Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives Monitor, November 1995 GLOBALIZATION AND DEMOCRACY: "Free trade" gives freedom only to capital by Ian Robinson Supporters of the Canada-U.S. Free Trade Agreement (FTA), the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA), and the Uruguay Round of the General Agreement on Trade and Tariffs (GATT) portray them as mere extensions of the trade- liberalizing trend that followed the Great Depression. They insist on calling them "free trade agreements" when in fact they go far beyond the traditional purpose of such agreements: reducing quotas and tariff barriers to international trade in non-agricultural goods. The new agreements (1) created new international property rights for foreign investors and intellectual innovators; (2) created new legal restrictions on government regulations; and (3) applied traditional GATT principles (i.e., "national treatment" and "most favoured national") to trade in agricultural goods and all categories of services. These innovations substantially increase capital mobility. It is now easier and more attractive to shift investment from domestic to foreign sites. This "exit" option gives corporations more leverage to demand reductions in taxes, regulations and wages that are said to curb profitability and competitiveness. Because their most important impact is the promotion of capital mobility -- and with it freedom from the constraints of democratic governments and unions -- these deals are more appropriately called "free capital agreements." These agreements embody a laissez-faire approach to the regulation of the global market economy. However, like national market economies, a global marker economy could also be governed by social democratic principles. A social democratic form of globalization would not aim to increase capital mobility and corporate property rights. Corporate capital was already highly mobile, by historical standards, before the FTA, NAFTA, and the Uruguay Round of GATT. From a social democratic perspective, the social dimension of international economic integration lags far behind existing levels of capital mobility. Two things are required to overcome this lag: * First, the regulation of international competition among states and firms so as to yield socially and environmentally desirable outcomes. * Second, the redistribution of a substantial part of the economic gains from globalization to those who are most in need and most vulnerable to the massive restructuring that globalization brings in its wake. These objectives should be the principal focus of binding, enforceable international agreements for the next 10 or 20 years. DEMOCRATIC SCOPE Why should we prefer a social democratic to a neo- liberal (or laissez-faire) form of globalization? One important reason is that the latter substantially reduces the degree to which citizens are able to exercise democratic control over their society and its economy. Free capital agreements reduce the scope of democracy by transferring the power to make decisions on important social and economic issues to unaccountable supranational public and private bureaucracies. A lot of criticism of NAFTA and the WTO focused on the lack of accountability of the tribunals that would administer these rules. While not without merit, this is not the most fundamental problem with these trade deals. Even the fairest, most open and transparent process, administered with perfect impartiality, will not generate good outcomes if the rules that these supranational tribunals are required to interpret and enforce are inappropriate. Conversely, if these international agreements reflected a social democratic vision of globalization, rather than a neo-liberal one, questions of process and accountability would be less pressing, though still important. The free capital agreements do this in two basic ways: first, through the legal restrictions they impose on the policies that governments may adopt; and second, through the market pressures that intensifying competition for scarce private investment imposes on national and provincial governments. The most important new legal restrictions on democratic states have to do with investment, intellectual property rights, and technical standards. NAFTA's investment chapter, for example, prohibits a wide variety of "performance requirements" -- that is, conditions that governments might require foreign investors to meet in return for the right to invest in a country. Among other things, states are barred from requiring foreign investors to transfer technologies, and from mandating that a share of the materials used in production be locally purchased, or that raw materials be processed to a certain level before export, or that a certain share of profits be locally invested. (Such conditions have been used by many countries in the past to diversity their economies and to increase the value-added manufacturing potential of their resources.) Nor can government create public corporations, embark upon new programs, or introduce new regulations that might reduce the "reasonably expected" value of foreign investments without paying compensation, or else they run the risk of trade sanctions. For example, if a province that doesn't already have public auto insurance wanted to introduce such a plan, it would have to pay compensation to any American Insurance companies that would lose business as a result. If Canada didn't already have a national health insurance program, its implementation today would require the same compensation to be paid to American health insurance companies operating in Canada. The necessity of paying such compensation could make new policies and programs prohibitively expensive, whatever the public interest. U.S. insurance companies do not occupy a large place in the Canadian auto or health insurance markets at present, but the free capital agreements could change that as well. For example, the investment chapter of NAFTA limits restrictions on foreign ownership, even in such sensitive areas as financial services. It thus paves the way for mergers and takeovers that could make these new property rights much more important over time. NAFTA's intellectual property provisions are similarly restrictive. When Canada's minister of health, Diane Marleau, announced that she would introduce legislation requiring that all cigarettes be sold in plain packages, U.S. free trade negotiator Carla Hills (in her new incarnation as an international trade lawyer) appeared on behalf of American cigarette manufacturers to warn the Canadian government that such a policy would constitute a "taking" of their intellectual property (specifically, their trademarks). Unless they were fully compensated for the resulting loss of sales, such a "taking" would violate NAFTA and open Canada to retaliation by the United States. The Canadian government quickly abandoned the plain packaging proposal. Finally, the technical standards provisions of the free capital agreements make it significantly more difficult for governments to defend regulations that are more stringent than an international minimum, requiring them to demonstrate that a challenged regulation is the "least trade restrictive necessary" to achieve a "legitimate" public objective. Tax policies are also highly vulnerable to capital mobility. The United States has a long experience of municipalities and states bidding down their property and corporate taxes in the competition for private investment. The same thing happened to death duties in Canada when they were decentralized from the federal government to the provinces. In a few years, they had been dramatically reduced by inter-provincial competition for investment. International competition has intensified in recent years, and, by increasing capital mobility, the free capital deals will intensify this problem in all countries. The impact of increased capital mobility on corporate taxation is exactly paralleled by its impact on corporate regulation. Any regulation can become the target of downward market pressures simply by virtue of the fact that transnational corporations regard it as a cost. SOCIAL DUMPING In the jargon of the European Union, this competitive bidding down of taxes and standards is called "social dumping." The ban on performance requirements protects corporations from competing against one another to give governments concessions in return for the right to invest. There is nothing, however, to prevent governments from competing to offer corporations concessions in return for their investment, and much that encourages it. The capacity of unions to reduce or stabilize income inequality through collective bargaining is also weakened. Unions face transnational corporations from a much weaker bargaining position than they do national or provincial or municipal employers. Any good or service that is domestically produced but might be produced elsewhere is vulnerable to corporate pressure to cut wages and benefits in order to reduce the attraction of shifting production overseas. We can therefore expect substantial increases in income inequality under the free capital agreements. The experience of the last 15 years supports this expectation. In this period, income inequality in the four countries that pursued neoliberal policies most rigorously -- in the U.S., Britain, New Zealand and Canada -- increased more rapidly than in the other OECD countries. SOCIAL DEMOCRATIC GLOBALIZATION A pro-democratic form of globalization would have to achieve three things: 1. reduce the legal restrictions on democratic governments associated with the investor, intellectual property, and technical standards provisions briefly discussed above; 2. neutralize the social dumping pressures associated with the high levels of capital mobility that will exist in any global market economy; and 3. create new mechanisms for redistributing a substantial portion of the economic gains from globalization to those individuals and nations most in need. The last two elements, taken together, are what the Europeans call "the social dimension" of international economic integration. A global social dimension, on the European model, would have two basic components: (1) a social and environmental charter and (2) structural funds. The charter would set out basic worker rights and labour and environmental standards that all members of the GATT, IMF, and other international organizations would have to meet. The structural funds would transfer resources from those who gain from market restructuring to those who lose. They would also help pay for the upgrading and infrastructure, and the promotion of economic development in depressed regions. In the short run, any such international social dimension would be very limited. However, it could be large enough to make a difference and it could be expanded over time. The European Union's social dimension -- except for its agricultural priced support system -- started out very small. But as the integration accelerated in the latter half of the 1980s, its structural funds twice doubled in size. By 1997, these funds will transfer about US$68 billion a year to poorer parts of the Union. I propose a very simple global social charter to begin with. It would protect just four basic worker rights: * the right to organize unions that members control democratically; * the right to engage in collective bargaining and to strike when such bargaining does not resolve the issues in dispute; * freedom from forced labour for children and prisoners; and * freedom from discrimination in hiring, promotion, and remuneration. This list is hardly adequate, even on the labour side of the social charter. It says nothing about what minimum standards should be included on the environmental side. However, if unions were strong and democratic, their members would be able to mobilize in pursuit of stronger standards, as in the early industrializing countries. Conversely, one can have the best labour standards in the world on paper, but if unions are not free and democratic, standards will not be effectively monitored and enforced. Further progress will be possible internationally as the domestic balance of political power is altered in the less developed countries, increasing the receptiveness of their governments to a more comprehensive international social charter. Beyond these four basic worker rights, the social charter would also follow the European example by protecting basic democratic rights. Worker rights don't mean much under authoritarian regimes, and neither do environmental standards, as the record of environmental degradation in Eastern Europe demonstrates. Environmental destruction is first and foremost a problem of political failure -- the failure to give the people most directly harmed by bad environmental practices sufficient political power to alter such practices. By expanding the scope of democratic control over such matters, a social democratic charter would be a substantial contribution to improving environmental conditions. The revenue source for the structural funds, and the formula by which they would be allocated, could also be kept very simple. One intriguing candidate for this role is the tax on international currency transactions proposed by Yale economist and Nobel Prize winner James Toxin. (See the recent CCPA report, "The Tobin Tax," by James Tobin, an excerpt from which appeared in the October 1995 issue of The Monitor.) This tax would yield more than $1 trillion in revenues every year. To qualify for their share, governments would have to respect the four basic labour rights, the environmental standards, and the requirement for democratic government that constitute the social charter. What can we do to promote such forms of social democratic globalization? One of the first priorities is to expose the coercive and anti-democratic character of neo- liberalism. Challenging the three foundational myths of globalization -- that its neo-liberal form is technologically rather than politically determined, inevitable and benign -- is an excellent place to begin. The principal vehicle for getting a different message to the public -- the message that there are realistic and workable alternatives on the left -- must be the array of social movements and non-profit organizations that cooperated in the struggle against the FTA, NAFTA, and the Uruguay GATT. This "common front" included the labour movement, most of the environmental movement, women's and students' organizations, family farm organizations, anti- poverty coalitions, and religious groups promoting human rights, peace and development. Together, these movements and organizations represent a substantial part of the populations of all the countries whose governments signed the free capital agreements. These movements were successful in convincing majorities of the informed Canadian electorate (i.e., those who had any opinion at all on the matter) that the FTA and NAFTA were contrary to the public interest. Their U.S. counterparts achieved the same success there in their fight against NAFTA. They did this despite the extraordinary financial and political resources ranged against them. Thus, a coalition of these social movements -- both within and across national boundaries -- has great political potential. For many of the leaders and activists in these organizations, their cooperation in the fights against the FTA, NAFTA and the Uruguay GATT began as a marriage of convenience. But by the end of the NAFTA struggle, a consensus was emerging that the common enemy was corporate- led neo-liberal globalization rather than any particular trade deal. The international common front also began to work on developing a common alternative to that vision. The most detailed expression of this vision to date is "A Just and Sustainable Trade and Development Initiative for the Western Hemisphere," developed by American, Mexican and Canadian opponents of free trade, including the Action Canadian Network. (See The Monitor, October 1994.) It is too early to know whether this vision can inspire the sustained "common front" of social movements that will be necessary if the social democratic vision of globalization is to prevail. But many activists in these movements are coming to the conclusion that they must now dedicate themselves to this end. We must do everything we can to strengthen the political tendency they represent. --------------------------------------- Ian Robinson is a professor of political science at Reed College, Portland, Ore., and author of the 1993 CCPA study "North American Trade As If Democracy Mattered." A longer version of this article was published earlier in DISSENT magazine. ---------------------------------------- THE CHILEAN CONNECTION Chile was selected as the first candidate for accession to NAFTA because of the apparent success of the economic reforms undertaken by the government that succeeded the country's military dictatorship. A closer look at the Chilean "miracle", however, shows that It has been achieved at the price of continuing human and labour rights violations. The repression of unions In Chile has been so extreme that the number of unionized workers has dropped from 33% of the work force to just 13%. Wages have been depressed to their average level of 25 years ago. The current minimum wage in Chile is only US$15O a month. The benefits of Chile's economic growth have been distributed very unevenly. After Brazil, Chile has the most unequal income distribution in Latin America: the richest 10% of the population receives 36 times more than the poorest 10%. According to economist Jacobo Schatan, the richest 100,000 Chileans control as much income as the poorest 6,000,000. Chilean unionists and social activists are convinced that NAFTA will weaken rather than strengthen that country's economy and do nothing to help establish real democracy there. According to studies carried out by the Confederatlon of Production and Trade and the National Agricultural Society, the expansion of maquiladora industries spurred by NAFTA will cause a loss of jobs in textiles, leather and shoe production, and in some mining sectors. It will damage the production of traditional crops such as wheat, corn and food-oil products. It is also likely to further impoverish Chile's indigenous peoples.