nonsense!! see comments below -- Jim D. 

>December 26, 2001

>Enron's Success Story

>By SUSAN LEE

>The collapse of Enron was many things -- a gratifying slap in the face to
corporate hubris and an exposure of the Alfred E. Neuman club of stock
analysts, rating agencies and the SEC. It may even prove to be a fascinating
look into criminal minds. But there is one thing, for sure, it wasn't -- a
market failure. To the contrary, Enron's implosion was confirmation of the
principles that govern competitive markets.

>Enron's success and failure ran along the lines set down in any
microeconomics text. The company discovered a new product -- mostly ways of
trading energy in the derivatives market -- that allowed producers and users
to lay off risk. This new product was wildly popular and, as the innovator,
Enron made lovely above-market returns. But those abnormal returns attracted
other firms into the business and Enron's advantage was gradually "competed
away." Each new market entrant put the squeeze on
Enron's margins. <

JD: this Schumpeterian story, by the way, is not prominently displayed in
micro books. Rather, the emphasis is on NC static equilibrium.

>What happened next is still a matter of speculation, but there are 
several theories that seem reasonable.

>Bad hedging. Although Enron started out as a plain vanilla energy company,
it shed those hard assets that could have underpinned its financial business
and morphed into a trading company and then, quickly, into a hedge fund.<

JD: It's amazing how economists forget the difference between hedging and
speculation. A true fund that hedges -- not speculative outfits like Enron
or Long-Term Capital Management -- seeks to minimize risk by diversifying,
locking in long-term prices (or interest rates) to avoid risks due to price
(rate) fluctuations. But these so-called "hedge funds" were speculative and
_highly leveraged_, as Lee notes below. The latter helps explain the high
returns: it is very easy to show that the more leveraged a speculator is,
the higher the return. 

>A trading company can make money no matter which direction the market goes
by simply trading and taking its money from creating a market. If
prices are falling, then suppliers rush into the market to get contracts
that nail down prices; if prices are rising, then users rush in to get
contracts. Traders can make money either way. Indeed, in this model, a
volatile market is the best of all possible worlds.

>But with its margins -- and cash -- getting squeezed, Enron started
borrowing money and pretty soon it was running with remarkable leverage,
thus becoming a giant hedge fund. When things started to go wrong, Enron's
traders quite possibly were panicked into trying to hit a home run. That is,
they started taking big bets on the direction of the market, perhaps taking
aggressively long positions in energy. A successful hedge fund, however,
depends on adequately hedging bets, especially leveraged ones. But as Enron
started to lose money on its big bets, observers guess that the
insufficiency of its hedges began to look lethal.<

JD: This seems okay (given the misuse of the word "hedging"), but ignores
the _fraudulent_ nature of Enron's enterprise. Marx pointed out that
speculative booms involve a tremedous amount of fraud and that this cheating
is typically revealed when the boom ends. 

>There are also more complicated theories that argue Enron was hiding its
slowing growth in earnings with various accounting strategies.<

JD: "strategies"? that's like calling the 1970 US invasion of Cambodia an
"incursion." Enron spun off a lot of its debt to "parterships," to make its
balance sheets look good.

>Bad trading. Enron's main technique to pump up earnings probably revolved
around a loose-as-a-goose process for the accounting of energy derivatives.
Called mark-to-market, the technique involves evaluating contracts at "fair
value" prices.

>Since some of these contracts stretched out for 20 years, the futures
market provides no firm prices. And, absent a liquid market with clear
prices, "fair value" becomes a mug's game in which companies can vastly
inflate value.

>These overstated gains, of course, were also unrealized, noncash gains. In
September 2000, Jonathan Weil, a reporter for the Journal, took a look at
Enron's second quarter and found that absent noncash earnings, Enron would
have had a loss. Mr. Weil later found that for the year as a whole,
unrealized trading gains accounted for more than half of the company's
originally reported pretax profits. Hardly a confidence-builder in the
quality of Enron's earnings.

>When their derivative strategies started to go sour, this theory runs,
Enron removed the contracts from its financial statements and hid them in
special entities created for just that purpose.<

JD: here's the deliberate effort to save Enron's ass by cheating. 

>Bad Assets. Another theory locates Enron's earning problems in their hard
assets. Enron had a bunch of huge and underperforming assets, like its
broadband company, water company and power plants in India and Brazil. In
order to hustle those assets and associated debts off its    financial
reports, the company created some limited partnerships to buy these dogs --
either with bank loans or money provided by Enron itself. These partnerships
(allegedly) transferred enough control to third parties to get them off
Enron's balance sheet.

>Enron guaranteed these deals with "make good" provisions backed by Enron
stock -- a promise that Enron would make good any losses in the value of the
partnerships. When the value of the assets tanked, the make-good provisions
kicked in, resulting, for example, in the enormous write-down in shareholder
equity in November.

>Depending on which theory one accepts, there are two bottom lines.

>The first holds that the sagging earnings problem was fatal and that it is
entirely possible Enron was in the process of liquidating itself. Jim Chanos
of Kynikos Associates hypothesizes that Enron's cost of capital was higher
than its returns on invested capital. A second argues that if Enron's
managers had been content to accept the fact that in competitive markets
their "first mover" advantage was going to be competed away, and had been
willing to endure slower earnings growth, it would not be in
bankruptcy today.

>Enron's collapse also says something valuable about the energy trading
markets: Competitive markets worked just as expected. As questions were
raised about the quality of Enron's earnings -- and, just as important, not
answered -- investors grew wary. Although the stock opened the year trading
in the 80s, it started drifting down as investors bailed. The stock had
already lost half its value and was trading below 40 before the company
announced a big third-quarter loss and made its first disclosure of
accounting "mistakes" in October.

>At the same time, traders outside the company had begun to unwind positions
and do business with other firms. At the end of September, Enron had 25% of
the energy-trading market. Just two months later, its business had
disappeared but that disappearance didn't cause the tiniest ripple in the
market. The swift collapse of what once was a $77 billion dollar company
failed to generate either a price spike or a supply interruption because the
market was sufficiently liquid and deep to absorb it. 

>In short, no matter how one views the purposes or operations of a 
competitive market, the history of Enron proves that the market works pretty
much as expected. And thus the story of Enron is, so far, a success story.<

JD: So "market success" involves wild fluctuations, which is much more than
the Schumpeterian story that Lee starts with. Instead of the story of the
entrepreneur who gets temporary super-profits, which are then quietly
competed away, this is a story akin to that of Marx: Enron's operations got
the company further and further away from equilibrium -- as so often happens
when fictitious capital rears its ugly head -- so that when equilibration
happened, it was forcible, abrupt, and destructive. 

Second, as befits a contributor to the Wall Street JOURNAL, Lee ignores the
external effects of Enron's fall -- on creditors, on workers (who were also
pension-holders), and on auditors. The first rule of H*yek/Friedmaniac
economics is to ignore or minimize the role of external effects. 

happy new year!

Reply via email to