Brad DeLong:
>A market economy is--with no externalities, no increasing returns, no
>market power, et cetera, et cetera--a very nice and effective way of
>achieving the goal of maximizing a particular objective function that is
>weighted sum of individual utilities, where each individual's weight is a
>function of wealth: as Mr. Orr said, if you don't have any wealth your
>preferences are simply not registered in the marketplace.

The problem is how to define an economy. In countries like India we are not
really dealing with Robinson Crusoe and his island. From the little I know
of free market ideology--from courses I took as an undergraduate in
1961-65, the model is always geared to a nation-state with England usually
serving as the concrete example, even in some respects in Marx. But what
use is that when the buyer and sellers are operating under the rules that
the British navy and Viceroy establishes? The advantage of Marx and Marxism
is that it highlights the manner in which historical inequalities are
established.

Marx, Capital V. 1, chapter 31, "Genesis of the industrial capitalist":

Of the Christian colonial system, W. Howitt, a man who makes a speciality
of Christianity, says: "The barbarities and desperate outrages of the
so-called Christian race, throughout every region of the world, and upon
every people they have been able to subdue, are not to be paralleled by
those of any other race, however fierce, however untaught, and however
reckless of mercy and of shame, in any age of the earth." [4] The history
of the colonial administration of Holland -- and Holland was the head
capitalistic nation of the 17th century -- "is one of the most
extraordinary relations of treachery, bribery, massacre, and meanness" [5]
Nothing is more characteristic than their system of stealing men, to get
slaves for Java. The men stealers were trained for this purpose. The thief,
the interpreter, and the seller, were the chief agents in this trade,
native princes the chief sellers. The young people stolen, were thrown into
the secret dungeons of Celebes, until they were ready for sending to the
slave-ships. An official report says: "This one town of Macassar, e.g., is
full of secret prisons, one more horrible than the other, crammed with
unfortunates, victims of greed and tyranny fettered in chains, forcibly
torn from their families." To secure Malacca, the Dutch corrupted the
Portuguese governor. He let them into the town in 1641. They hurried at
once to his house and assassinated him, to "abstain" from the payment of
£21,875, the price of his treason. Wherever they set foot, devastation and
depopulation followed. Banjuwangi, a province of Java, in 1750 numbered
over 80,000 inhabitants, in 1811 only 18,000. Sweet commerce! 

 The English East India Company, as is well known, obtained, besides the
political rule in India, the exclusive monopoly of the tea-trade, as well
as of the Chinese trade in general, and of the transport of goods to and
from Europe. But the coasting trade of India and between the islands, as
well as the internal trade of India, were the monopoly of the higher
employés of the company. The monopolies of salt, opium, betel and other
commodities, were inexhaustible mines of wealth. The employés themselves
fixed the price and plundered at will the unhappy Hindus. The
Governor-General took part in this private traffic. His favourites received
contracts under conditions whereby they, cleverer than the alchemists, made
gold out of nothing. Great fortunes sprang up like mushrooms in a day;
primitive accumulation went on without the advance of a shilling. The trial
of Warren Hastings swarms with such cases. Here is an instance. A contract
for opium was given to a certain Sullivan at the moment of his departure on
an official mission to a part of India far removed from the opium district.
Sullivan sold his contract to one Binn for £40,000; Binn sold it the same
day for £60,000, and the ultimate purchaser who carried out the contract
declared that after all he realised an enormous gain. According to one of
the lists laid before Parliament, the Company and its employés from
1757-1766 got £6,000,000 from the Indians as gifts. Between 1769 and 1770,
the English manufactured a famine by buying up all the rice and refusing to
sell it again, except at fabulous prices. [6] 

 The treatment of the aborigines was, naturally, most frightful in
plantation-colonies destined for export trade only, such as the West
Indies, and in rich and well-populated countries, such as Mexico and India,
that were given over to plunder. But even in the colonies properly so
called, the Christian character of primitive accumulation did not belie
itself. Those sober virtuosi of Protestantism, the Puritans of New England,
in 1703, by decrees of their assembly set a premium of £40 on every Indian
scalp and every captured red-skin: in 1720 a premium of £100 on every
scalp; in 1744, after Massachusetts-Bay had proclaimed a certain tribe as
rebels, the following prices: for a male scalp of 12 years and upwards £100
(new currency), for a male prisoner £105, for women and children prisoners
£50, for scalps of women and children £50. Some decades later, the colonial
system took its revenge on the descendants of the pious pilgrim fathers,
who had grown seditious in the meantime. At English instigation and for
English pay they were tomahawked by red-skins. The British Parliament
proclaimed bloodhounds and scalping as "means that God and Nature had given
into its hand." 


Louis Proyect
(http://www.panix.com/~lnp3/marxism.html)



Reply via email to