Robin Hahnel writes a lot of stuff I agree with. But I missed where he
wrote about how the capitalists (and other elite groups) would use dirty
tricks and violence to undermine and wipe out the mass democratic movement
for socialism that he (and I) advocate. (I recommend "How the Change Came"
in William Morris' utopian novel NEWS FROM NOWHERE for a prescient sketch
of a socialist revolution from below. Many of its events presage actual
revolutions, as in Chile in the early 1970s.)

Further, he writes: 
>Moreover, we can find no solace in old left doctrines of inevitable
collapse. Many twentieth century progressives sustained themselves
emotionally and psychologically with false beliefs that capitalism's
dynamism and technological creativity would prove to be its weakness as
well as its strength. Grandiose Marxist crisis theories -- a tendency for
the rate of profit to fall as machinery was substituted for exploitable
living labor, or insufficient demand to keep the capitalist bubble afloat
as productive potential outstripped the buying power of wages -- buoyed the
hopes of the faithful  in the face of crushing defeats of progressive causes.<

I've studied crisis theory a bit (and seemingly a bit more than Robin).
Some of the theories are wrong, some are right, often in different
situations. In my work, I've tried to synthesize the valid aspects of them.
I won't bore people with the details. But the key point is that (1)
capitalist crises _are_ inevitable (in a sense that is explained below) but
(2) socialism is not. The latter actually requires activist intervention,
because it requires the growth of a mass movement of the sort that Robin
writes, a movement that does not arise -- or win -- automatically in any way. 

Crises involve capitalism fouling its own nest -- a nest in which we have
the misfortune to live. What some or many people from the Old Left missed
was that they don't imply the end of capitalism, only opportunities for
change, either progressive reform or revolution (or regressive changes, as
in Hitler's Germany). The oppressed don't always have it together to take
advantage of those opportunities. In the MANIFESTO, Marx & Engels'
prediction of inevitability was based on an optimistic extrapolation of the
self-organization of the working-class movement, but their theory really
doesn't predict that continuation of the growth of parties and unions.
Despite the optimistic tone, M&E admit that revolution can lead to the
mutual destruction of the two classes (rather than to socialism). This is
what Luxemburg later summarized as "socialism or barbarism" (while the
experience of the East Block indicates a third alternative: socialist
barbarism). Marx's politics were also much more complicated than in the
MANIFESTO, as indicated by Draper's multivolume KARL MARX'S THEORY OF
REVOLUTION. 

(what I mean by inevitability, which follows Luxemburg: the timing of the
crisis can't be predicted, but successful efforts to delay the crisis make
it worse when it comes. For example, Keynesian policies worked for quite
awhile in the US, but contributed in a big way to the stagflation crisis of
the 1970s.)

>Marx's prophesy of economic emiseration did not prove true for the first
world. <

I wish leftists wouldn't imitate the right's labeling of Marx as a prophet
and his predictions as "prophecies." Marx's prediction of _relative_
immiseration was very abstract, being along the lines of an "everything
else equal" prediction. (Economists are always making these kinds of
predictions without being labeled "prophets." One thing that distinguished
Marx from the crowd is that he didn't limit his predictions to small
issues.) As Paul Sweezy pointed out in the first chapter of THE THEORY OF
CAPITALIST DEVELOPMENT, it's a prediction for abstract capitalism, ignoring
such matters as imperialism and trade unions which can counteract the
prediction's working out in specific countries. If capitalism fits Marx's
abstract capitalism, the prediction doesn't work very well without bringing
in all of the complicating factors into the analysis. But if capitalism
fits Marx's abstract description, the prediction works better. It seems to
be working pretty well these days, even in the "first world." 

Though I generally agree with (or at least learn from) the work by Robin
and his usual collaborator, Michael Albert, I wish they wouldn't denigrate
other traditions on the left as much as they do. It smacks of product
differentiation -- a common oligopolistic marketing technique -- or of
academic sectarianism. 

Jim Devine [EMAIL PROTECTED] &
http://clawww.lmu.edu/Departments/ECON/jdevine.html



Reply via email to