The Economist/October 20, 2001

EDITORIAL: The risks are worsening

SUPPOSE that the second-hand car you bought kept breaking down. Would you 
buy another from the same dealer? The same question might apply to economic 
forecasters. A year ago, most expected the American economy to grow by 3.5% 
in 2001. By early this year, they thought that a sharper slowdown, but 
still a soft landing, was likely; even in early September, almost all still 
ruled out a recession. Today, however, most believe that a recession was 
already under way before September 11th. When these same people confidently 
tell you that this recession will be short and mild-indeed, that it will be 
one of the mildest in 50 years-why would you believe them?

It is surely wishful thinking to hope that the bursting of one of the 
biggest financial bubbles in history, combined with the aftershocks from 
the most serious attack ever on America's soil, will be followed by the 
mildest recession in history. That is not to suggest that America will 
follow Japan with a decade of stagnation. America is in a healthier state 
than Japan was at the start of the 1990s. Yet there are good reasons to 
expect America's recession to be deeper and longer-lasting than most people 
now expect (see article). One is the sheer scale of investment and 
borrowing during the late 1990s. Another is the unusually synchronised 
nature of this global slowdown, with economies around the world sinking 
together. Indeed, it is possible that the world economy as a whole may be 
about to suffer its deepest downturn since the 1930s. That, in turn, 
increases the chances of a deeper recession in America.

Despite all this, some commentators fret that policymakers are in danger of 
easing monetary and fiscal policy by too much, so pushing up future 
inflation. The Economist has a reputation as an inflation hawk, so one 
might expect us to be in this camp. On the contrary. If anything, the risk 
to the global economy is not too much inflation, but too little. As a 
result of the sharp slowdown in demand, global excess capacity is by some 
measures at its greatest since the 1930s. That will push inflation lower 
over the next year, from its already low levels. One result is that growth 
in the G7 economies will be strikingly low in nominal terms, running at 
just above 1% in the current quarter. Sluggish nominal GDP growth means 
that it will take longer to purge the excesses of debt and overcapacity. 
Unexpectedly low inflation will squeeze profits, exacerbate debt problems 
and put strains on the financial system.

By some measures, in any case, monetary policy is not that loose in 
America. Using the Fed's favoured measure of inflation, the personal 
consumption expenditure deflator, real interest rates are still positive. 
Moreover, rate cuts have failed to ease overall financial conditions much. 
Such cuts work partly by pushing down the currency or propping up equity 
prices. Yet, despite the recovery of the past two weeks, share prices are 
30% below their peak, and the dollar is stronger than at the start of the 
year. Heavily indebted firms and households may also be reluctant to borrow 
more even with lower rates.

American interest rates probably need to be cut further. Likewise, starting 
with the luxury of a budget surplus, America's government is right to be 
giving the economy a fiscal boost. To be effective, though, any fiscal 
easing must put money into the hands of those most likely to spend it. The 
exact shape of the fiscal package now being debated by Congress is 
therefore more important than its size.

Altogether now

At least American policymakers are trying hard to stave off a deep 
recession. The same is not always true elsewhere. Despite worsening 
deflation, the Bank of Japan beggars belief by arguing that further 
monetary easing could run the risk of triggering hyperinflation. The 
European Central Bank also failed to cut interest rates last week. Wim 
Duisenberg, its president, argued unconvincingly that a cut in rates might 
dent consumer confidence by giving the impression of panic. And few 
European governments (except France's, and then only mildly) offer much 
hope of fiscal stimulus, arguing instead that there should be no relaxation 
of budgetary discipline.

Nor is there much hope from emerging economies, for many in Latin America 
and Asia are in recession already. Asian governments are at least using 
their fiscal tools more actively to boost their economies. Singapore's 
government has announced tax cuts and extra public spending equivalent to 
7% of GDP. But many Latin American countries that are heavily dependent on 
foreign capital, notably Argentina, are actually having to raise interest 
rates and tighten fiscal policy.

Economies such as Japan and Europe, which still have room for monetary or 
fiscal easing, would be wise to use it. Low inflation and budgetary 
discipline are fine long-term goals, but they are best put aside when the 
world economy is flirting with such a deep recession.

Copyright © 2001 The Economist

Jim Devine [EMAIL PROTECTED] &  http://bellarmine.lmu.edu/~jdevine


Reply via email to