On the specialness of labor
===========================

1.  Everybody knows that human labor is a special process and labor-
power a very special commodity.  But a certain sort of hard-nosed 
theorist is very unwilling to grant labor any special theoretical privilege.  
This attitude, although I think it is ultimately theoretically debilitating, is 
understandable.  One doesn't want to be caught sneaking into one's 
basic economic *theory* a privileging of labor that is based on 
scientifically "extraneous" ideological, political or humanitarian 
concerns.  If the LTV acquires its "validity" *only* from, say, a 
standpoint of political-ideological sympathy with the labor movement, 
this seems like sufficient reason for rejecting it.  

2.  Sraffa's very title, "The Production of Commodities by Means of 
Commodities," seems to bespeak such a concern, which is more 
explicit in some of his followers.  From the abstract theorist's point of 
view, labor (or rather labor-power) is just one of the n commodities 
that jointly produce each other.  

3.  I will attempt to allay this fear, showing that the granting of a 
special privilege to human labor time, and the commodity labor 
power, is *not in the least* (or need not be) the effect of the intrusion 
of extraneous factors into the realm of theory.  

4.  Here is a very broad first pass:  The economy is "about" the 
production of goods that serve certain human purposes, by human 
beings, via their labor time.  (The stipulation that the goods "serve 
human purposes" -- though those purposes may be quite various -- is 
necessary to distinguish economic production from, e.g., the 
production by humans of carbon dioxide and other bodily wastes.)  Is 
this an "ideological" statement, extraneous to science?  Not at all.  
Some such statement is absolutely required to prevent the "economy" 
from *vanishing* as a specific object of theoretical investigation.  
Otherwise how can one make a principled distinction between the 
economy, and all the other stuff going on in the biosphere (with which, 
of course, the economy is intricately linked)?  

5.  One could try delimiting the economy as the set of activities that 
earn (and participate in the determination of) the equalized rate of 
profit.  But strictly speaking, this would be the empty set.  Or "the set 
of activities involving the allocation of scarce resources by and on 
behalf of humans."  But that, IMO, is too broad to isolate the 
economy as such; and besides, it skirts the point -- to be defended 
shortly -- that labor is the *key* "scarce resource."  

6.  There follow three quotations, one from each of the classical 
proponents of the LTV.  No, this is not an appeal to authority.  It is a 
limbering-up exercise, a preliminary to presenting some further angles 
on the "specialness" of labor.  If you are interested in this topic, I 
would ask you to try to look at these quotes with fresh eyes -- to 
ignore the fact that they are almost cliches, and to see if they suggest 
any interesting implications.  

A.  Smith: 

   The real price of everything, what everything really costs to the man 
who wants to acquire it, is the toil and trouble of acquiring it. ... 
Labour was the first price, the original purchase-money that was paid 
for all things.  It was not by gold or silver, but by labour, that all the 
wealth of the world was originally purchased...  

B.  Ricardo: 

   Possessing utility, commodities derive their exchangeable value from 
two sources: from their scarcity, and from the quantity of labour 
required to obtain them.  
   There are some commodities, the value of which is determined by 
their scarcity alone.  No labour can increase the quantity of such 
goods, and therefore their value cannot be lowered by an increased 
supply.  Some rare statues and pictures, scare books and coins, wines 
of a peculiar quality, which can be made only from grapes grown on a 
particular soil, of which there is a very limited quantity, are all of this 
description.  Their value is wholly independent of the quantity of 
labour originally necessary to produce them, and varies with the 
varying wealth and inclinations of those who are desirous to possess 
them.  
   These commodities, however, form a very small part of the mass of 
commodities daily exchanged in the market.  *By far the greatest part 
of those goods which are the object of desire, are procured by labour; 
and they may be multiplied, not in one country alone, but in many, 
almost without any assignable limit, if we are disposed to bestow the 
labour necessary to obtain them.* (emphasis added)

C.  Marx:

   Every child knows that any nation that stopped working, not for a 
year, but let us say, just for a few weeks, would perish.  And every 
child knows, too, that the amounts of products corresponding to the 
differing amounts of needs demand differing and quantitatively 
determined amounts of society's aggregate labour.  It is self-evident 
that this necessity of the distribution of social labour in specific 
proportions is certainly not abolished by the specific form of social 
production; it can only change its form of manifestation.  


==========================
Allin Cottrell 
Department of Economics 
Wake Forest University
[EMAIL PROTECTED]
(910) 759-5762
==========================


Reply via email to