(Harry Shutt, "The Trouble With Capitalism: an Enquiry into the Causes of
the Global Economic Failure", Zed Books, 1998, pp. 194-196)


RETREATING TO DETERMINISM

Confronted with the obstinate refusal of growth to revive, a significant
number of economists and others have been inclined to flirt with
quasi-metaphysical theories which supposedly give grounds for expecting a
spontaneous recovery in the global economy irrespective of the revealed
current tendency of market forces. According to such theories economic
growth is governed by very long cycles (of fifty years or more), which
their advocates claim can explain the ups and downs of the world economy at
least since the Industrial Revolution, and that these unfold more or less
independently of any 'man-made' events or influences such as world wars,
political changes or innovations in technology. To anyone who recognises
economics to be a social science -- and hence inherently subject to the
unpredictable actions and reactions of ever-changing human society --such
attempts to subject it to a series of rigid laws of motion can scarcely
seem worthy of a moment's consideration. That some respectable academics
have allowed themselves to take such theories seriously is thus only of
interest as an indicator of how far some will go to avoid addressing the
harsh realities of systemic failure.

An even more desperate response of some economists, manifested in 1997 to
the failure of the longed-for growth revival to materialise, has been to
claim that it is actually happening but that somehow the statistics have
failed to record it -- or are inherently incapable not doing so. The main
basis for these rather nebulous assertions appears to be that the large
productivity gains resulting from the information technology revolution
must be resulting in higher levels of output --or that, at the very least,
the benefits to consumers resulting from the increased efficiency and
convenience of the goods and services affected (such as that provided by
cash-dispensing machines) ought to be reflected in a higher rate of
economic growth than that actually recorded -- rather than in an increased
capacity surplus. These claims have been advanced mainly by Wall Street
economists -- with the blessing of none other than Chairman Alan Greenspan
of the Federal Reserve Board (the US central bank) -- in an effort to
convince the investor community that the huge surge in stock prices (which
had doubled in just over two years since 1995) did not overstate the true
value of the underlying assets. The most bizarre aspect these arguments is
that they amount to a repudiation of one of most elementary tenets of
market economics, namely that the only activities that count for the
purposes of measuring total output income are those that are actually paid
for and can thus be valued terms of a common monetary unit of account. As
such they seem unlikely to convince serious investors that there is any
hidden real value in corporate equities. Rather their significance lies
mainly demonstrating the extent to which highly qualified economists are
prepared to sacrifice their intellectual self-respect in order to serve the
interests of a beleaguered financial establishment.

CONCLUSION: NO WAY OUT

If we concede that it is difficult, if not impossible, to give definitive
explanations for why particular past surges in economic growth happened
when they did, we must also concede that the possibility of another one
occurring 'spontaneously' in the near future cannot be excluded. Yet the
analysis presented in this chapter unquestionably indicates stronger
grounds for expecting it not to occur. Moreover this conclusion is
reinforced by consideration of the huge scale the growth needed to reverse
the slide to disaster.

To put this in perspective, it should be noted that, even though growth
rates recorded by OECD countries since the mid-1970s averaging some 2.5 per
cent a year -- have been low by the standards of the 1950s and 1960s, they
appear to be very much in line with the norm for industrialised countries
over the hundred years prior to World War II. Despite this, as we have
seen, they have been insufficient to prevent either a growing
underutilisation of both capital and labour or, largely because of this
capacity surplus, a rapid rise in both public and private indebtedness. It
follows that a revival growth will have to be sustained at a rate high
enough to permit the elimination of both the capacity surplus and the
existing debt, while at the same time being consistent with continued high
returns on capital, if a disastrous fall in financial asset values is to be
avoided. It is difficult to estimate exactly what the minimum average
growth rate needed to meet all these requirements would be. Yet there can
be no question but that it would have to be at least as high as the 5 per
cent average real rate recorded in the 1960s -- and perhaps even higher,
assuming a continuing rise in the productivity of capital and labour.
Furthermore, it would probably need to be sustained at that average level
for at least ten to fifteen years before something like balance was restored.

Many have until recently argued that the supposedly dynamic economies of
East Asia -- which have consistently recorded such high growth rates since
the early 1980s -- could provide both the example and the 'locomotive'
power to restore sustained dynamism to the world economy. However, the
record of Japan -- whose model of development they are seeking to emulate
-- gives little ground for optimism, since it has gone from being the
fastest growing industrialised economy in the 1970s and l980s to one of the
slowest growing in the 1990s, as it stagnates under a mountain of bad debt.
In fact, as noted in Chapter 10, there have been increasing signs since
1995 that South Korea, Thailand and other Asian 'tigers' are likewise set
to move to a lower growth path because of problems not dissimilar to those
affecting Japan.

Thus an assessment based on historical evidence and analysis of the more
recent conjuncture of economic forces leads us to the conclusion that only
a veritable miracle could avert an eventual (and perhaps quite early)
world-wide financial and economic collapse such that the organs of state
(whether national or international) will be too impoverished to prevent.
For in order to continue paying for the consequences of the surplus of
capital -- by bailing out insolvent institutions (and countries) and
otherwise subsidising profits -- as well as that of labour (through higher
welfare bills), governments would be forced to raise taxes substantially.
Yet this could now only be done at the cost of either sharply reducing
corporate profits. thereby undermining asset values anyway, and/or further
squeezing of personal incomes, thus engendering still weaker consumption
growth and greater social deprivation. Faced with such an insoluble dilemma
political attention must soon begin to focus on alternatives to the profits
system.


Louis Proyect
(http://www.panix.com/~lnp3/marxism.html)



Reply via email to