary tendencies. The real level of interest rates fell even further, in 
this way providing further financial leverage. At the same time conditions of 
high internal demand caused increasing demand for imports. The flow of capital 
to the “periphery” on the one hand offset the cost of participation in the 
single market while at the same time generating the preconditions for a 
deterioration in competitiveness (as higher inflation boosted the price of 
domestically produced commodities). Thus the euro contributed to the 
perpetuation of asymmetries in the current account balances and divergences in 
unit costs of labour and inflation (competitiveness).

Clearly it is not that easy to sort out the line of causation between current 
account deficits and capital account surpluses, but a “centre-periphery” 
approach, we would argue, is misleading with respect to understanding the 
dynamics of the eurozone. Monetary union evidently generates strategic benefits 
for the collective capitalists of all the countries that participate in it. In 
other words, the strategy of exposing individual capital to international 
competition resulted in high growth rates and accumulation in the 
less-competitive countries of “periphery”. It is not possible to sustain the 
argument that EMU is exclusively the servant of the “insatiable” schemes of 
Germany, with its competitive economy. Moreover the experience in Greece, after 
the adoption of the first stabilization plan, suggests that what we have been 
witnessing is entirely understandable as a massive assault on the living 
standards of Greek workers for the benefit of Greek capital. It could further 
 be argued that Greece provides a crucial test case, for European capital’s 
ability to enforce a “solution” to the crisis which strengthens its hand. The 
emphasis on Germany’s role severely misrepresents both of these aspects to the 
detriment of socialist strategy, to which we now turn.

A critique of the National Routes to Socialism: Class Politics revisited

Above we have argued that the financial and economic architecture of the 
eurozone, which does not simply rest on the single currency, acts as a 
mechanism for exerting pressure for reorganizing labour in all member 
countries. The squeezing of the German working class, which started well before 
the eruption of the crisis, is an important part of the story. The debt crisis 
has further served to tighten the screws on labour in all areas of the 
eurozone. The policies of austerity have been almost universally adopted even 
though they have been unable to halt the eurozone crisis.

Is the exit strategy as a response to the crisis in the eurozone?

In our view the basic problem is not the supposed radical nature of the 
strategy, but that it fails to challenge deeply enough prevailing views about 
the nature of the Greek predicament. In this way it is also unable to break 
with ruling ideas concerning the importance of the national economy and 
competitiveness. The serious economic and social consequences of breaking off 
from the euro are to be met with, presumably in rapid succession, capital 
controls, nationalization of the banking sector and leading industries, and 
industrial policies. That is to say, we have a national response in the face of 
a globalized world, with all the numerous interdependencies that this entails, 
and a capitalist class united and organized at the world level.

The alternative supported here does not ignore the importance of the nation 
state and local struggles. On the contrary, it is happy to concede that the 
primary locus of struggle is within the nation state and against the bourgeois 
class of that state. But it is also keenly aware of the importance of reaching 
out to secure alliances, and promoting initiatives, beyond the boundaries of 
the nation state. Labour in both the PI(I)Gs and the northern economies has a 
lot of common interests that need to be exploited. Some in the exit camp have 
been keen to place their approach within the tradition of leftist 
internationalism. Thus it has sometimes been argued that Greece represents the 
weakest link in the capitalist chain, and that a radical break with the 
eurozone in Greece will lead to radicalizing initiatives elsewhere. But it is 
not that convincing that a strategy that relies, in its initial stages at 
least, on a competitive devaluation to promote the competitiveness of the Greek 
capita
 list economy can be sold as an exercise in internationalism. Moreover the 
emphasis on the national economy does not suggest that an integral aspect of 
the strategy is the process of bringing together the largest possible 
concentration of the forces of labour to take on the class enemy.

An additional problem is that such approaches fail to learn from history: 
national roads together with the demonisation of the foreign ‘other’ without a 
proper antidote of making the necessary class distinctions and integrating 
within a regional class struggle are easily manipulated by the forces of 
nationalism. This is particularly poignant in the Greek context, where the debt 
default and euro exit option has been taken up wholeheartedly by a wide range 
of nationalistic forces, whose anti-imperialist rhetoric is not always easily 
distinguishable from that of certain sections of the Left[6] . Debt default is 
supported in these currents because Greece does “not owe anything; they owe 
us”, and that the county is facing a new form of “occupation”, a term that 
still has a powerful resonance in a country that has not forgotten its wartime 
experience and all that followed from that. This line of reasoning, needless to 
say, does not allow any internal division between the “peo
 ple” and the “nation”.

Syriza has taken a clear position on this. Also on a number of times, the 
general secretary of the KKE, Aleka Papariga, has suggested that in current 
circumstances a withdrawal from the euro could have catastrophic consequences. 
For the KKE the exit is postponed to the longer run, under conditions of 
“popular power”. Thus the stance of Syriza, and also to a certain extent the 
KKE, with respect to the exit strategy has nothing to do with their acceptance 
of a “role of passive repositories for popular rage” (Kouvelakis, 2011, p. 31) 
but more with a class analysis of the capitalist crisis and their historical 
understanding of the dynamics of nationalistic politics.

The long tradition within the Greek Left of placing great emphasis on the 
reconstruction of the economy has also influenced the dominant discourse, in 
particular modernizing currents that came to the fore with the first Kostas 
Simitis PASOK government in 1996. The dominant discourse has argued that it 
represents the outward- looking pro-European option. In actual fact what has 
been on offer is a national strategy within the EU. Modernizers, before and 
after the outbreak of the crisis, were willing to offer some criticism of 
existing EU policies and institutions, but a shift in these was never seen as 
an indispensable element of the solutions offered. In the post-1974 period, the 
Left was concerned with the restructuring of national economy. PASOK and the 
KKE thought that this could be done best outside the (then) EEC, while the 
KKE-interior, reflecting the eurocommunist tendency within Greece, argued that 
a national strategy inside the EEC was more viable. What was lacking from this 
 conflict, which has subsequently re-emerged in different guises a number of 
times, was a strategy based in part on supra-national solutions.

But it is interesting to note that this national emphasis in socialist politics 
had, in the years before the outbreak of the crisis, had been subjected to very 
serious criticism. Much of this revolved around the issue of the economism and 
statism of the traditional Left, as well as its focus on winning elections and 
forming a government, or its governmentalism to use the Greek expression. It 
cannot be said that those supporting the exit have shown any great readiness to 
engage with such criticisms.

For instance the economistic bent of the approach can be fathomed from the 
importance given to acquiring a national currency. There is a case to be made 
whether devaluation can provide the same level of real wage decline but with 
lower unemployment, but it is not obvious that devaluation is always to be 
preferred to the type of internal deflation being pursued at present by the 
Troika. The statism of the approach seems to have learnt nothing from previous 
experiences of Left governments, such as the French experiment in the early 
1980s. The idea that forming a government of the Left is a sufficient condition 
for a change in enforceable policies is one that dies hard it seems. And this 
is especially the case when the emphasis is so much on reconstructing the 
productive basis of the economy in order to be better able to compete, and so 
little on changing the relations of production and promoting new forms of 
social production. This line of argument is taken up more fully in the followi
 ng section. The governmentalism of the approach is evidenced by the emphasis 
given to what a Left government would do in order to bring Greece out of the 
crisis. So the whole Left is entangled in a, often vitriolic, debate of what 
needs to be done once a government of the Left is formed. This can only 
sideline the central tasks of building a movement towards that end, with that 
level of active participation that experience shows is a vital prerequisite for 
making the best use of government.

Underlying this triptych seems a return to a form of popular frontism. It is as 
if the people have a common interest against large capital, thereby 
considerably simplifying the problems of popular and state power. This may be 
also a result of a “centre-periphery” mindset that suggests that Greek 
capitalism is weak and therefore the forces of reaction are also weak. This 
approach does, as we have seen, not stand up well in terms of theory, and 
perhaps more importantly, it has not been borne out by the events after the 
outbreak of the crisis. As Rylmon (2011) points out that:

[the] higher social groups as well as a large section of the middle strata 
accept the deterioration in inequality with respect to income and social 
services, as they do the increase in unemployment and the spread of poverty. In 
spite of the fact that the consequences of the crisis, and the policies that 
have managed that crisis, have some effect for nearly all the population, the 
deterioration that has been enforced by these policies has been met with 
enthusiasm by a large majority of the privileged ... firms are sacking in large 
numbers those who are struggling to preserve the legal rights of workers ... 
therefore calls for national unity in these conditions represent a failure to 
look at the real issue...

Austerity has seriously worsened the conditions of labour. The equality of 
insecurity, to use a telling phrase of John Gray, being imposed on both public 
and private sector workers, has unified the experience of large numbers of 
people, and has put severe limits on individualistic responses while leading to 
the proletarization of sections of the middle class. What we are witnessing is 
the return of the social question, and the prioritization of the issue of jobs 
and wages. This is the basis for a return to class politics and the need to 
start from basics. It is for this reason that one section of the Left has put a 
radical redistribution of income at the heart of its response. It is not “a 
simple rejection of austerity”, as suggested by Kouvelakis (2011, p. 29). Such 
a stance further requires rather more explicitness on possible friends and foes 
than the supporters of the exit strategy are willing to express.

The central issue, for us, at least revolves around whether the basic 
contradiction is between capital and labour or between capital and the people. 
What we need is a discourse, or rhetoric, that elevates class, and not the 
“popular”, and which has the potential to unite the blue- collar worker, the 
precariously employed and the supermarket employee.

This does not imply that there are no middle classes that can take sides with 
the forces labour. But thinking about this issue relies going beyond the 
anti-monopoly schemas that dominate some parts of the Greek Left. The category 
of the middle classes, including the petit bourgeoisie (Milios & Economakis 
2011), covers a wide range of experiences and social practices. The Left needs 
to analyse these distinctions. It also needs a hegemonic politics that seeks to 
reach out to some these classes, not on the basis of their traditional mode of 
operation, which in the Greek case could simply imply tax evasion or worse, but 
on the basis of new practices and new consumption and production prototypes.

Alternatives to the Hegemony of Capitalism

We are criticizing here a position which has a curious conservative quality. It 
is as if the Left has always known the path to socialism, including the optimum 
economic interventions along that path, and all that is needed is the 
appropriate political climate to reactivate the given formula. Making a virtue 
out of necessity, exiting the euro and suspending debt repayment provides an 
ideal framework, it seems, for implementing the usual panoply of leftist 
economic responses: capital controls and the nationalization of the banks, 
price controls, renationalization of most of the public utilities privatized by 
the ND and PASOK administrations since 1996, industrial policy and so on. Those 
who recall the experience, or better the fate, of the Alternative Economic 
Strategy in Britain or the Common Programme of the Left in France, might be 
tempted to express some mild surprise that so little has changed in the rather 
extensive intervening period. Nor can it be said that the proponents of th
 e exit strategy displayed any great interest in discussing the reasons behind 
past failures in alternative economic experiments or the extent to which 
economic developments since the 1970s, such as globalization and 
financialisation, necessitated certain new departures.

But thinking about alternatives is not only a matter of assessing past 
failures. In most Marxist conceptualizations, theory, and therefore practice, 
should in part be based on the generalization of the actual experience of 
working class. More recently, leftists would be keen to extend this formulation 
to the experience of the feminist, anti-racist and other movements, such as 
those that have been struggling against the commodification of social and 
public goods. The experience of the anti-globalization movement, given its 
prevalence in the lean years of neo-liberal hegemony, would seem to provide an 
excellent workshop for leftists seeking guidance about how to think about 
alternative economic and political strategies. Grass roots activism, 
self-organization, self-management, the social economy, social auditing, fair 
trading and ethical banking would seem to be just some of the experiences that 
have sprung up across the world which could realistically form the elements of 
a new approa
 ch. Not necessarily as alternatives to, say, democratic planning or industrial 
policy, but at least as useful additions. We would stress two themes, common to 
many of these innovations: that social needs provide the essential starting 
point for thinking about any alternative (see Lebowitz, 2003), and that an 
active response from the agents of change is indispensable for addressing those 
needs and therefore also for the political aspects of any transition 
strategy[7] .

It is not that either of these themes was entirely missing from previous 
experiments. To take just one example, British leftists who engaged with the 
Alternative Economic Strategy were keen to stress the role of industrial 
democracy and workers’ participation. It would go too far to claim that the 
strategy relied exclusively on the transfer into state ownership of large banks 
and enterprises. But it is no exaggeration to claim that there was an inflated 
expectation concerning the degree to which such a transfer would, by itself, 
open new opportunities for a socialist transition. In retrospect it seems that 
the dominant view was that a state controlled by the Left could be relied upon 
to know which needs of labour have to be prioritized, while the active 
involvement of those from below was, at best, an additional extra.

In our conception, on the other hand, what the two themes – needs and active 
participation from below – provide is a basis for uniting the experiences of a 
wide range of movements, some of which are anti-capitalist, but many of which 
have an anti-capitalist dynamic without any conscious commitment to that 
effect. The connecting threads seek to challenge both production and 
consumption prototypes of capitalism, and not just of the neo-liberal variety. 
They bring to the fore, in new and interesting ways, the historical Marxist 
problematic concerning who produces what for whom and how. They open up the 
question of new technologies and how these can serve communities rather than 
the control of capitalists over production and distribution processes. They 
relate directly to ecological concerns about sustainable development or 
feminist ones about the role of “care” in our societies.

At the same time after 2008, and in Greece especially after 2010, social 
resistance to austerity included diverse forms of solidarity and initiatives to 
set up a parallel social economy. It could be argued that these experiments 
were hesitant and sporadic, while they lacked the critical mass necessary to 
provide viable alternative modes of consumption and production, let alone to 
seriously challenge the system. But in the position we are criticizing here 
such experiments tended to be seen, if at all, as useful protests that 
expressed disaffection with the austerity policies of the government. They had 
little bearing on the big picture of setting up a viable socialist economy.

We would argue that this is too limited a conception. When Kouvelakis (2011) 
argues that Syriza limited its political strategy to opposing austerity and 
hoping that the Greek debt problem would be solved at some unspecified moment 
in the future he is doubly misleading. First, one section of the radical Left 
argues that we need to go beyond the issue of debt, important though it is, if 
the Left is to provide convincing answers to the crisis. To conceptualize the 
issue as a straight fight between those arguing for austerity within the euro 
and those arguing for exiting the euro to provide space for the restructuring 
of the economy and growth, is to remain on the terrain of the dominant 
ideology. For that ideology, most often experienced as a threat, maintains that 
the only alternative to austerity is being expelled of the eurozone and all the 
significant costs this entails. This dilemma can only be transcended when the 
problem of debt is given its proper weighting, along with the issue
 s of the crisis in capitalist production and consumption prototypes discussed 
above.

Secondly, that part of the Left, criticized by Kouvelakis, was intensely 
engaged in all those movements discussed above. Not only as an expression of 
solidarity, but also through a belief that if the Left was to regain its 
hegemony it needed to prove that it was not only saying different things from 
the dominant elites, but also doing different things. Neo-liberalism has, as it 
is often argued, led to a devaluation of politics and its potential to actually 
change things. The issue, therefore, resolves around the agency of social 
change. For us these forms of solidarity and social economy are better seen as 
practices with radical potential. At one level they provide an immediate 
response to the needs of those at the butt end of the neo-liberal response to 
the crisis. But at another they provide transformative structures (Suchting, 
1983), in which people come to see the value, of say solidarity, in practice 
and come to see that politics, widely defined, can actually change things. To b
 e sure, people primarily shift position because of material circumstances and 
ideological reconsideration. But practices that are antithetical to capitalist 
values can also play a key role: in a context where trade unions, or working 
class associations of all types, are unable to fulfill such a role, at least to 
the extent they did in the past, the Left needs to think very seriously about 
the role of alternative practices.

Unless that is, one thinks that the most important element in transforming 
consciousness is the homing in on the “correct” political line with respect to 
present conjuncture. For many on the Greek Left, we fear, the response of 
exiting the euro and the suspension of debt repayments was/is just such a line, 
which, for reasons that have already been elucidated we question. But the point 
here is that there is only so much that the correct “line” can achieve. Given 
the above, it is not surprising that the position we are critiquing here failed 
to ask difficult questions about the level of support for its chosen strategy. 
Often it assumed exactly what needed to be shown.

In Greece, even amongst progressive sections of the population, there is 
widespread skepticism that the existing state can be a vehicle for change in 
anything resembling a desired direction. This reflects not only the effects of 
so many years of neo-liberal hegemony but the actual workings of the Greek 
state – a hierarchical, inefficient, clientelistic and authoritarian state 
which has served Greek capitalists and their allies well. How to challenge such 
a state, how to democratize it, how to make it sensitive to social needs, and 
how to link it to forms of direct democracy would seem to be some of the more 
pressing questions for the Greek Left. But not for the view we are critiquing 
here where it is assumed that: 1) the state is in a position to carry out the 
traditional panoply of leftist economic alternatives and 2) that enough people 
believe this to be the case. There seems little warrant for either assertion. 
It is not as if there any easy answers to such questions. But it is 
 difficult to believe that progress can be made without at least setting them, 
and at various levels. Can, for instance, public sector unions transform 
themselves to be able to integrate their traditional demands to those consumer 
groups and social movements demanding better public services?

But are we seriously suggesting that progress towards socialism, or at least a 
leftist exit from the crisis that opens up new agendas, needs to wait for the 
resolution of such difficult questions? Of course not, but our objections do 
resolve around a long debated issue of the Left. In the context of the Greek 
conjuncture it can be stated simply in terms of whether the programme of the 
Left can be said to preexist independently of the movement. Notice that this 
question holds whether we conceive the movement towards a different society in 
terms of a long process of evolutionary changes within capitalism, in terms of 
a more condensed period of rupture with the capitalist system or something in 
between (of intermediate “ruptures” along the path to socialism as left 
eurocommunists used to argue).

Opponents of the line of exiting the euro and the suspension of debt repayment 
were/are keen to argue that, whatever we think of the issue, it need not become 
an obstacle to finding common ground in the here and present. After all nobody 
in their right minds actually announces a devaluation - just think what would 
happen to bank deposits on the eve of an election when a victory for the Left 
was on the cards. But the main issue is whether, in the period when the 
movement to support a radical break with the present system is emerging, we 
prioritize the essential unity of the movement and its interconnectedness on 
common concerns and aspirations, or, on the other hand, the “correct” political 
line? Is the movement to be divided now because of the very different answers 
to what a Left government needs to do once in power concerning the exchange 
rate and reducing the level of debt repayments? More than the actual answer to 
the question of the appropriate exchange rate regime, it is th
 e priority given to the question that we have found immensely problematic, and 
especially when it has been used as an excuse to resist social pressures for 
the unity of the Left in response to the austerity programmes.

Notes


[1] Antarsya represents a political alliance of a number of extra-parliamentary 
leftist parties from various traditions (Trotskyist, orthodox Marxist, and 
others). Syriza represents a much larger grouping, in terms of numbers and 
electoral appeal (it currently has 9 Members of Parliament), based around 
Synaspismos, the largest Greek Left party after the KKE, with a number of 
smaller leftist parties also stemming from different traditions (Trotskyist, 
Maoist, left-eurocommunist etc). The main orthodox communist party, the KKE, 
remained rather aloof from the debate concerning the euro. While the KKE is a 
virulently anti-EU party, and is clear that progress to socialism requires 
Greece leaving not only the euro, but the EU itself, it was, on the whole, 
unwilling to commit itself to a short-term strategy of exiting the euro.
[2]We are less convinced, however, of the argument that Germany is so 
committed, as Lapavitsas (2012) seems to believe, to the importance of the euro 
as a form of world money. Germany, before the euro, was always sceptical about 
the deutschmark turning into a major reserve currency, and this scepticism has 
carried over with respect to the euro.
[3] It is an uncomfortable fact for present day supporters of the exit strategy 
that their approach has so much resonance with the failed “socialist” 
experience of the early 1980s in Greece. PASOK in that period was also 
committed to a national road in which industrial policy, planning agreements 
and socialization of the public sector were to play a major role, in an 
environment where capital controls, the exchange rate and monetary policy were 
freely available as policy tools.
[4]Alpha Bank, Greece and Southeastern Europe. Economic & Financial Outlook, 
n.74, May 2010 (internet: 
http://www.alpha.gr/files/infoanalyses/Greece_&_Southe astern_201005.pdf).
[5] This, be it noted, does not apply in the case of Ireland.
[6] Thus D. Kazakis, an independent economist, originally from the KKE, has set 
up his own party with identifiable nationalistic sentiments. Before that his 
support for the default and exit option ensured that he was given a platform by 
leftist organizations that should have known better. Another case is that of 
Spitha (spark), a group that has coalesced around the famous musician Mikis 
Theodorakis. Theodorakis is a historic figure of the Left, but his increasingly 
patriotic rhetoric, and some unsavoury company, has meant that it is the 
nationalistic aspects of the Spitha that dominate.
[7] These two themes are central to Laskos and Tsakalotos’ (2011) book, in 
Greek, which looks at the Left’s response to the crisis in a historical 
perspective. The ‘no turning back’ title of the book refers not only to the 
social democratic and neo-liberal experiments of the post-war period, but also 
to the Left’s response to the crisis of the 1970s in terms of national 
strategies, essentially of reconstruction of the domestic economy.

References

Kouvelakis S. (2011) ‘The Greek Cauldron’, New Left Review, 72, 
November-December, pp. 17-32.
Lapavitsas C., Kaltenbrunner A., Lindo D., Michell J., Painceira J. P., Pires 
E., Powell J., Stenfors A., Teles E. (2010) Eurozone Crisis: begger thyself and 
thy neighbour, Research on Money and Finance, Occasional Report.
Lapavitsas C., A. Kaltenbrunner, G. Lambrinidis, D. Lindo, J. Meadway, J. 
Michell, J.P. Painceira, E. Pires, J. Powell, A. Stenfors, N. Teles y L. 
Vatikiotis (2011) Breaking Up? A Route Out of the Eurozone Crisis, Research in 
Money and Finance, Special Report 3.
Lapavitsas K. ‘Default and Exit from the Eurozone: A Radical Left Strategy’, 
Socialist Register 2012: The Crisis and the Left, vol. 48.
Laskos Ch. and Tsakalotos E. (2011) No Turning Back: capitalist crises, social 
needs, socialism, KaPsiMi publications, Athens (in Greek).
Lebowitz D. (2003) Beyond Political Economy: Marx’s Political Economy of the 
Working Class, Palgrave Macmillan.
Milios J. and Sotiropoulos D. (2009) Rethinking Imperialism: A Study of 
Capitalist Rule, Palgrave Macmillan.
Milios J. and G. Economakis (2011), ‘The Middle Classes, Class Places, and 
Class Positions: A Critical Approach to Nicos Poulantzas’s Theory’, Rethinking 
Marxism Vol. 23 No. 2 (April), pp. 226-245.
Rylmon (2011) ‘There is no quick exit strategy’, Epoxi, 30/12/11.
Suchting W. A. (1983) Marx: An Introduction, Wheatsheaf Books















_______________________________________________
P2P Foundation - Mailing list

Blog - http://www.blog.p2pfoundation.net
Wiki - http://www.p2pfoundation.net

Show some love and help us maintain and update our knowledge commons by making 
a donation. Thank you for your support.
https://blog.p2pfoundation.net/donation

https://lists.ourproject.org/cgi-bin/mailman/listinfo/p2p-foundation

Reply via email to