>From Jim D. to Paul:
>Paul writes:
>>Rob raises an interesting question.  If, due to subcontracting 
>>labour, wage labour becomes a minority of workers in developed
>>"capitalist" countries, does that mean they are no longer 
>>capitalist?  (Which is the implication of accepting Jim's position 
>>on slavery.)
>
>Actually, it's my "position" on capitalism, not on slavery. Frankly, 
>I don't think capitalism is possible without wage labor. I think 
>that most "subcontracting labor" is just wage labor in disguise. 
>(There are also subcontractors who are petty or even large 
>bourgeois.) Of course, this is an empirical question, one that I 
>don't have the energy to even try to answer this morning.

What is happening in our post-Socialist & post-Social-Democratic 
epoch is that early transitional forms of emerging capitalist 
relations have returned.

*****   positions: east asia cultures critique 7.2 (1999) 307-342

Bathing in the Far Village: Globalization, Transnational Capital, and 
the Cultural Politics of Modernity in China*

Tim Oakes

Bathing in the Far Village

In the summer of 1996 I was browsing through a chic clothing boutique 
in downtown Seattle when I came across a batik bathrobe prominently 
displayed alongside several elegant dresses (fig. 1).  It caught my 
attention because it was of a particular style of batik that I 
recognized.  The sight of it--displayed among the silk, linen, and 
rayon gowns from around the world--stopped me in my tracks, for two 
years earlier I had seen this type of batik being produced in the 
rural households and town workshops of Guizhou, China. Knowing what 
peasant women earned in the laborious and highly skilled work of 
applying wax for batik dying, my first impulse was, of course, to 
check the price tag. The bathrobe was going for a cool $150.  By my 
calculation, the Guizhou household that contributed the majority of 
the labor needed to produce the bathrobe earned roughly 2.5 percent 
of the retail sale price.

The labor of women villagers in Guizhou was being sold in Seattle 
under the label of Far Village, a small company established in 1993 
by a Los Angeles designer. As the bathrobe's tag--on rough 
handcrafted paper--sought to make clear, the purpose of Far Village 
was to promote and protect the art and craft skills of "ancient 
cultures" such as Guizhou's Miao people.  More than this, Far Village 
claimed that it promoted the empowerment of Miao peasant women, the 
actual producers of its clothing. As the tag made explicit, the 
consumer was purchasing much more than just a bathrobe; indeed, the 
item itself was almost secondary to the concept being sold: the 
possibility of organic cultural continuity in the modern world 
and--as an added bonus--the modern emancipation of village women as 
well.  The Far Village project promoted a multicultural politics of 
consumption that has become a hallmark of advanced capitalism in the 
neoliberal West, a "politics" constituted less by the production of 
difference than by its circulation according to the needs of flexible 
accumulation and postmodern cultural relativism.  Within this 
politics of consumption, a blissful collage of abstracted and 
consumable identities substitutes for the real social differences 
that have historically emerged within and been so disruptive to 
capital. 1

One way of interpreting the displacement of cultural politics from 
the realm of production to that of consumption is to see it as part 
of the global penetration of the commodity form--the colonization and 
exploitation by transnational capital of the remaining modes of 
production that have previously functioned beyond its reach. 
Capital, according to this view, roams the world in search of 
cultural otherness that is ripe for commodification, while 
consumer-tourists, transfixed by the ideologies of multiculturalism, 
quickly follow to "appreciate" and "preserve" the wreckage that 
remains.  Indeed, an apparent condition of advanced or "disorganized" 
capitalism is a pattern of everyday consumption that renders us more 
and more like tourists as we purchase not products but 
representations and experiences. 2  Thus, in Seattle, one can be an 
ethnic tourist by purchasing a batik bathrobe; one can bathe in the 
far village without ever leaving the bathroom--and believe that the 
village is better off for it. At any rate, that is the marketing 
pitch that Far Village, as a capitalist venture, relies upon. 3

At first glance, then, the Far Village project reflects the familiar 
story of transnational capitalism, with its pervasive extension of 
the commodity form into the final frontiers of premodern "tradition" 
and the metropolitan fetishizing of those commodities into the 
misplaced metaphors of preindustrial cultural preservation and 
justice for Fourth World women. 4  But the ethnographic details 
underlying the Far Village project compel us to challenge the 
assumption that globalization is a straightforward process of capital 
commodifying everything in its path and enlisting cultural 
differences into its repertoire of surplus-value extraction.  The 
social relations of production that underlie the Far Village project 
are profoundly conditioned by multiple ethnic, cultural, and gender 
differences within China, differences that divert and complicate the 
politics of consumption going on in the Seattle boutique, as well as 
the material processes of commodification underway in Guizhou.  While 
the surplus labor of Miao village women is being appropriated by 
capital (a fact obscured by the myths of preserving ancient culture 
and empowering women), their encounter with transnational capital is 
further complicated by an ongoing cultural politics of modernity 
within China, which, in its latest guise, could be described as the 
challenge of an increasingly vigorous capitalist marketplace to the 
socialist state's role as the dominant narrator of China's "identity" 
as a modern nation-state and culturally coherent society. 5  Ethnic 
groups in China, such as the Miao, find themselves at the unstable 
intersection of state and capitalist discourses as they compete for 
the loudest voice in narrating ideal models for the modern 
imaginations of the Chinese people.  Their participation in a 
globalized production and marketing project such as Far Village 
enlists Miao villagers in a struggle not only over the exploitation 
of surplus labor value but also over the unfinished project of modern 
China.  It is this struggle over Chinese modernity, and the role of 
ethnic groups in this struggle, that divert and distort the politics 
of consumption expressed in the purchase of a batik bathrobe.  While 
globalization clearly links producers and consumers across vast 
spatial divides, intensifying the exploitative reach of capital to an 
unprecedented scale, this essay seeks to argue that those linkages 
are profoundly conditioned and altered by processes that occur on 
more local and regional scales.  Here, globalization is viewed 
through the lens of the local to bring into sharper focus the dynamic 
interaction between placed cultural practice and displaced capital. 
6...

...Examining ethnic politics in China according to the 
political-economic context of the relationship between rural ethnic 
producers and international capital--as mediated by the Chinese state 
and the tourism industry-- also offers a materialist contribution to 
the growing literature on Chinese ethnic cultural studies. 10  In 
this essay, minority subjectivity is also considered, but within a 
field of power relations dominated by capital and state policies that 
have less to do with ethnicity per se than with liberal market 
reforms.  While I offer no definitive conclusions regarding the 
agency of minority subjects, I hope to provide a framework for 
analyzing ethnic cultural politics in China that pays explicit 
attention to the growing role of mobile capital and market 
development in conditioning minority subjectivities.

The Sway of Capital

Gathering the analytical threads spun thus far, three critical points 
may now be made regarding the political-economic context of ethnic 
crafts production in China.  First, the Far Village project 
represents less the preservation of a noncapitalist production 
environment and culture than an intensification and an extension of 
an existing form of state capitalism in China toward more global 
channels of accumulation.  Second, the functional division of labor 
inherent in Guizhou's commercial rural crafts production is marked by 
gender and ethnicity.  The Guizhou crafts industry is segmented into 
Han versus non-Han ethnicity, and the question of who eventually 
controls the production of ethnic products is also a question of 
ethnic politics. 11  In addition, minority subjectivity in China is 
largely a feminized subjectivity; crafts production itself is thus 
further segmented by the marking of specific tasks as "women's work." 
Ethnicity and gender thus play complementary roles in the configuring 
of minority subjectivity in China, and these roles are reflected in 
the production relations that dominate the crafts industry.  Third, 
the cultural politics of crafts production in Guizhou provides an 
arena in which the divergent interests of the state and capital 
become apparent as they compete for dominance over the ethnicity- and 
gender-charged narratives of Chinese modernity. The consumer of Far 
Village products enters unaware into this arena of the cultural 
politics of Chinese modernity.

The Far Village project seeks to promote an alternative model to the 
industrial capitalist modernity of the West.  Yet, paradoxically, it 
seeks to achieve this via conventional market mechanisms that are 
subject to uneven patterns of capital accumulation.  The Los Angeles 
designer who, in 1993, proposed the project to leaders in Guizhou's 
crafts and tourism industries sought explicitly to "avoid demanding 
so much work that it disrupts village life and becomes an unpleasant 
chore."  Her proposal further indicated that "rather than just 
selling a product we want to sell the concept of Far Village; that 
the world needs to protect and help these ancient cultures to 
survive; that things made by hand are valuable and should be honored; 
and that the marketplace will respond to such a selling technique." 
12  Her vision for the project was that of a nonexploitative market 
link between metropolitan consumers and "ancient cultures"--the 
latter with their traditional, noncapitalist modes of production 
(modes presumably not characterized by the exploitative extraction of 
surplus labor value).  This vision therefore relied upon an assumed 
image of "village life" that was somehow free of the "unpleasant 
chores" of formalized wage labor or production for the market; a "far 
village" that did not live, in other words, under the sway of capital.

Contrary to this marketable myth of consumer contact with (and 
preservation of) the premodern, the Miao villagers who produce goods 
for Far Village enter into production relations that are closely 
integrated with the Chinese state's capitalist development 
strategies.  They live, in fact, well under the sway of capital, and 
it is precisely for this reason that they produce their crafts for 
Seattle consumers.  It is their integration within capitalist 
relations of production, rather than survival beyond them, that leads 
to the labor of Miao women being fetishized as an ideal type of 
"natural economy," which is characterized by the so-called 
subsistence mode of production.  Usually equated with preindustrial 
and precapitalist rural production relations, the naturalness of the 
peasant economy is often assumed in popular, official, and even some 
scholarly characterizations of "backward" (luohou) regions of China's 
countryside (such as Guizhou). 13  There is much dismay among Chinese 
officials and scholars, for example, over the "small-farmer 
mentality" (xiaonong sixiang) of Guizhou's rural producers, their 
resistance to marketization, and their refusal to embrace the ideal 
of comparative advantage in China's new "market socialism." 
According to this view, subsistence producers persist in their ways 
of self-sufficiency and ad hoc participation in local markets.  More 
important, however, is the charge that such peasants are not 
sufficiently entrepreneurial and therefore fail to create conditions 
in which capital can accumulate.  In other words, production 
relations of subsistence are not oriented toward profit, that is, 
toward extracting surplus labor value.

For a Chinese state seeking to enlist market forces in its 
modernization agenda, such peasant stubbornness is a problem.  For 
the Far Village project, it is the fragile artifact of a way of life 
long lost in the industrialized West. Both the Chinese state and 
transnational capital, in other words, construct a mythical image of 
the Miao other--but for opposite purposes.  The state's agenda is one 
of developmentalism, in which the Miao other represents a version of 
a subsistence-oriented agrarian tradition that the state sees China 
progressing beyond as it engages with the world economy. 14  Far 
Village's agenda is obviously quite different. Echoing the ideals of 
what in the Mexican context Scott Cook and Leigh Binford have termed 
"ethnicized neopopulism," Far Village "combines the celebration of 
indigenous ethnic pluralism . . . with a genuinely romantic loathing 
of capitalism." 15  The production of labor-intensive crafts such as 
ornate batik and embroidery is only possible, it is felt, in a 
noncommercial, subsistence-oriented environment. Hence the project's 
goal of not interrupting village life or making crafts production an 
"unpleasant chore."  But changing the subsistence environment of the 
village would also destroy the uniqueness (and therefore 
marketability) of the products.  Thus, the idea is to preserve a 
communitarian, household-based production environment that is 
dominated by kinship relations--an environment where the production 
process is presumably not regulated by a disciplined regimen of time. 
Through their conscription into the front lines of subcontracting 
capitalism (as it reaches into the most remote regions of China's 
interior), Miao villagers find themselves occupying a space in which 
the contradictory discourses of modernity narrated by the Chinese 
state and by capitalist elites compete for dominance.

In fact, the Chinese state has long played a significant role in 
shaping the social relations of production in which Miao villagers 
participate.  Historically, the Miao of Guizhou have been subject to 
the volatile economic permutations that are characteristic of a 
Chinese "internal colony." 16  With the development of collective 
agriculture under Mao, Guizhou peasants were fundamentally 
integrated, as never before, into the broader political economy of 
state resource extraction. 17  Through the socialist state's 
appropriation of agricultural production, and through its many 
ideological campaigns aimed at instilling a modern revolutionary 
consciousness throughout China, village economies were fundamentally 
disrupted and linked to relations of production that were distinctly 
modern and statist and which profoundly destabilized local social 
relations in the countryside.  State procurement of surplus grain 
directly implicated Chinese peasants in an industrial modernization 
strategy that depended heavily on the exploitation of agriculture. 
Land reform and collectivization destroyed any lingering possibility 
that Guizhou's villagers could be viewed as isolated holdouts, where 
ancient production relations governed by the customs of tradition and 
kinship might escape the modernizing influences of the modern 
nation-state.  Ironically, it is not until the post-Mao era that we 
begin to see the specter of subsistence raised by the reform-oriented 
state's efforts to introduce a new round of modernization to the 
rural Chinese economy.

Rural reforms in post-Mao China have brought an important shift in 
which a state-market hybrid has largely replaced the state in its 
role of dominating local production relations.  Agricultural 
production is increasingly driven by commercial concerns, and rural 
industrialization has brought significant new sources of wealth and 
inequality to the countryside. 18  Initially, during the early 1980s, 
rural reforms that unintentionally led to the dismantling of 
collectives and the establishment of household contracting brought 
about an unprecedented increase in grain production and, with the 20 
percent rise in state grain-procurement prices, a rapid rise in rural 
incomes and household savings. 19  In the latter half of the 1980s, 
however, the state sought to reward farmers for diversifying their 
activities and making market-based decisions about what and how much 
to produce.  At the same time, fiscal decentralization encouraged 
local governments to actively seek out new sources of revenue; for 
rural areas, this meant local state support for rural 
industrialization and commercial agricultural production.  With the 
central state divesting itself of the rural economy, and with 
collective resources largely dismantled, demand for capital 
investments in new industrial and commercial ventures intensified. 20 
Rural industries and commercialized agriculture have become two 
important means to achieving fiscal autonomy for many prosperous 
rural areas along the coast and near large cities.  Thus, rural 
production in these areas witnessed a profound shift--from a focus on 
intensifying traditional inputs (such as labor) to increased 
capitalization, efficiency, and profitability. By 1992, when Deng 
Xiaoping made his famous southern tour, which initiated a commercial 
boom throughout the country, a "commercial countryside" was being 
explicitly advocated as the primary goal of rural development. 
Household crafts production is currently being promoted throughout 
China--especially in regions where larger-scale rural industries 
remain undeveloped--as a complement to, rather than a departure from, 
this trend. 21

For Guizhou's villagers, post-Mao reforms have meant important new 
incentives to produce for the market, as well as new opportunities to 
seek out off-farm sources of wage income.  Yet developments since 
1985 have made it increasingly difficult to earn a living from 
farming in a region where cultivation is dominated by staple grains. 
Although procurement quotas have been dropped and grain prices 
continue to rise, increasing production costs have made grain farming 
a losing venture in all but the most prosperous and industrialized 
regions. 22  While commercial crops now receive the greatest priority 
among farmers throughout China, weak agricultural markets, poor land, 
and high population pressure make cash crops an unrealistic option 
for most Guizhou farmers. 23  Even traditional specialties, such as 
cotton or tobacco, or sidelines, such as pork or poultry, generate 
slim profits that leave farmers vulnerable to an increasingly 
volatile market environment. 24  Across China, access to nonfarm wage 
income has therefore become the key to improving the living standards 
of rural households. 25  In regions where rural industries meet 
household demands for wage labor, rural incomes have seen dramatic 
increases.  But in more remote regions, such as Guizhou, where 
industrial manufacturing is not feasible, household-based commercial 
crafts production is seen as one of the few opportunities to improve 
rural incomes and one of the few options for generating a more 
capitalized, profit-oriented rural sector. 26

Intensified crafts production emerges, then, not as the peasant 
household's stubborn clinging to a traditional subsistence economy in 
the face of modern change--as Far Village might lead us to 
believe--but rather as its active response to an increasingly 
commercialized and capitalized countryside, where structural 
transformations in the economy require peasant families to bring in 
more cash income.  In the Chinese countryside, crafts production has 
historically thrived in commercially developed regions not because of 
the persistence of a "peasant mentality" but because of the chronic 
need for cash faced by peasants in an increasingly market-based 
economy. 27

This speaks to a broader debate over the articulation of capitalist 
with noncapitalist modes of production.  The Far Village project's 
marketability depends, in part, on selling to the consumer the idea 
that noncapitalist modes of production can remain wholly 
"beyond"--yet at the same time profitably linked to--capitalism.  In 
fact, petty-commodity production has been characterized as a peasant 
strategy of capital accumulation rather than a strategy of 
traditionalist survivalism on the part of "ancient cultures." 
Indeed, it is often because of their intense desire for modernity 
that peasants in Guizhou enter into household crafts production. 
Petty-commodity production has been conceptualized by Cook and 
Binford according to the following four elements: (1) production for 
market exchange; (2) nonwaged labor and private (household) control 
of the means of production; (3) relative independence and autonomy of 
the production unit; and (4) production for subsistence "but never to 
the exclusion of capital accumulation or profit." 28  These four 
elements have in common the peculiar way in which labor is joined to 
capital.  Instead of extracting profit through the control of waged 
labor, capital accumulation for petty-commodity enterprises "occurs 
through the extraction of surplus value from nonwaged labor."  Cook 
and Binford call this process "endofamilial accumulation"; it is 
through such an accumulation strategy that peasant households may 
realize actual profits from their "self-exploitation," profits that 
may exceed the simple reproduction of subsistence. 29  Importantly, 
this approach to conceptualizing petty-commodity production focuses 
our attention on the conditions that either enable or prevent peasant 
households from achieving actual capital accumulation rather than on 
their assumed disinclination to pursue increased profits and 
efficiency in their household enterprises.  This can help us to move 
beyond the assumptions underlying the Far Village project and to 
examine more closely the production relations inherent in Guizhou's 
village crafts industry.

In Guizhou, commercial crafts production is largely driven by 
widespread rural poverty, which provides the incentive for women in 
Miao households to become self-exploitative specialists. 30  As the 
following section will reveal, definite patterns of class 
stratification have occurred within crafts-producing regions 
according to the commodity chains that have developed between 
producers, middlemen, value-adding workshops, and traders who deal 
with companies such as Far Village.  But the functional division of 
labor that adheres, and the articulations of meaning that emerge 
within the industry, do not necessarily reflect class relations of 
production per se but rather extant social differences based on 
ethnicity and gender.  Thus, while crafts production in Guizhou falls 
firmly within the "sway of capital," the resulting patterns of uneven 
accumulation and social differentiation do not necessarily arise from 
the commodity form itself but from deeply imbedded patterns of 
ethnic, cultural and gender differences that mediate and divert the 
further encroachments of transnational capitalism toward a regionally 
specific struggle over Chinese modernity.

The Cultural Politics of Modernity in Guizhou's Touristic Development

...Ethnic craft commodity production in Guizhou has developed within 
a macroeconomic environment characterized by state fiscal 
decentralization and decline.  During the Reform Era, the 
redistributive effectiveness of the central government has lessened 
considerably. 31  Since 1980, a trend toward local self-financing has 
also generated growing regional economic disparities. 32  The central 
government's share of the budget has dropped from roughly 47 percent 
in 1984 to 29 percent in 1995.  By 1995, government revenues had 
declined to 10.7 percent of the GNP. 33  Fiscal power has 
increasingly been concentrated in wealthy regions, while poor 
provinces such as Guizhou are faced with greater fiscal 
responsibilities, inadequate revenues, and growing deficits.  In 
1995, for example, Guizhou's provincial revenues had amounted to just 
45 percent of expenditures. 34 Between 1988 and 1994, the province 
had received annual fixed-quota subsidies of RMB 740 million, which 
represented an increasingly smaller proportion of the expanding 
provincial budget. 35  In the early 1980s, central subsidies had 
financed nearly 60 percent of Guizhou's total budget.  By 1993, this 
figure was down to less than 20 percent.  Correspondingly, in 1995, 
70 percent of total fixed-capital investments were financed by the 
province, a significant increase over the 1992 figure of 48 percent. 
36  One result was that by the 1990s, unable to transfer its 
diminishing subsidies to the counties, the provincial government was 
instead extracting a surplus from them to finance its outlays.  Local 
leaders, inventing new fees and surcharges to cover their remittance 
quotas, correspondingly increased the financial pressure on rural 
households.  One report concludes that "in Guizhou, since 1988, the 
entire rural sector has acquired net remitter status, so that the 
rural sector may be supporting the urban sector." 37  Overall, poor 
rural counties have seen very little growth in expenditures, while 
even relatively wealthy counties are strapped with heavy 
revenue-sharing burdens that dampen whatever comparative advantages 
they have had.  In addition, a new tax-sharing arrangement introduced 
by the Ministry of Finance in 1994 has made it more difficult for 
Guizhou counties specializing in liquor and tobacco production to 
retain revenues associated with the tax on these "luxury goods."

Faced with the inadequacy of central development funds designed to 
compensate for the adverse effects of fiscal decentralization on the 
minority and impoverished counties of China's interior, Guizhou has 
increasingly advocated the commercialization of the rural sector as 
the means by which the rural poor may escape poverty.  In other 
words, the province's answer to its simmering fiscal crisis is to 
"sell Guizhou." 38  This strategy amounts to addressing the 
province's chronic shortage of capital by attracting external 
investment for commercial development schemes.  While central-state 
investments in Guizhou's mining and energy sectors remain significant 
(Guizhou is a key provider under the Comprehensive National 
Development Plan, which emphasizes mineral and energy development), 
the province is increasingly left on its own to both revive a 
derelict ordnance-manufacturing industry and establish an integrated 
rural market economy.  39 Guizhou's efforts to attract external 
capital have focused on retooling its ordnance industries for 
consumer-goods production; expanding its traditional specializations 
in liquor, tobacco, herbal medicines, and ethnic crafts; and 
intensifying commercial timber and livestock production. 40  The most 
significant avenue for attracting investment, however, is the tourism 
industry.  Touristic marketing of Guizhou as an attractive and exotic 
place has dominated the province's commercial development strategy, 
and in this regard, the region's significant population of ethnic 
minorities has played a crucial role.

Indeed, tourism has been slated to become one of the province's 
"pillar industries," with plans calling for tourism revenues to 
contribute as much as 20 percent to Guizhou's income by 2010, up from 
about 5 percent in 1993. 41  However, in contrast to the province's 
other recognized "pillars"--coal mining, hydroelectricity, mineral 
processing, the defense industry, and agriculture--tourism is 
promoted with two specific goals in mind: First, as a vanguard 
industry, it is expected to open the way for other processes, 
particularly external investment and the commercial integration of 
the rural economy with external markets.  This idea is championed by 
the phrase lüyou tatai, jingmao changxi (economic trade performing on 
a stage built by tourism), which is found in nearly all local media 
coverage of commercial development projects. Second, tourism is also 
expected to serve as a primary means by which the countryside might 
cast off its "traditional thinking" and adopt a "commercial 
conscience," thereby helping the province to lay a foundation for 
fiscal solvency. 42

Reflecting this dual role of tourism development, ethnic minority 
culture has become a fundamental feature of Guizhou's promotional 
activities, both in terms of using exotic cultural representations as 
enticements for potential investors and as a component of market 
socialism's potential for rural development in minority regions. 
Ethnic minority groups make up roughly one-third of Guizhou's 
population.  Most public events, such as trade fairs and holiday 
celebrations, are marked with the ubiquitous ethnic symbols of music, 
dancing, staged rituals, and crafts.  Standardized versions of Miao 
and Dong lusheng (reed pipe) dances, roadblock wine (lanlujiu) 
ceremonies, and related performances have likewise become regular 
features of tourist itineraries catering to official and business 
travelers.  Indeed, a major conference center at Hongfeng Reservoir 
on the outskirts of the provincial capital was built to resemble a 
series of minority villages--Dong, Miao, Yi, and Bouyei--where guests 
may experience exotic ethnic receptions mixed in with their more 
familiar karaoke singing contests.  The touristic staging of such 
ethnic performances and ceremonies is meant not only to make Guizhou 
more interesting to outsiders but to establish a model for the 
"cultural development" of minority groups themselves and to condition 
them to articulate symbolic cultural practices with commercial 
projects.  Indeed, it is tourism's explicit marketing of ethnic 
culture that most clearly illustrates its importance both as a 
propaganda and marketing tool for Guizhou and, more importantly, as a 
process of development and integration that encourages minority 
regions to become more modern.  It is in the field of ethnic-crafts 
development that this dual role of tourism is most clearly at work.

The state narrates this modernizing role of tourism in several ways. 
Examples abound of isolated villagers who are encouraged by the 
guiding hand of the state to cast off their backwardness and jump 
into the sea of commerce.  One popular story relates how the 
prefectural governor of southeast Guizhou, a Miao named Wu Dehai, 
helped villagers to abandon ancient superstitions and create a 
healthier scientific and modern culture through tourism:

In Qingman Village, custom dictated that the lusheng couldn't be 
played, nor could drums be beaten, between spring planting and autumn 
harvest. To violate this custom, it was said, was to risk some great 
natural calamity.  Wu Dehai himself is a Miao and wanted to respect 
the customs of his own people.  But he also wanted to adapt to the 
new environment of reform and openness.  So he went to the Miao 
village, found the village elders and cadres, spoke to them in 
rational and scientific terms, opened their thinking, and reached an 
agreement to establish an ethnic tourist site.  After this, when 
tourists came, the villagers performed, playing the lusheng at any 
time of the year.  Thus, the locals received an enlightening 
education and increased their enthusiasm for tourism. 43

Another story tells of a Miao woman who, having visited Beijing in 
her ethnic costume, was pursued by an entrepreneurial Han to return 
to Guizhou and begin selling Miao textiles to Beijing tourist shops. 
This was another departure from the "law of tradition."  A chapter 
about her in a book titled Zhongguo qiye yinghao [Heroes of Chinese 
enterprise] stresses that she was coaxed out of her "premodern" 
thinking to blossom as a successful entrepreneur and culturally 
developed citizen of "new China."  She is credited with having 
"brought the Miao out of the mountains and into the world of 
commerce.  From the point of a needle, they have filled the earth 
with embroidery and leaped to earning over 800,000 yuan." 44

As a number of scholars have suggested, the narrative of modern China 
has emerged, in part, from an ongoing discourse of non-Han otherness. 
45  Throughout the twentieth century, peripheral minority groups have 
served as both a symbolic source of authentic primitive vitality, 
which has reinforced China's indigenous roots as a society capable of 
modernizing while remaining distinct from the West, and a marker for 
gauging the "normalcy" and progress of the dominant Han population. 
This symbolic role intensified during the 1980s "roots" (xungen) 
fever.  As Louisa Schein puts it, "The suppressions of the Cultural 
Revolution . . . combined with the perceived emptiness of imported 
culture from abroad, seem to have left a void at the core of Chinese 
ethno-nationalism, leading individual and state culture producers to 
turn to minority cultures as reservoirs of still-extant 
authenticity." 46  This authenticity was inscribed with a subject 
position that was both non-Han and feminine--at once primitive, 
exotic, sensual, and enticing. Post-Mao narratives of Chinese 
modernity are thus conditioned, in part, by what Schein calls 
"internal orientalism."...

The Crafts Industry and the Far Village Project

As practiced in Guizhou, the cultural politics of Chinese modernity 
evinces two diverging hegemonies.  Minority groups are the first 
targets of a state-narrated modern subjectivity that draws on an 
established history of China's "civilizing mission" toward non-Han 
peripheral peoples. 47  In Guizhou, touristic crafts production is 
thus meant to instill a "commercial consciousness" that will help 
minority farmers progress beyond their "small-farmer mentality." 
Along with tourism, commercial crafts production encourages minority 
groups to move "toward the world" (zouxiang shijie). 48  Capital, 
too, seeks this kind of alignment between local production practices 
and the global marketplace.  The difference is that the subjectivity 
narrated by capital is one in which minority groups are invested with 
a premodern and preindustrial authenticity, which serves as both a 
marketable image and a romantic ideology that addresses metropolitan 
anxiety over global capitalist development.  In these terms, then, 
Guizhou's modernization depends upon the very primitiveness that the 
socialist state seeks to overcome.  In the case of the Far Village 
project, we see being narrated precisely this paradoxical version of 
modernity, as well as the capitalist relations of production that 
underlie it.

The contradictions of Guizhou's touristic commercial development are 
visible not just in the Far Village project but throughout the 
province's commodity craft industry.  Tourism, it is well known, is a 
significant catalyst to commercial crafts production throughout the 
world. 49  In Guizhou, it has helped spawn what may be roughly 
categorized as three broad types of crafts development: first, 
relatively large-scale, factory-based crafts production; second, 
household-based traders, or "middlemen" (locally called erdao fanzi), 
who travel the countryside buying old and new crafts from poor 
households and selling them directly to tourists or to metropolitan 
wholesale buyers from places such as Hong Kong, Guangzhou, and 
Taibei; and third, putting-out systems that link town- and city-based 
marketing and value-added industries directly to poor, rural 
household producers. 50

Each of these types is characterized by distinct ethnic, gender, and 
spatial divisions of labor.  The management of larger-scale factories 
is composed almost exclusively of urban Han men, while the workers 
are all non-Han female migrants from nearby rural villages.  Rural 
household-based traders are exclusively non-Han women, while their 
buyers are either foreign or urban Han.  Rural household producers 
participating in putting-out systems are also exclusively non-Han 
women, while their "foremen" (longtou) are often (but not always) 
men, and may be Han or non-Han.  These divisions reflect the nature 
of cultural discourse that emerges within the local crafts industry, 
a discourse that articulates these social divisions with the broader 
narratives of modernity emanating from state and capitalist agents.

Household crafts production in the Miao villages where Far Village 
work is contracted is strictly regarded as women's work.  With the 
intensification of neoliberal reforms in 1992, the growing difficulty 
of earning a livelihood from agricultural income alone has meant that 
women's work is increasingly called upon in poor households to help 
fill the budget gap. 51  Many unmarried women help fill the gap by 
seeking employment in larger crafts factories in nearby towns and 
cities, while other women--unmarried and married alike--remain in 
their villages doing putting-out contract work in their homes.  While 
many of these women have welcomed the opportunity to earn a living by 
selling their crafts skills, they regard contract work as a very 
unattractive option chosen only as a last resort.  They are well 
aware of the exploitative nature of the putting-out system.  Thus, it 
is only the very poorest households that are compelled to participate 
in crafts contract work.  Fewer and fewer younger women, furthermore, 
take the time to learn embroidery and batik skills, which many regard 
as "old-fashioned," preferring to wear "modern" clothes at special 
occasions.  Such attitudes only reinforce the image of impoverishment 
and destitution that accompanies this work.  Nevertheless, they are 
encouraged to participate by local officials, entrepreneurs, and even 
tourists, who regard their work as a form of cultural preservation 
that keeps the old handicraft traditions from dying out.

Leaving home to work in crafts factories is one of the few 
opportunities young women have to earn a cash income and live in 
town--to be on their own, away from the village.  In the Miao and 
Dong autonomous prefecture of Qiandongnan, coastal trading firms 
established a number of labor-intensive crafts factories in the early 
1990s, thanks in part to local tax policies designed to attract 
investors.  These policies began in 1994 when the prefecture was 
designated a state-level "experimental development zone" by the State 
Nationalities Affairs Commission (Guojia Minwei). 52

In Taijiang County, within Qiandongnan, such policies netted several 
new, externally funded crafts-producing enterprises in 1994.  These 
were essentially sanlai yibu (literally, three "importeds" and one 
"compensatory") enterprises, in which the local nationalities affairs 
commission provided a building and recruited female labor from 
surrounding villages while a number of coastal trading companies 
provided the capital, raw materials, and market connections.  One of 
these factories, set up by a Jiangsu company to produce tie-dyed silk 
cloth for export to Japan, employed about one hundred village women 
who sat all day tying up thousands of tiny dot patterns on silk (fig. 
2).  They were paid RMB 6 for every ten thousand ties, and although 
the manager said they could typically produce five thousand ties per 
day, workers on the shop floor told me that the most anyone earned 
was between RMB 30 and 40 per month. 53  Another Taijiang factory 
employed a similar number of rural women who earned similar wages 
making embroidered cloth for export to Southeast Asia.  I visited 
other such factories of this size throughout Qiandongnan Prefecture, 
where in all cases, women lived in factory-provided dormitories but 
were responsible for their own food; the workers' wages seldom 
exceeded RMB 50 per month.  Moreover, the special policies developed 
to attract this economic activity to Qiandongnan meant that Taijiang 
County was collecting few tax revenues from these factories.

When asked in 1994, an officer at the Taijiang Nationalities Affairs 
Commission (Taijiang Minwei) justified these exploitative ventures by 
stressing that they only represented a first step in modernization. 
He likened them to a window through which other coastal companies 
could see the county's investment potential.  He also noted that 
Taijiang's rural households still had few opportunities to earn cash 
and that these factories would help generate a "commercial 
consciousness" in the countryside; he believed that turning Guizhou's 
countryside into a source of cheap labor for coastal companies 
dabbling in international trade would not adversely affect future 
development prospects.  But by 1996, the county's attitude had 
changed considerably: it refused to renew any leases for the 
coastal-run factories, citing insufficient pay and poor working 
conditions.  For Taijiang County, the previous goal of attracting 
external investment at any cost had clearly backfired. "We lost money 
and the workers were treated badly," the Minwei officer admitted. 
Furthermore, the county no longer had any funds available for 
promoting commercial crafts production.  The county Minwei's annual 
appropriation of RMB 10,000 had been cut, and remaining development 
grants were being swallowed up by day-to-day administrative 
expenditures and salaries. 54  Thus, by 1996, the local government's 
role in promoting rural "commercial consciousness" had diminished 
considerably.

The development of larger-scale factories thus reflects the efforts 
of the local state to attract external investment regardless of the 
high opportunity costs involved.  In Taijiang, further, the 
exploitative tendencies of uneven capital accumulation contradicted 
the state's goals in the broader field of sociocultural development. 
While the local government managed to drive the most egregious 
exploiters out of the county, fiscal restraints have also forced it 
to retreat from full participation in the commercial crafts arena, 
leaving future development solely to the private urban entrepreneurs 
who are the basis of the putting-out system.  In these developments, 
we see a different version of modernity being narrated through 
commercial integration.  While the state seeks to promote 
sociocultural development and socialist modernization (in which 
Guizhou's rural poor are encouraged to progress beyond their insular 
traditions and local customs), independent capitalists seek to 
exploit precisely that image of primitive backwardness as a marketing 
strategy in selling ethnic craft products.

Larger-scale factories benefited from the cheap yet highly skilled 
labor of unmarried Miao women, but they tended not to emphasize the 
exotic ethnicity of their products.  Setting up operations in places 
such as Taijiang was instead done to take advantage of a distinctive 
labor market of skilled young women.  In contrast, the many 
enterprises engaged in the putting out of crafts production in the 
region specialized in products that were explicitly marked by their 
ethnic exoticism.  The largest and most established of these 
enterprises in southeast Guizhou, where the bulk of the province's 
ethnic crafts are produced, was Taijiang's Miao Embroidery Factory 
(Miaozu Cixiu Gongyipin Chang).  This was basically a finishing 
workshop where Miao textiles, produced by village women under 
contract, were incorporated into numerous products, including 
wallets, shoulder bags, and clothing (fig. 3).  These products were 
generally not used by locals themselves but were the result of advice 
given by tourists and textile specialists who passed through the 
region suggesting ways that local crafts might be made more 
marketable.  But because of their apparent role in contributing to 
the preservation of the ethnic textile heritage, enterprises such as 
the Miao Embroidery Factory were also regarded by the state as 
institutions of cultural development.  Indeed, the Taijiang 
government's retreat from the arena of commercial crafts development 
had resulted in its support of the factory as a means of achieving 
local development goals.  The county bureaucracy facilitated the 
factory's obtaining a large grant from UNICEF and promoted it among 
prefectural and provincial tourist agencies.  Tour groups were 
regularly brought to the factory store, and this often resulted in 
the establishment of market links in Hong Kong, Taiwan, and 
throughout East and Southeast Asia.

Such close relations between local governments and rural industries 
are, of course, common throughout China.  Nor is the Miao Embroidery 
Factory's situation unique among crafts enterprises in Guizhou, where 
these enterprises typically have maintained close ties to local 
governments and the state tourism industry.  Significantly, it was 
these ties that helped spawn the development of the Far Village 
project, in which an American clothing designer proposed to turn 
authentic ethnic textiles into fashionable clothing for high-end 
markets in Japan and the United States.  From its very inception, the 
project was linked to an established putting-out system of commercial 
crafts production that was already articulated with the modernizing 
state in many ways.  The project thus inherited an extant set of 
relations, both between these enterprises and the state and between 
the enterprise and its contracted household producers.  There was 
almost no direct link between the project and actual producers; 
instead, the stated goals of the project could only be realized via 
the putting-out system upon which much crafts production relied.  As 
it turned out, this system proved to be a poor transmitter of Far 
Village's stated goals.

The significance of the putting-out system (which supported crafts 
workshops like the Miao Embroidery Factory) is that it represented 
not simply an unequal economic relationship with producing households 
but unequal ethnic and gender relations as well; the inherent power 
dynamic expressed in the system's economic relationships is thus also 
reflected in these other dimensions.  Production contracts generally 
entailed the provision by the workshop (and/or its agent or longtou) 
of all materials and designs, with the household being responsible 
solely for labor.  In 1994, the application of wax for batik earned 
village women in Taijiang an average of RMB 7 for twelve hours of 
labor; in 1998 women earned RMB 20 for embroidery pieces that took 
roughly one month to make.  Household producers clearly understood 
the difficulty of accumulating any real capital under such 
conditions.  But the system was attractive to desperate locals 
because households didn't have to put up any capital to participate 
and all materials were provided.  These households were also 
typically those without sufficient labor power to send a family 
member to a nearby city or to the coast to earn cash.

More important than the extraction of surplus labor value inherent in 
such an arrangement was the way it guaranteed that control over 
production remained in the hands of urban workshop managers, who not 
only dictated piece rates but provided the "authentic" designs and 
patterns that ensured the standardization of their products. 55  This 
power to dictate textile patterns was also wielded across ethnic and 
gender lines, with most urban managers being Han men and all 
household producers being non-Han women.  Thus, the very definitions 
of authenticity and tradition constituted a field of ethnic and 
gender politics in which a feminized non-Han minority tradition 
continued to be constructed, in part, by a more powerful, 
masculinized class of urban Han.  Whereas wealthier households could 
afford to purchase new, more "modern" designs for their own use, poor 
women working under contract merely produced the "authentic" designs 
provided by their foremen.  Urban entrepreneurs were thus encouraged 
to seek out the poorest villages.  Villages that urban workshops had 
exclusively dealt with during the 1980s were, by the early 1990s, 
being passed over for more remote and poorer places on the grounds 
that, as one factory manager put it, the early sites had "become more 
and more influenced by Han culture, and so the patterns aren't as 
authentic."  Another problem cited by this manager was that the 
increasing commercialization of textile production in these villages, 
which were no longer self-enclosed economies, had influenced local 
embroidery styles.  His solution to this "contradiction" (maodun) was 
to maintain a cultural bank of authentic traditional styles, frozen 
in time, that would form the basis of sustained future production. 
"If peasants want a job," he said, "they'll have to produce 
embroidery according to the styles we require, and these will be the 
authentic ones." 56 For many ethnic producers, the result was not 
simply increased subjugation to capital but an associated surrender 
to their Han employers of the determination of what was authentic.

It is into this contradictory environment of China's cultural 
politics of modernity that the Far Village project arrived, 
trumpeting the goals of cultural preservation, "sustainable 
development," and "empowerment" for villagers, especially village 
women.  As stated in the Far Village project proposal, the designer's 
objective was to ensure that younger women, who "lose these skills as 
they move away from the village . . . be offered a way of earning 
money in order to retain their embroidery, weaving, and batik 
skills." 57

Yet as the project got underway in 1994, it was apparent that the 
enlisting of capital for these misguided purposes was instead 
reinforcing an extant power dynamic that worked to keep women 
producers subordinate and vulnerable, rather than "empowered."  The 
project was affiliated with four existing crafts workshops (and their 
associated putting-out systems) in different locales throughout the 
province.  Far Village work was parceled out by these workshops 
according to the same contractual arrangements that had previously 
existed. Village producers, on average, earned between 1 percent and 
5 percent of these workshops' wholesale prices for Far Village 
products.  In addition, the whole project, and especially the 
clothing designs, were shrouded in secrecy.  Ostensibly, this was 
because of intense competition from nonaffiliated crafts workshops. 
One affiliated workshop had had the experience of a designer who quit 
in 1992 starting his own workshop with designs stolen from his 
employer.  But there was another, more disturbing reason for all the 
secrecy.  This was necessary, one manager claimed, "so that the idea 
doesn't get out of control, so that peasants don't start trying to do 
this kind of thing for themselves. That would influence their 
traditional designs."  The manager further justified this control as 
in the best interests of the peasant producers themselves: should 
these unsavvy crafts workers unwisely stray into more "modern" 
designs, they would fail to satisfy foreign buyers and thus lose any 
income potential. 58   Not seeing the final product assembled in the 
crafts factory, village women applying wax for batik had no idea that 
their labor had helped produce a bathrobe that would eventually be 
sold in a Seattle boutique.  Such knowledge, according to workshop 
managers, would have compromised the "traditional authenticity" of 
their products. 59...

[Endnotes omitted; the full article is available at 
<http://www.press.jhu.edu/journals/positions/v007/7.2oakes.html>.] 
*****

Yoshie

Reply via email to