----- Original Message -----
From: "Louis Proyect" <[EMAIL PROTECTED]>
To: <PEN-L@SUS.CSUCHICO.EDU>
Sent: Monday, May 07, 2007 10:10 AM
Subject: Re: [PEN-L] More on Transition, Brenner, Allen, Productivity


LP: I suppose there is no need to explain why England's agrarian
productivity was on a par with the rest of "precapitalist" Europe in
1700 when supposedly the big leap forward took place at least 150  years
earlier.
_____________________________________

But clearly, England's productivity is above par with precapitalist
Europe and at par with the low countries where similar capitalist
agricultural relations existed.  As I stated previously, it would be
worthwhile to read Brenner's analysis of the development  of capitalism
in the low countries.  Nowhere in his writings do I find Brenner
referring to a big leap forward in England in the mid 16th century.
What Brenner does say in his initial paper "Agrarian Class Struggle and
Economic Development" is:

"That agricultural improvement was already having a significant effect
in English economic development by the end of the 17th century can be
seen in a number of ways:  most immediately in the the striking pattern
of relatively stable prices and (at least) maintenance of the population
of the latter part of the century... Thus although English population in
this period reacched the very high levels of the early 14th century
(which at that time had meant demographic crisis) there was not the same
sort of violent fluctuations in prices nor the crises of subsistence
which gripped France and much of the Continent in this period.  Nor was
there the marked demographic decline which came to dominate most of
Europe at this time, the famous Malthusian "phase B." In short, England
remained largely exempt fron the "general economic crisis of seventeenth
century" which sooner or later struck most of the Continent....

It seems moreover that agricultural improvement was at the root of
those....processes which... had allowed some 40 percent of the English
population to move out of agricultural employment by the end of the 17th
century..."

Several things are of note here:  first Brenner is specifically
attacking and refuting the demographic determinism that sought to
substitute population pressures for class analysis, and analysis of
class struggle, in the conditions of society in general and agricultural
production in partiuclar.  Secondly, the increase in productivity takes
root in the changing of class relations in the 16th century, but only
makes itself manifest as sustainable, as sustainability at the end of
the century.   Thirdly, this increased productivity is measured
"internally," so to speak, not in some sort of gross comparison to other
countries, but in its ability to support release of labor from
agriculture, again to sustain specific social relations.
_________________

In response to Dough Henwood's query:  Brenner really begins with
question of demographic determinism, the role of population pressures in
the breakdown/emergence of feudalism and the transition to capitalism,
and he shows that demographics themselves, abstracted from actual class
relations of production cannot account for breakdown, emergence,
transition.  Those features are products of class struggle.  For
Brenner, the class struggle rather than simple developments in the
forces of production determines the varied, and specific, developments
in the countries of the dying medieval and emerging modern era.

In so doing, Brenner is attempting to locate, and ground specifically,
Marx's birthmark of capitalism --"separation of the means of production
from the means of labor"--   in the relations of agricutural production
and producers.

Now the Brenner debate originally was a debate with the Malthusian and
neo-Malthusian orthodoxy. It burst forward into a blazing debate within
the left after the 1977 publication in NLR of his "The Origins of
Capitalist Development: a Critique of Neo-Smithian Marxism," in which he
takes on Wallerstein, Frank, Sweezy etc. about the specificty of the
origin of capitalism, and capitalist social relations-- arguing that
that entire line of analysis displaces class relations from economic
analyses of development and underdevelopment.  Frank and Wallerstein
after him essentially argue that the origin of capitalist development in
England, France, in Europe is in the underdevelopment of other
countries.  Accumulation then is not a a class process, but a country,
region world process, and it is not a process of reproduction, but of
transfer. Accordingly capitalism can be seen to be everything everywhere
all the time-- anywhere trade exists, or expropriation of surplus,
that's capitalism.

The specific nature of capitalist accumulation, the need for expanding
reproduction not of the means of production as the means of production,
but as capital, to aggrandize more, not just labor, but wage-labor; the
specific capitalist transformation of the markets from activities and
areas for the exchange of goods to the arena for the realization of
value-- drops away-- and we get capitalism that supposedly was born by
transferring gold, or pearls, or silver, or sugar from new to old
worlds.

How exactly this wealth could transform a society based on subsistence
where the population is chained to peasant-based agriculture is never
explained.  How the simple transfer of wealth can make agriculture so
productive that significant portions of the population can be
"productively" dispossessed into the  cities without triggering the
Malthusian demographic crisis is never explained as  class drops out of
the analysis.

 (And with all respect to Eric F William, author of one of the truly
great, mistaken works of historical analysis, the slave traders of
Liverpool did not become the industrialists of Manchester, nor did they
become the bankrollers  of the industrialists of Manchester ).

Certainly more than a few Marxists saw in Brenner's analysis a pretty
strong critique of current day "third worldism," and the battle was on.

Reply via email to