< http://www.hinduonnet.com/fline/fl1910/19101210.htm>
Growing exports, falling incomes
Jayati Ghosh

The latest Trade and Development Report from UNCTAD discusses why
increasing manufacturing exports may not be good enough for developing
countries' income growth.

DIVERSIFICATION of production structures and exports has traditionally
been seen as the key to fast development. Indeed, this has been taken so
much for granted that for much of the past half century the debate among
economists has been not so much about the desirability of this goal, but
of the policies required to achieve it. Marketist neoliberal economists
have argued that the best way is through liberalisation, deregulation and
greater integration of domestic markets with world markets, while
structuralist economists have emphasised the need for domestic structural
change assisted by trade restrictions that promote industrialisation.

In either case, the need to enter new forms of production, to diversify
away from traditional exports, and ideally to enter high-value
manufacturing production, has been taken for granted. But some new
research (discussed in the latest Trade and Development Report (TDR)
produced by the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development
(UNCTAD)) suggests that even this may not be as unproblematic as it
appears, and that product diversification in itself ensures neither more
dynamic exports nor even higher incomes from such activities.

On the face of it, developing countries as a group have achieved an
impressive degree of production diversification over the past two
decades, and this has also been reflected in export performance. From the
early 1980s, merchandise exports from developing countries have been
growing much faster (at 11.3 per cent per annum) than the world average
of 8.4 per cent.

More significantly, there has been a big shift in developing country
exports away from primary commodities (whose share has fallen from 51 per
cent in 1980 to 19 per cent in 1998) and towards manufactured goods,
which now account for more than 80 per cent of their exports. What seems
most promising is that the largest increase has been in the exports of
manufactures with high skill and technology intensity, whose share jumped
from 12 per cent of total developing country exports in 1980 to 31 per
cent in 1998.

Despite all these apparently positive signs, however, there is no
evidence of improved income shares for developing country exporters. In
fact, the Trade and Development Report 2002 argues that "while the share
of developing countries in world manufacturing exports, including those
of rapidly growing high-tech products, has been expanding rapidly, the
income earned from such activities does not appear to share in this
dynamism".

This becomes apparent from a comparison of shares in exports and
value-added in world manufacturing. While developing countries as a group
more than doubled their share of world manufacturing exports from 10.6
per cent in 1980 to 26.5 per cent in 1998, their share of manufacturing
value-added increased by less than half, from 16.6 per cent to 23.8 per
cent. By contrast, developed countries experienced a substantial decline
in the share of world manufacturing exports, from 82.3 per cent to 70.9
per cent. But at the same time their share of world manufacturing
value-added actually increased, from 64.5 per cent to 73.3 per cent.

This means that developed countries moved up the value chain much faster,
and that developing country exporters have continued to face problems in
translating export volume growth into income growth. The problem is
compounded by the fact that developing countries remain net importers of
manufactured goods, indeed they have become more so. Imports of
manufactured goods have continuously outpaced exports of such goods for
developing countries, unlike developed countries. Meanwhile,
manufacturing exports have consistently exceeded the value of
manufacturing value-added, once again the opposite of developed
countries.

HOW can we square this with the evidence on product diversification and
entry into dynamic exporting sectors that was mentioned above? After all,
developing countries have been increasingly active traders in what are
seen as the most dynamic sectors of the world economy: computers and
office equipment; telecommunications, audio and video equipment; and
semiconductors.

But the point is that international production and trade in these sectors
exhibit a relatively new pattern, whereby there is a "vertical
disintegration of production" across locations. That is, different parts
of a production process are dispersed across different geographical
locations, and goods travel across several such locations over the entire
process before reaching final consumers. This is also true of the other
major dynamic export sector: textiles and clothing.

In such sectors, the total value of recorded trade far exceeds the
value-added. But by and large most developing countries are confined to
the labour-intensive processes in this overall production. This means it
is misleading to look simply at the "high-tech" nature of the final
product. Many of these processes involve essentially low-skilled
assembly-type operations, in which developing-country locations compete
with one another by virtue of their cheap labour rather than any other
criterion. This also means that much of the value-added that does accrue
in this process is garnered by the multinational corporations that are
organising the production in this way, rather than by the economies that
are hosting them.

But there are other factors, apart from this firm-based separation and
geographical relocation of production, that may have played a role in
reducing returns to developing-country exporters. The most important of
these is the well-known fallacy of composition: the idea that what may be
possible and attractive for an individual exporting country may turn out
to have much-reduced or even opposite effects when many countries try to
follow the same path.

This problem has been well established for a range of primary products
for some time now, but recent evidence suggests that it is also becoming
increasingly significant in world trade in manufactured goods. Thus, the
slowdown in exports from the East/Southeast Asian region from 1996, which
preceded the financial crisis, has been attributed to the same fallacy of
composition (Ghosh and Chandrasekhar, Crisis as Conquest: Learning from
East Asia, Orient Longman, 2001). As more and more countries in the
region entered the world market for office equipment and
semiconductor-related items, overproduction meant that prices crashed.
Only the People's Republic of China and the Philippines showed very high
rates of growth of exports in this category in that year. For all other
countries in the region, exports in this sector stagnated or declined.

The electronics sector typifies the problem of overproducing standardised
mass products with high import content, which have experienced both
higher volatility and steeper falls since 1995. But the same is true of a
range of manufactured goods exports from developing countries, which is
why there is evidence of a general terms of trade movement against
manufactures of the South.

Since more and more developing countries are turning to precisely this
strategy and basing their hopes on relocative foreign directr investment
(FDI) to achieve it, those already within the loop become vulnerable as
well. Thus the pattern of high export volume growth and relatively slow
or stagnant income growth has become marked even for middle income "super
traders" such as Hong Kong and Mexico.

In addition, developing countries increasingly try to offer fiscal and
trade-related concessions to would-be exporters, especially relocative
multinational corporations. When this is combined with other conditions
currently prevailing in the world economy, such as the increasingly
crowded markets for labour-intensive goods, weak aggregate demand growth
and protectionist tendencies in the advanced countries, it is not
surprising that increased export volumes in these sectors have not
translated into higher real revenues.

IRONICALLY, it turns out that some primary products actually performed
better in world trade markets than many of these manufactured goods. The
most "market-dynamic" agricultural commodities have outperformed most
manufactured goods in terms of export volumes and values. These include
silk, beverages, cereal preparations, preserved food, sugar preparations,
manufactured tobacco, chocolate, fish and seafood. However, apart from
silk (in which China has a 70 per cent market share), these other
commodities are dominated by developed-country producers. Other primary
commodities, which are major exports of most developing countries, have
continued to languish.

The lesson from all this should not simply be to despair that nothing
seems to work in terms of export focus for developing countries. Rather,
this year's TDR serves as an important reminder that the current pattern
of export orientation, based either on traditional primary production or
relocative FDI-based exports relying on labour-intensive parts of wider
manufacturing processes, may not deliver sustained benefits in terms of
income growth.

The earlier, more successful, East Asian strategy was based on targeted
trade and industrial policies rather than on market-determined processes.
While such strategic trade policies may have become much more difficult
in the current context, what this report suggests is that some
alternative strategy must be found if developing countries are to
negotiate their integration into the world economy in a way that actually
furthers their development prospects.

Reply via email to