Patent nonsense

Companies now demanding intellectual property rights were built up without them

George Monbiot
Tuesday March 12, 2002
The Guardian

The most surprising aspect of the steel war launched by the United States last week is 
that anyone is
surprised. For all the talk of increasing freedom, the only certain and consistent 
trend in global trade rules
over the past 10 years has been the drift towards protectionism.

The rich nations have repeatedly promised to phase out agricultural subsidies and to 
remove the tariffs on
textiles imported from the poor world, but those promises have been broken. Instead 
they have battened down
the hatches by granting to the corporations they shelter new laws defending 
"intellectual property".

At the world trade talks in November, the poor nations appeared to win some ground. 
They would be allowed to
continue to import cheap copies of the patented drugs required to fight epidemics. 
But, though few people
spotted it, there was a catch. While nations will be permitted to buy these drugs, by 
2005 the countries
manufacturing them will be forbidden to sell them, with the result that the rules 
defending public health
won't be worth the paper they're written on. At a meeting last week, the European 
Union seemed prepared to
compromise on this issue, but the US wouldn't budge.

New global trade rules have also allowed big corporations to patent crop varieties 
and, in effect, the genes
of plants, animals and human beings. This has grave implications both for food 
security and the accessibility
of medicines. But the corporations argue that this new protectionism is essential to 
stimulate both innovation
and investment. There are many ways in which this claim could be challenged, but I may 
have just stumbled
across a novel and fascinating one. It is contained within the histories of the very 
companies which now
insist that intellectual property rights are the pre-requisites of development.

In Industrialisation without National Patents, published in 1971, the economic 
historian Eric Schiff tells the
story of the emergence of some of Europe's biggest corporations. They came into being 
in Switzerland and the
Netherlands during the period (1850-1907 in Switzerland; 1869-1912 in the Netherlands) 
in which neither
country recognised patents. Some of them appear to owe their very existence to this 
exemption.

In the Netherlands the old patent laws were clumsy and poorly drafted. The government 
decided they were
unreformable, and simply scrapped them. In Switzerland, the confederation developed 
without them, and decided
to keep it that way. Contrary to all current predictions of what the impact of such 
abrogations would be, in
both nations they appear to have contributed to massive economic growth and innovation.

Switzerland was a poor country without many natural resources, whose economy was 
largely reliant on farming.
But in 1859 a small company based in Basel "borrowed" the aniline dying process which 
had been developed and
patented in Britain two years before. The company, later called Ciba, soon became a 
massive industrial
enterprise, swiftly outstripping competing firms in Britain. In 1995, Ciba merged with 
another Swiss firm,
Sandoz, to form the conglomerate Novartis. Novartis was one of the companies which 
successfully lobbied for
the European convention allowing companies to patent genes. It was also one of the 
firms which spent three
years fighting the South African government's attempt to buy cheap copies of its 
patented drugs, in order to
treat patients infected with HIV. Now, having merged with Zeneca to form an even 
bigger company, Syngenta, it
is extending its intellectual property rights still further by developing seeds which 
don't reproduce.

But Switzerland's economic growth during this period did not rely solely upon 
purloining other nations'
patented processes. Industrial innovation flourished, especially in food technology. 
No country, Schiff notes,
has ever contributed "as many basic inventions in this field as did Switzerland during 
her patentless period".
In 1875, for example, Daniel Peter invented milk chocolate. In 1879, Rudolf Lindt 
developed chocolat fondant.
In 1886, Julius Maggi invented powdered soup. A few years later he developed stock 
cubes. All these men
founded companies which still bear their names today. But the biggest food firm to 
emerge in this period took
root in 1865, when Henri Nestle developed a cereal for children.

In 1998, the International Chamber of Commerce lobbied the World Trade Organisation in 
support of corporate
rights over plants, animals and genes. It argued that "the protection of intellectual 
property" is "essential
for economic growth". Its chairman at the time was Helmut Maucher, who was also the 
chief executive of Nestle,
the company which arose and conquered the world without any intellectual property 
protection whatever.

In the Netherlands too, the absence of patents appears to have done little to arrest 
the growth of
manufacturing industry. In the early 1870s, two companies, Jurgens and Van den Bergh, 
commandeered a patented
French recipe and started manufacturing a brand new product called margarine. They 
soon became Europe's
biggest producers. Jurgens and Van den Bergh later merged with a British company to 
form the conglomerate
Unilever. Like Novartis and Nestle, Unilever is one of the most influential members of 
Europabio, the lobby
group now pressing for ever stricter patent protections for big corporations.

In the 1890s, Gerard Philips, unhampered by intellectual property laws, started 
manufacturing the incandesent
lamps developed by Thomas Edison in the United States. The absence of patent 
protection did not prevent him
either from holding off European competition or from developing several important new 
designs. But, in its
recent submission to the European Commission's consultation on patent rights, Philips 
insists that
intellectual property "is one of its key business tools".

Switzerland and the Netherlands eventually adopted patent laws in response to threats 
from other
industrialised nations. This, Schiff argues, was a political decision, not an economic 
one. It is, he notes,
"difficult to avoid the impression" that the absence of patent laws "furthered, rather 
than hampered
development". The two countries relied for their growth not upon exclusive rights but 
upon high educational
standards and technical ability.

These examples do not necessarily suggest that the abandonment of patent protection is 
an essential
precondition for development. But they do indicate that it can, in the right 
circumstances, be an effective
tool. This tool has been denied to poor nations, partly as a result of energetic 
lobbying by the very
companies which once made use of it.

Those who have challenged the inequalities of global trade have pointed to the fact 
that some of the world's
richest nations once used tariff barriers to devastating effect in building their 
economies. But the history
of patent protection suggests that that is not the only means by which the rich 
nations have raised the
drawbridge after entering the castle. When it suits the rich countries to impose free 
trade, they do so. When
it suits them to impose protectionism, they argue that this is the only path to 
development. But woe betide
the poor nation which seeks to apply the lessons of the past.

www.monbiot.com


Reply via email to