http://.nytimes.com

   Saw James C. Scott square off vs. Sam Popkin once. Wallersteinian
conference at UCSC wioth others in attendence
http://www.wjh.harvard.edu/soc/faculty/skocpol/
and Temma Kaplan, at UCSC. Debated, the Moral vs. Political Economy of the
Peasant.  Papers later published in Theory & Society, I think. The journal
founded by Alvin Gouldner, author of the classic, "The Coming Crisis of
Western Sociology, " from 1970.


The Best-Laid Plans
Date: April 19, 1998, Late Edition - Final
Byline: By John Gray
Lead:

SEEING LIKE A STATE
How Certain Schemes to Improve
the Human Condition Have Failed.
By James C. Scott.
Illustrated. 445 pp. New Haven:
Yale University Press. $35.



Text:



The 20th century has seen many grand schemes for improving the human
condition. The collectivization of farming in the Soviet Union, compulsory
''villagization'' in Ethiopia and postcolonial Tanzania, the construction of
Brasilia according to Le Corbusier's theories of urban planning, Maoist
China's Great Leap Forward and the self-sufficient rural economy that was
the goal of Pol Pot's Cambodia were ambitious efforts to better the lot of
humankind. The ideas inspiring the schemes and the regimes that attempted
them were highly diverse. The human costs of the experiments varied from an
immeasurable toll in broken lives in Russia and China to a farcical waste of
effort in Brazil. Despite their differences, these bold experiments had one
thing in common: all failed. Why is it that such grandiose schemes of human
betterment came to nothing? And can we be sure we have learned the lessons
of their failure?

In what must be one of the most profound and illuminating studies of this
century to have been published in recent decades -- ''Seeing Like a
State'' -- James C. Scott contends that these apparently disparate
experiments exemplify a single body of ideas. He calls this system of
beliefs ''high modernism,'' and he tells us that it inspired such different
figures as Robert McNamara, Walther Rathenau, Jean Monnet, the Shah of Iran,
David Lilienthal, Lenin, Trotsky and Julius Nyerere. Scott identifies the
birth of high modernism with the economic mobilization of Germany during
World War I, and describes Nazism as ''a reactionary form of modernism.'' As
he goes on to show, high modernism is found not only in totalitarian
regimes. He sees evidence of high modernist ideas in what he terms the
''Soviet-American fetish'' of ''industrial farming'' -- the enthusiasm for
mass production in agriculture that led some American agronomists to support
Soviet collectivization. What is this set of beliefs that so easily crosses
boundaries between regimes, economic systems and political ideologies?

For Scott, high modernism is the attempt to design society in accord with
what are believed to be scientific laws. Typically, high modernists think
that the best way to meet human needs is by expanding production in
agriculture and industry. They want society to be governed not by the
practical intelligence of its members but by scientific knowledge. Some
believe that production itself should be planned. All are convinced that
society must be reshaped according to a rational design. Seeing the apparent
disorder of societies that are not governed by some overall scheme as a sign
that they are not yet modern, they believe that in a truly modern society
everything that is traditional or accidental will have been rendered
obsolete.

Scott contends that two of the largest social experiments of our century --
urban renewal and the rural resettlement of peasant farmers -- are examples
of the high modernist attempt to use the power of the state to impose a
rational order on society. In a fascinating interpretation of the growth of
the modern state, he points out that, at least since the Enlightenment and
the French Revolution, governments have been making the life of society
''legible'' in order to make social life comprehensible, and thereby
controllable, by political power. The lives of medieval cities and peasant
farmers could not easily be known by outsiders; to understand them local
knowledge was needed, because the order of people's lives differed from
place to place. Modern states need standardized techniques of measurement to
tax and monitor their citizens and mobilize the resources of society. The
clutter and lumber of peasant and medieval life were obstacles to such
goals. Accordingly -- in contexts as different as the development of
''scientifically managed'' forests containing only a single type of tree (a
telling example Scott cites from 19th-century German history); the
construction of straight, gridlike streets in cities; and the introduction
of fixed surnames -- modern states have implemented systems of
classification that allow them greater control over resources and the lives
of their citizens.

High modernists have used the increased powers of states to reshape society
so that it functions as an enterprise whose goal is to maximize production.
They have done so in the faith that they can thereby improve the human lot.
Yet wherever it has been attempted the high modernist project has led to
poverty, and sometimes it has produced human tragedy on a grand scale. Scott
argues that ''the most tragic episodes of state-initiated social engineering
originate in a pernicious combination of four elements.'' He suggests that
the conditions that account for the failure of the great 20th-century
schemes of human improvement are the administrative ordering of society by
the state, a faith in high modernist ideas, an authoritarian regime ready to
use its coercive power to promote high modernist designs, and a weak civil
society that lacks the power to resist these plans. When these four
conditions occur together -- as they did in the Soviet Union, China and
certain developing countries -- the results have been some of the worst
disasters of social engineering.

The grand schemes for improving the human condition that our century has
witnessed failed because of an error in their perception of human knowledge.
High modernists thought they knew better than ordinary human beings how
society works. They aimed to replace the common understanding of social life
with scientific knowledge. But scientific knowledge is too abstract to
capture our understanding of local circumstances -- the practical knowledge
the ancient Greeks called metis, which carried Odysseus though his
adventures. This is the knowledge that modern governments ignored when they
attempted to resettle peasant farmers in newly constructed villages. It is
the knowledge urban planners lack when they try to construct cities
according to a simple, comprehensive design.

The lesson of ''Seeing Like a State'' is that the disasters of 20th-century
social engineering come from its neglect of metis. Without the human
capacity for this practical understanding, the harm done by grand schemes of
human improvement would have been even worse. In fact, the only thing that
has saved some societies from total wreckage by the absurdities of these
projects has been the presence in them of resourceful human beings who have
tempered them with the wisdom embodied in metis.

Scott presents a formidable argument against using the power of the state in
an attempt to reshape the whole of society. But, as he acknowledges in a
number of asides that unfortunately he fails to develop, it is not only
state planning that can disregard the practical knowledge of ordinary
people. The free market can do it just as well. Today, when ideas of
planning are in disarray, high modernism has found a home in the ideology of
free markets.

The contemporary cult of the free market is just as radical an exercise in
social engineering as many experiments in economic planning tried in this
century. Like other kinds of high modernism, it rests on a confident
ignorance of the immensely complex workings of real societies. Governments
throughout the world are being advised by transnational organizations to
reconstruct their economies on the basis of free markets. But no government
or transnational organization can know what will be the results of promoting
free markets in societies in which they have never before been central. What
will be the effects on family life, on crime and on the economy itself?

In Russia since the collapse of Communism, the attempt to construct free
markets has resulted in a species of capitalism very different from that
portrayed in Western economics textbooks. The fact is that free market
theories can tell us little about how different economies really work. Yet
it is a theoretical ideal rather than a detailed knowledge of local
circumstances that continues to guide economic reform in many parts of the
world.

Today's faith in the free market echoes the faith of earlier generations in
high modernist schemes that failed at great human cost. ''Seeing Like a
State'' does not tell us what it is in late modern societies that
predisposes them, against all the evidence of history, to put their trust in
such utopias. Sadly, no one knows enough to explain that.





 Return to the Books Home Page


----------------------------------------------------------------------------
----

Home | Site Index | Site Search | Forums | Archives | Marketplace

Quick News | Page One Plus | International | National/N.Y. | Business |
Technology | Science | Sports | Weather | Editorial | Op-Ed | Arts |
Automobiles | Books | Diversions | Job Market | Real Estate | Travel

Help/Feedback | Classifieds | Services | New York Today

Copyright 2001 The New York Times Company


Reply via email to