Central banks should not rescue fools
By Martin Wolf
Financial Times
August 28 2007

Sometimes a picture is worth a thousand words. The one last Wednesday
showing Christopher Dodd, chairman of the US senate’s banking committee,
flanked by Hank Paulson, Treasury secretary, and Ben Bernanke, governor of
the Federal Reserve, was such a picture. This showed Mr Bernanke as a
performer in a political circus. Mr Dodd even announced Mr Bernanke’s
policies: the latter had, said Mr Dodd, told him he would use “all the
tools” at his disposal to contain market turmoil and prevent it from
damaging the economy. The Fed has its orders: save Main Street and rescue
Wall Street.

Such panic-driven politicisation is almost certain to lead to both
overreaction and the creation of bad precedents. What then would be the
right response to this latest scrape that supposedly sophisticated financial
markets have fallen into?

Policymakers must distinguish two objectives: the first is macroeconomic
stability; the second is a sound financial system. These are not the same
thing. Policymakers must not only distinguish these objectives, but be seen
to do so. The Federal Reserve failed to do this when it issued statements,
on prospects for the economy and on emergency lending, on August 17. This
unavoidably – and undesirably – confused the two goals.

The statement on the economy was also premature. Everybody knows that the
Fed’s job is to stabilise the economy and prevent deflation. Everybody
knows, too, that the Fed will investigate the economic implications of the
crisis in the credit markets at the next meeting of the open market
committee. If prospects seem significantly worse, the Fed will, presumably,
cut rates. But now a cut looks pre-announced. Monetary policy should not be
made “on the hoof” in this way, except in the direst of circumstances.

This brings one to the second objective: ensuring the functioning of the
financial system. The question is how to help the system without encouraging
even more bad behaviour. This is such an important question because the
system has been so crisis-prone, as Larry Summers points out (“This is where
Fannie and Freddie step in”, August 27). I think of the underlying game as
“seek the sucker”: sucker number one is persuaded to borrow too much; sucker
number two is sold the debt created by lending to sucker number one; sucker
number three is the taxpayer who rescues the players who became rich from
lending to sucker number one and selling to sucker number two.

The most recent game is a particularly creative one. This time the geniuses
seem to have created a “lemons crisis”, after the celebrated paper by the
Nobel laureate George Akerlof*. Consider the market in used cars. Suppose
buyers cannot tell the difference between good cars and bad ones (lemons).
They will then offer only an average price for cars. Sellers will withdraw
any good cars from the market. This may continue until the market disappears
entirely.

What is driving this is “asymmetric information”: buyers believe sellers
know more about the quality of what they are selling than they themselves
do. This seems to be precisely what has now happened to trading in certain
classes of security. The crisis is focused in markets in structured credits
and associated derivatives. The cause seems to be rampant uncertainty.
Investors have learnt from what happened to US subprime mortgages that these
securities may be “weapons of financial mass destruction”, as Warren Buffett
warned. With the suckers fled, the markets have frozen. The people who
created this kind of stuff distrust both the instruments and their
counterparties. This, in turn, has led to the panic purchases of US Treasury
bills shown in the chart.

Yet the difficulty is not a lack of general liquidity. Central banks have
provided it freely. Some would argue that, in the case of the Fed, with its
half a percentage point cut in the discount rate, provision has been too
cheap and, in the case of the European Central Bank, provision has been too
free. Nor is this a general crisis in lending. Credit spreads have not
exploded for corporate or emerging market debt. They have merely become less
unreasonable. Market volatility has increased, but not to extraordinary
levels.

This then is a crisis in the market for financial lemons. So what should the
authorities do about that? My answer is “nothing”. They should, of course,
stand ready to provide liquidity to the market, at a penal rate (since
insurance should never be free), and also to adjust interest rates to
overall macroeconomic conditions. But they should not promote the survival
of a market in lemons.

This is why I disagree with the suggestion by Willem Buiter and Anne Sibert,
in the FT’s Economists’ Forum, that central banks should now become
market-makers of last resort. Central banks could do this only if someone
regulated not just the soundness of financial institutions (as now) but also
the properties of all the products these institutions invent. Otherwise, the
central banks might be forced to buy what they do not understand. They
would, instead, be offering a commitment to be buyers of last resort in a
market for lemons, thereby subsidising the creation of a market in junk. If
central banks were to regulate products, however, they would be running the
financial institutions. Ours would become a quasi-nationalised financial
system.

Now suppose central banks did, instead, refuse to intervene in the afflicted
markets. What would happen? Sellers must turn lemons into apples, pears,
strawberries and all the rest. In other words, they must demonstrate the
precise properties of what they are trying to offload. Where they cannot do
this, they may have to hold securities to maturity. Meanwhile, vulture funds
would invest in obtaining requisite knowledge. Losses will also have to be
written off. How much of the market in securitised lending would survive
this shake-out, I have no idea. But I do not care either. That is for the
players to decide, after they realise the consequences of getting it wrong.

Burned children fear the fire. If some of the biggest and most powerful
institutions in the world have been playing with fire, they need to feel the
burns. It is not the central banks’ job to rescue them by creating a market
in the incomprehensible. It is their job to preserve the banking system and
the health of the economy. Neither seems now to be in grave danger.

Decisions made in panic are almost always bad ones. Stick to principles and
let the masters of the financial system sort themselves out. They are paid
enough to do so, after all.

* The Market for “Lemons”, Quarterly Journal of Economics 1970

Reply via email to