< http://www.prospect-magazine.co.uk >
Are global poverty and inequality getting worse?

Dear Martin

 22nd January 2002

You have written eloquently in the Financial Times about
globalisation. You make three main points. (1) Poverty and
inequality on a world scale have both fallen over the past two
decades for the first time in more than 150 years. (2) These
falls are due to greater global economic integration. (3) The
anti-globalisation movement encourages countries to adopt
policies that will in fact only intensify their poverty and
inequality.

Let us take the first point about trends in poverty and
inequality. If you are wrong here, the rest of your argument
begins to wobble and, in fact, there are reasons to doubt what
you say. On poverty, the World Bank is the main source of
numbers. Bank researchers have found that the number of people
in absolute poverty (with incomes less than about $1 per day)
was roughly constant in 1987 and 1998, at around 1.2 billion.
Since world population increased, the proportion of the world's
population in absolute poverty fell sharply from around 28 per
cent to 24 per cent in only 11 years. This is good news.

But recent research on where the Bank got the 1.2 billion
suggests that the method for calculating the numbers is
questionable. The effect is probably to understate the true
numbers in poverty. How much higher than 1.2 billion we do not
yet know.

So what is happening to global inequality? It is widening
rapidly, if we compare the average incomes for each country and
treat each one as a unit (China = Uganda). Yet income inequality
among countries has become more equal, since around 1980, if we
compare the average incomes for each country and weight each one
by its population. However, this result comes from fast growth
in China and India. If they are excluded this measure of
inequality shows no obvious trend since 1980.

In any case, this measure-using the average income of each
country weighted by population-is interesting only as an
approximation to what we are really interested in, which is the
income distribution among all the world's people or households,
regardless of where they live. The problem is that we do not
have good data for the incomes of all the world's people. You
say that global inequality amongst households has probably
fallen. But the most comprehensive data on world incomes, based
on household income and expenditure surveys, find a sharp
increase in inequality over as short a time as 1988 to 1993.
Some of this may be statistical error; but the results do mean
that the balance of probability falls in the direction of
increasing global inequality among households.

This conclusion is strengthened by the trends in industrial pay
inequality within countries. Pay inequality within countries was
stable or declining from the early 1960s to 1982, then sharply
increased from 1982 to the present. The year 1982 was a dramatic
turning point towards greater inequality within the world's
countries.

Doesn't the fast growth of populous China and India create a
presumption that world income distribution is becoming more
equal? No. At low levels of income, growth has to be fast for a
long time before the absolute gap with slow-growing, high income
countries begins to fall. The absolute income gap between a
developing country with an average income of $1,000 a year,
growing at 6 per cent, and a developed country with average
income of $30,000, growing at 1 per cent, continues to widen
until after the 40th year. China and India are not reducing the
gap between their average incomes and the averages of the
countries of western Europe, North America and Japan. They are,
though, closing the gap with the faltering, middle-income states
like Mexico, Brazil, Russia and Argentina, which is why average
inequality among countries has become more equal since around
1980. But this reduction in the gap between China and India and
the middle-income states is probably offset by widening income
inequality within the two giants.

Perhaps all the thunder and lightning about the trends diverts
attention from the main issue: the sheer magnitude of poverty
and inequality on a world scale. The magnitude is unacceptable,
regardless of the trend, and the world development agenda should
make inequality reduction (not only poverty reduction) a high
priority. Roughly 85 per cent of world income goes to 20 per
cent of the world's population and 6 per cent to 60 per cent of
the world's population. Can this meet any plausible test of
legitimacy? It is difficult to see how it could meet the
Rawlsian principle that a given degree of inequality is
acceptable if it is necessary for the worst off to become better
off.

Integration/globalisation is nothing like the engine of
development you say it is. The engine is the advance of
technology and the diffusion of technical capacities of people,
firms and governments. Some forms of integration may help this,
others may hinder it, depending partly on a country's stage of
development.



Regards Robert



Dear Robert

 25th January 2002



----------------------------------------------------------------
----------------


All data on incomes and income distribution are questionable,
above all those generated in developing countries. But, contrary
to what you say, World Bank researchers have calculated the
numbers in extreme poverty-less than $1 a day-on a consistent
basis, in recent studies.

The data shows a decline since 1980 of 200m people in the
category of the absolutely poor. This is a fall from 31 per cent
of the world's population to 20 per cent (not 24 per cent, which
is the proportion in developing countries alone). That is a
spectacularly rapid fall in poverty by historical standards. It
makes a nonsense of the idea that poverty alleviation has been
blighted by globalisation.

Now turn to the even murkier area of inequality. Here you argue
that if we exclude China and India, there is no obvious trend in
inequality. But why would one want to exclude two countries that
contained about 60 per cent of the world's poorest people two
decades ago and still contain almost 40 per cent of the world's
population today? To fail to give these giants their due weight
in a discussion of global poverty alleviation or income
distribution would be Hamlet without the prince.

You then write that changes in relative average incomes across
countries are not what we are really interested in, "which is
the income distribution among all the world's people or
households." This is wrong in itself. If a country's average
income rises rapidly, it does also possess greater means for
improving the lot of the poor. Maybe the government refuses to
use the opportunity, but a successor government could.

In any case, we do possess data on relative household incomes.
In a Foreign Affairs article, David Dollar and Aart Kraay of the
World Bank report a big decline in world-wide income inequality
since its peak in about 1970. The study builds on work that goes
back to 1820. The underlying method is to calculate the
percentage gap between a randomly selected individual and the
world average. The more unequal the distribution of world
income, the bigger that gap becomes. They report that this gap
peaked at 88 per cent of world average income in 1970, before
falling to 78 per cent in 1995, roughly where it was in 1950.

The chief driver of changes in inequality among households is
changes between countries, not within them. This was also the
finding of Branko Milanovic's study of global household income
distribution between 1988 and 1993, which you cite approvingly.
You rely on this study to support the thesis of rising household
inequality. But it contains at least four defects. First, there
are well-known inconsistencies between data on household
expenditures and national accounts. Second, the methods used
generate no increase in rural real incomes in China, which is
inconsistent with most views of what actually happened. Third,
the period of five years is very short. Fourth and most
important, this was an atypical period, because India had an
economic upheaval in 1991, while China's growth was temporarily
slowed by the Tiananmen crisis.

My conclusion is that the last two decades saw a decline not
just in absolute poverty but also in world-wide inequality among
households. The chief explanation for this was the fast growth
of China and, to a lesser extent, of India. This progress was
not offset by rising inequality within them. In the case of
India there was no such rise. In China there has been a rise in
inequality in the more recent period of its growth, largely
because of controls on the movement of people from the
hinterland to the coastal regions.

Unfortunately, you muddy the waters on inequality by raising the
question of growing absolute gaps in incomes between rich and
poor countries. If the income of the poor rises faster than the
income of the rich, inequality falls, even if absolute gaps
rise, since the standard measures of inequality describe
relative, not absolute, differences in incomes.

This is vastly more than just a question of definition. China's
average incomes per head are only a tenth of those of the US.
They would have to grow at around 20 per cent a year to match
the absolute increases now prevailing in the US. I see no point
in bemoaning the failure to achieve what is impossible. Unless
you are suggesting implausibly huge income transfers from
taxpayers in rich countries to the world's poor, or complete
freedom of migration, absolute gaps in living standards will
rise for many decades, even if poor countries now grow very
quickly. This is the tyranny of history: we can only start from
where we are.

The trends in pay inequality you bring in to support your
arguments further cloud the issue. Few of the world's poor earn
wages that anybody reports. They work as subsistence farmers or
do casual work in informal activities. Almost all reported wage
earners are in the upper half of the global income distribution.

Yet this debate is, as you say, not just about measuring poverty
and inequality, but about what these trends mean. You write that
the magnitude of poverty and inequality are unacceptable. I
agree on the former. That is why raising average incomes in poor
countries and of poor people in both poor and less poor
countries is an urgent goal of public policy.

But your position on the unacceptability of inequality also
amounts to saying that the world would be a better place if the
rich countries of today had never started rapid development in
the 19th and 20th centuries. Maybe you do think this. But almost
all citizens of advanced countries do not. They have no
intention of doing without what they now have. So bemoaning the
magnitude of global inequality, as opposed to the low standards
of living of large parts of the world, is just empty rhetoric.
It has no significance for action.

Today's global inequality and continuing, though also declining,
mass poverty are the outcome of deep-seated historic processes
that can be reversed only with vast and sustained improvements
in poor countries, supported by rich ones. A start was made in
the 1980s and 1990s. But the huge worry concerns those poor
countries where there is now no sustained rise in living
standards.



Yours Martin



Dear Martin

 29th January 2002



----------------------------------------------------------------
----------------


On absolute poverty, you take the World Bank figures at face
value, I say that they cannot be so taken. On inequality, you
cite the work of World Bank economist David Dollar as the main
evidence that world income inequality has declined over the past
20-25 years. But his method gives too much weight to what
happens in the middle swathe of world population and too little
weight to what happens towards the lower and upper ends of the
distribution.

Contrary to what you say, inequality in India-rural-urban,
intra-urban, intra-rural-increased over the past two decades.
And everyone agrees inequality in China has risen rapidly. In a
recent year, the ratio of the richest to poorest state or
province was 1.9 for the US, 4.2 for India and for China, 7 in
the early 1990s, 11 in the late 1990s.

You place too much trust not only in David Dollar's methodology,
but also in the Bank's data set on inequality to which it is
applied. Anyone applying the "laugh test" would have grounds for
doubt: according to the Bank, Spain is the most equal country in
Europe; France is much more unequal than Germany; India and
Indonesia are in the same equality league as Norway. The data is
based on uncoordinated sample surveys, separated in time and
space, often conducted by unofficial researchers, in countries
with differing concepts of income and differing attitudes
towards revealing income to strangers. The Milanovic data based
on household income and expenditure surveys around the world
also has its problems, as you say, but is not obviously inferior
to the Bank's national income data; and it suggests sharply
rising inequality.

You say that "bemoaning the magnitude of global inequality, as
opposed to the low standards of living of large parts of the
world, is just empty rhetoric." No. If the magnitude of
inequality is as large and difficult to justify as it seems to
be, this greatly fortifies the case for public policy
actions-some national, some international-to "tilt the playing
field" in favour of the lagging regions. A significantly more
equal world is likely to be more stable, peaceful and possibly
more prosperous. Also, there's no reason for you to reject
measures of absolute income gaps just because these are not
relevant to the standard measures of inequality. We should be
concerned with both absolute and relative gaps, for both relate
to important ethical values, both are relevant to feelings of
disempowerment and deprivation. Absolute gaps between, say, the
top quintile and the bottom quintile of the world's population,
you have to agree, are rising sharply.

So far, all this has been about your first point to do with
trends in poverty and inequality. Your second point is about
globalisation (or increased economic integration) as the world's
best means of reducing poverty and inequality. I doubt it. The
most powerful engine of development is the diffusion of
technical capacities. This is proceeding at a furious rate in
China, more sedately in India, at a snail's pace in most of
Latin America, and slower, if at all, in sub-Saharan Africa and
much of the middle east. China and India are likely to
experience a shift towards more income equality when they come
near to full employment, five to ten decades from now. But any
such shift in Latin America, sub-Saharan Africa and the middle
east will be even further away.

The World Bank studies on which you rely for your conclusions
about the benign impacts of globalisation are shot through with
problems. They distinguish "globalising" countries from
"non-globalising" countries, and find that the former have much
better economic performance than the latter. They measure
globalising by changes in the ratio of trade to GDP. So
globalising countries are ones that had a big rise in their
trade/GDP ratio.

Let us accept that the countries the Bank calls globalisers did,
indeed, have fast economic growth. The question is: why? At
best, the Bank studies show that countries that start being
closed, with very low trade/GDP, can have fast growth if they
take policy steps that yield more trade/GDP. This sounds
plausible, and it matches the experience of South Korea and
Taiwan in the 1950s. But the finding does not support the policy
prescription that all developing countries should liberalise
their trade regimes in order to experience faster growth.

For two decades, the Bank's official view about development has
been: adopt a liberal trade policy (low tariff and non-tariff
barriers), deregulate markets, privatise state enterprises,
welcome foreign firms, maintain fiscal balance and low
inflation. The trouble is that there is no evidence that opening
to trade does generally result in subsequently faster growth,
holding other things like macroeconomic conditions constant.

The best examples of globalising countries are China and India,
which are hardly poster-children for globalisation. They have
certainly both had fast rises in trade/GDP in the recent period,
and also fast economic growth. But the onset of fast growth
occurred about a decade prior to their liberalising trade
reforms. And the Bank would now be denouncing their trade
policies and internal market-restricting policies as growth and
efficiency-inhibiting-if they had not been growing so fast.
Their policies remain far from those that the Bank seeks to get
its borrowers to adopt; in fact, their trade barriers remain
amongst the highest in the world. Their experience, and that of
Japan, South Korea and Taiwan earlier, shows that countries do
not have to have liberal trade policies in order to grow fast.
It shows only that as countries become richer they tend to
liberalise trade, which is not the same thing. The sensible ones
liberalise in line with the growth of domestic capacities-they
try to expose domestic producers to enough competition to make
them more efficient, but not enough to kill them. China and
India suggest a policy regime that is not close to what the Bank
says, but nor is it "anti-globalisation."

The China-WTO agreement shows the dangers of pressing free trade
upon developing countries. The agreement makes it difficult for
China to adopt one of the most powerful inequality-mitigating
measures: agricultural subsidies. In Japan, South Korea, Taiwan
and, of course, Europe and the US, agricultural subsidies have
been an important means of redistributing the fruits of
industrialisation. China has had to sign away its rights to all
but very low subsidies, with consequences that, given the degree
of regional inequality, could be quite explosive. Likewise,
China's agreement to give equal access to foreign companies will
mean that it cannot protect "inefficient" labour-intensive
industries that serve to equalise incomes. It is worrying for
the whole world that the Chinese government itself now seems to
think it can maintain an urban-rural apartheid state by means of
the pass laws, while opening the economy at a pace so fast that
unemployment will shoot upwards from its already high levels.

The point is more general. Under WTO rules, developing countries
face constraints which prevent them from adopting the measures
that already-developed countries (including East Asian ones)
deployed to nurture their technological learning. This is
outrageous. WTO rules and the Bank's official view need to be
revised, soon, in the self-interest of the west, as well as the
bulk of the world's population.



Regards Robert



Dear Robert

 3rd February 2002



----------------------------------------------------------------
----------------


A significant decline has occurred in the proportion of the
world population in absolute poverty over the past two decades.
I think we agree on this. Whether there has been a fall in
absolute numbers is less certain, though also, in my view,
highly plausible. Your denial of this latter proposition rests
on the view that any data or analyses from the World Bank must
be tainted. Yet you rely on another Bank study for the
proposition that inequality increased between 1988 and 1993.
Your position is that any study which comes to a conclusion you
dislike must be rejected (and vice versa).

You stress that absolute gaps between the world's richest and
poorest people are rising. I agree. But so what? Even if poor
countries grew far faster than rich ones, absolute gaps in
living standards would rise for many years. This is the result
of two centuries of differential growth. Why bemoan what cannot
be helped?

What is needed, you then suggest, is "to tilt the playing field"
in favour of lagging regions. There have been many attempts to
do this, from carte blanche for protection to substantial aid.
None has been notably successful. So what are you proposing?
Huge transfers to the world's poor, free migration into rich
countries, or a permanent depression in the north? I look
forward to your attempts to sell any of these. Yet the very
notion that impoverishment of the north might be a good thing
shows the absurdity of your obsession with equality in itself.
World income distribution was far less unequal two centuries
ago, when perhaps 80 per cent of its population lived in extreme
poverty. Did this make 1800 better than today?

The only sensible goal must be to raise the standards of living
of the world's poorest people as quickly as we can. What is
needed for this is faster growth. Look at China and India's own
data. Indian data gives a decline of about 100m in absolute
poverty between 1980 and 2000. China uses a lower poverty line
but reports that the number of extreme poor in China declined
from 250m in 1978 to 34m in 1999. Unfortunately, these successes
have been offset by calamitous failures elsewhere, notably in
sub-Saharan Africa.

I assume you support the need for faster growth in poor
countries. Presumably, you also endorse the need for open
markets in the north. After all, Taiwan and South Korea
developed through exploitation of access to world markets. Yet
many in the anti-globalisation movement are against trade
liberalisation by the north. Many of them also say that foreign
direct investment (FDI) impoverishes the poor. You say that
China is not a "poster-child for globalisation." But China has
been the biggest recipient of FDI in the developing world.
Malaysia, to take another example, has received roughly as much
inward FDI as the whole of sub-Saharan Africa.

The causes of developing country growth are complex. But your
technological determinism is even more simple-minded than your
caricature of the so-called Washington consensus. Many countries
devoted much effort to upgrading technological capacity, but
have failed to sustain rapid development: the Soviet Union was
one and India another. One cannot separate technology from the
context in which it is applied.

Among the essential pre-conditions for growth are: a stable
state; security of the person and of property; widespread
literacy and numeracy; basic health; adequate infrastructure;
the ability to develop businesses without suffocation by red
tape or corruption; broad acceptance of market forces;
macro-economic stability, and a financial system capable of
transferring savings to effective uses. In successful countries,
these conditions emerge in a mutually reinforcing cycle. There
is also evidence, I accept, that some initial equality in income
and asset distribution helps.

The tragedy of Africa is that so few of these pre-conditions
exist. Do I believe that trade liberalisation would fix this?
No. But trade is the handmaiden of growth. There is no country
that set out to reduce its reliance on trade, as
anti-globalisers propose, and subsequently secured sustained
growth. Even in the inauspicious soil of Africa, countries such
as Uganda, which tried to exploit market opportunities, have
achieved faster growth and poverty reduction.

Finally, you argue that, under WTO rules, developing countries
are being forced to forgo their ability to adopt
inequality-alleviating or growth-promoting policies. You assume
that, in the absence of external constraints on their policy
discretion, these countries would choose well-targeted trade
policy interventions. This proposition does fail your laugh
test. In any case, developing countries can use tariffs if they
wish. China could have remained outside the WTO. But the Chinese
authorities believed their country would do even better inside.
I suspect this judgement will be proved right.

I would invite you to subscribe to the following three
propositions. First, the biggest policy challenge is to
accelerate economic growth in poor countries. Second, open
markets in the north and FDI make an important contribution to
such growth. Third, self-sufficiency is a foolish development
strategy. If you accept these points, you are on my side of the
policy argument with the anti-globalisers, like it or not.



Yours Martin

Dear Martin

 4th February 2002



----------------------------------------------------------------
----------------


I agree with your three propositions and have never argued
anything different. You seem wedded to simplistic
categorisations of "globalisers" and "anti-globalisers." I am
not an anti-globaliser or a friend of protectionist American
unions. But there is a fundamental fudge in your argument. It is
contained in your category of "globalising" countries-those with
fast rising integration into the world economy, like China and
India. You take their economic success as evidence of the
benefits of integration. You also believe in liberal trade
policy with low tariffs and non-tariff barriers; in particular,
you believe that trade liberalisation is a powerful force for
higher growth, so poor country governments should give high
priority in the use of scarce development funds to trade
liberalisation and WTO membership. But China and India (Vietnam
too) have reaped benefits of integration without having anything
like a liberal trade policy, as also have Japan, South Korea and
Taiwan before them. So one cannot use their success to support
the case for liberalisation.

The single biggest issue in the trend of world income
distribution is what has happened in China over the past two
decades. It makes a huge difference whether one takes the World
Bank's growth rate of 10 per cent at face value, or uses a (more
plausible) figure of, say, 7 per cent. If one takes the former
figure, global inequality has not got much worse, may have
remained constant, and might even have improved. If one uses the
latter figure, virtually all the plausible measures of world
inequality show a worsening. This underscores the point that the
world is ill-served by the Bank being the main producer of
development statistics. It has an official view about how to do
development and is subject to arm-twisting by its major
shareholders. It is under constant pressure to fudge its GDP
data base, most glaringly in the case of China and in the case
of politically sensitive numbers like the number of absolute
poor in the world.

At the heart of our disagreement, I think, is the question about
how far rich countries in general should go in using the power
our superior resources give us (a) to set the rules of the
market so that resource power is translated into market power,
and (b) to use that power to the maximum when bargaining with
people much poorer than ourselves. You say, "China could have
remained outside the WTO." But China faced a choice of taking
American terms or facing perpetual uncertainty about the US
export market. We need to press the rich country governments to
soften the conditions they set for WTO membership, and not just
for China.

In relation to countries like China and India, whose ability to
absorb and create technology is such that they have a real
prospect of reducing the gap with the rich countries in the next
five to ten decades, the rich countries should be more generous
in making trade and investment concessions to accelerate their
growth and allow them to grow in a manner according with their
own values. In relation to Africa and the non-oil parts of the
middle east and central Asia-countries that lack much of the
social technology you list-there has to be more direct aid, much
of it in the form of World Bank-type projects on the ground. The
FT could help by backing the modest increase of $50 billion in
western development aid that Gordon Brown is proposing.



Regards Robert



Dear Robert

 6th February 2002



----------------------------------------------------------------
----------------


You are convinced that the World Bank has cooked the data on
poverty and inequality. You need to produce chapter and verse to
substantiate such a serious charge, but have failed to do so.
That is not good enough. All you assert is that we do not know
what has happened to poverty and inequality, not that they have
become worse. I note also that you have not taken up my offer to
explain how we are to reduce absolute gaps in living standards
in the near future.

I accept that infant-industry promotion, buttressed by trade
restrictions, may occasionally accelerate economic growth.
However, the record on the use of such policies in developing
countries is, with few exceptions, dreadful. Yet even though
liberalisation of protectionist trade policy regimes is good for
developing countries, I don't claim it is a panacea.

I also fail to see why WTO constraints on policy discretion
should be good for rich countries, as we know they are, but not
for poor ones. Governments of developing countries are, if
anything, more vulnerable to capture by protectionist lobbies
than those of advanced countries.

I do accept, however, that developing countries have sometimes
been forced to accept inappropriate policies: the trade-related
intellectual property agreement is an example. I also agree that
the north should liberalise in favour of the south and that more
aid, targeted on countries with governments that know how to use
it, is a moral and practical necessity.

Yet there is one fundamental matter, in this debate, on which we
do disagree. Economic growth is, almost inevitably, uneven. Some
countries, regions and people do better than others. The result
is growing inequality. To regret that is to regret the growth
itself. It is to hold, in effect, that it is better for everyone
in the world (or within individual counries) to remain equally
poor. You come close to saying just that. It seems to me a
morally indefensible and practically untenable position.



Yours Martin



Reply via email to