Re: financial leverage

2003-10-31 Thread alypius skinner
 Short-term I would lose about 1-2% percent on the
 borrowed fund but in the long-term I would gain 1-2%
 when I lock in a long-term bond that has a coupon rate
 that is above the borrowed rate.  I don't see how bond
 would be a loser if interest rates goes higher since I
 will locking in a bond that yield a higher coupon rate
 then the borrowed rate.

If you plan to resell your bonds before maturity, the rising rates will
cause the resell value to go down accordingly.  If you plan to hold the
bonds to maturity, the interest you receive will probably be a net loss in
constant (inflation-adjusted) dollars, because interest rates do not rise
for no reason.  If rates on long term bonds rise, it will probably be in
large part because of rising inflation.  With our government increasing the
money supply to stimulate the economy and the value of the dollar vis a vis
other currencies in a sustained downward trend, both higher inflation and
higher interest rates are likely in the future.

~Alypius


Re: MVT and policy portfolios

2003-10-18 Thread alypius skinner
- Original Message -
From: fabio guillermo rojas [EMAIL PROTECTED]
To: alypius skinner [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Cc: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Sent: Saturday, October 18, 2003 11:47 AM
Subject: MVT and policy portfolios



   - people spend an inordinate time satisfying extreme voters, even
after
   winning a party nomination
  
   They're trying to put together a winning coalition by targeting a
variety
  of market segments.  You don't see General Motors or Altria/Philip
Morris
  targeting just the median car buyer or median cigarette smoker.
 
  ~Alypius

 Well, this is not a prediction of the median voter theorem. If you have N
 policies, the MVT would predict that the candidate would gravitate to the
 center of each policy. What you are suggesting is that the candidate would
 go to the extreme position for each policy, as defined by some
 subpopulation who cares about the issue.

 Fabio


Yes, special interests--sometimes including  the opinions of the rulers' own
social class--are often more influential than the median voter preference.
Furthermore, if a politician can put together a winning coalition--let's say
one that reliably gives him about 55% of his constituents' votes-- he can
usually ignore those market segments who are not part of his winning
coalition.  Sometimes we also see politicians neglecting part of their
coalition--such as Democrats neglecting blacks or Republicans neglecting
religious social conservatives--because, in a non-parliamentary system, they
can be safely taken for granted.  Thus, both President Bushes courted the
homosexual lobby, because they knew that the Democrats would not nominate
anyone  the social conservatives, however unhappy, could vote for.   (And
I'm fairly sure, if David Duke could win the Democratic Party's presidential
nomination, that he would carry the black vote in the general election.)
The Democrats are enthralled to a coalition of special interests which would
never allow someone acceptable to social conservatives to be nominated,
just as the Republican coalition would never allow anyone to be nominated
who was not acceptable to big business interests.  As another example,
notice how both Democrats and Republicans in Presidential elections always
nominate someone whose views on abortion are to the left and the right
respectively of the median voter, who, according to polls, prefers more
restrictions than the Democratic nominee will endorse and fewer restrictions
than the Republican nominee is willing to allow.  So the two parties, rather
than competing for the median voter, will  compete for those market segments
which would not drive away--or be driven away by--the other segments that
make up the core of *either* party's coalitions.  In a close election, this
often means that both sides compete intensely for that segment of likely
voters which is least informed, least consistent in its opinions, and most
politically clueless.  These people are often the kingmakers in
democracies.

Related to this is the question of whether there really is a median voter.
Let's take 10 issues--abortion, gun control, gay rights, trade policy, tax
rates, immigration, middle east policy, racial preferences, CO2/global
warming policy, and SDI/star wars missile defense.  What percentage of
the electorate is in the middle quintile (if we could quantify these issues)
on all 10?

 There also is the weight that each voter gives to each issue.  For
significant numbers of voters, abortion or support for Israel or support for
Kyoto/the environment or gay rights positions or gun control or
affirmative action policies will outweigh all other considerations.  Much
more often, even  though one is not dealing with a true single issue
voter, taking the right or wrong position on one issue may outweigh
one's position on 2, 3, or more other issues that are a lower priority for a
given voter.  There is also the question of how committed an office seeker
seems to be to a given issue.  For example, among Republicans we often see
the following tightrope being walked:  the office seeker tries to be
sufficiently supportive of traditional values that he endears himself to the
social conservatives in his party--especially in the primaries--but not so
supportive that socially liberal Republicans in the primaries (or
independents in the general election) will think that he really means it.

On a weighted list of issues, there may not be enough median voters to
bother with.   Putting together a winning coalition of market segments is
probably a surer path to victory.

~Alypius


Re: Median Voter Theorem, Part Deux

2003-10-17 Thread alypius skinner
 - people spend an inordinate time satisfying extreme voters, even after
 winning a party nomination

 They're trying to put together a winning coalition by targeting a variety
of market segments.  You don't see General Motors or Altria/Philip Morris
targeting just the median car buyer or median cigarette smoker.

~Alypius

PS--Fabio, this reply may not appear on the list.  I think Bryan has been
diverting my posts to some cyberfile 13.  The last half dozen or so times I
attempted to post, nothing ever appeared on the list, so I've pretty much
given up trying.  But I can still read everyone else's messages, so you can
reply to me on the list if you wish to.


Re: immigration: net gain or net drain?

2003-09-18 Thread alypius skinner

 Of course, if the losses from immigration restrictions are greater than
 you might think, the gains of weaker restrictions are also greater than
 you would think.  When you double the number of immigrants, you will be
 admitting a lot of people with a lot of surplus, not just marginal
 immigrants.


I'd like for you or someone to attempt a crude, ball park estimate for me of
the net gains from immigration in a specific case.
Less than 100 years ago, Kosovo was a mostly Serbian region of the Federal
Republic of Yugoslavia.  Then high levels of legal and illegal immigration
from neighboring Albania made it a mostly Albanian region.  How much better
off is Yugoslavia today as a result of past immigration than it would have
been if it had tightly restricted immigration? How much better off are the
few remaining Serbs who have not been driven out of Kosovo or killed than
they would have been if foreign immigration had been tightly restricted for
the last 100 years? (Of course, one can always argue that the immigrants
benefited, but how did the receiving party benefit? How was it in their
best interest to open the doors?)

Another example is Palestine.  Now I know the natives of Palestine had no
control over immigration policies in the late 19th and early 20th centuries;
that was a British decision.  But how much better off is the *average*
Palestinian--most of whom live in the West Bank and Gaza strip--as a result
of Jewish immigration?  And since immigration makes their lives so much
better, why is there so much unrest?

A third example: American immigration to the Mexican state of Texas
certainly benefited the immigrants; but as a result, half of Mexico was, a
generation later, off limits to most Mexican citizens until today.  How much
did the average member of the receiving party benefit from allowing large
scale Anglo immigration to Texas?

If current immigration policies in the United States give the Democrats a
permanent lock on the White House beginning in 2008, and eventually a lock
on Congress as well, how much better off will the receiving party and their
posterity be as a result? In California, would Cruz Bustamante be a
frontrunner in the special election for governor in the absence of large
scale immigration from Mexico?

~Alypius


Re: Economics and E.T.s

2003-09-18 Thread alypius skinner
 Well, we have reaches a level of life exactly equal to our own, and we
 haven't colonized anything beyond our planet.  The tehnology is
 probably there, but the costs are high and the benefits are unclear.
 The same maybe true 200 years from now.

(Gee, I hope this is on topic!) Anyway, a physicist said one time that any
extraterrestrial visitors probably would have to live in our little corner
of the Milky Way.  Since  the speed of light functions as an absolute speed
limit, the length of time necessary for distant interplanetary travel poses
logistic challenges that are probably insurmountable with any possible
technology.


 Also, think about this: On our own planet, there are thousands, maybe
 millions of different forms of life, from humans to peat moss to
 bacteria.  The overwhelming majority of species on earth are things
 like insects and bacteria -- not humans.  If there were life elsewhere
 in the universe, isn't there a higher probability that's it's on the
 level of bacteria rather than humans?


Oh, absolutely.  Even if life is common, intelligent life probably isn't.
It took life on earth many hundreds of millions of years to evolve an
intelligent life form, and even then it was unlikely.  If some disaster had
not wiped out the dinosaurs, there might never have evolved a niche for
primates.  And if the Pleistocene ice age had not begun about 3 million
years ago when the isthmus of Panama moved into its present position (which
altered the oceans' thermohaline circulation in important ways) and about
the time that  early hominids evolved in Africa, Homo sapiens, or even
erectus, might never have evolved. Our primate ancestors might have remained
in the rain forest without the drying and cooling effects of the ice age.
And even primates that adapt to savannah do not necessarily become
intelligent--just look at baboons.  And even if early Homo had evolved, in
the absence of our periodic glacial episodes, his IQ probably never would
have risen to a high enough level to create industrial civilization.  IQ,
brain size, cranial size, and the latitude at which a population probably
lived during the last glacial era (circa 120,000 BC to c. 11,000 BC) are all
correlated.  And even now either a return to ice age conditions or, in the
case of continued interglacial conditions, a gradual decline in intelligence
due to unfavorable differential fertility trends, might be sufficient to end
civilization.

Furthermore, it is not only intelligence that makes technological
civilization possible, but prehensile thumbs and bipedalism.  It all has to
evolve as a package.

When the first humans came to the western hemisphere, why didn't they find
another intelligent species already here, having evolved independently?
Because the chance of intelligent life evolving anywhere, at any time, is
remote.

Intelligent species don't even appear to be very successful.  If you look at
every species of ape but man, they are marginal species.  Their sparse
populations eke out an existence in specialized environmental niches and do
not appear to be very adaptable.  Even Homo sapiens was almost extinguished
following the eruption of a super-volcano about 72,000 BC.  It was only with
the invention of agriculture at the beginning of this interglacial that our
numbers multiplied enough to give our species the (misleading?) appearance
of biological security.

~Alypius


Re: HEAVEN'S DOOR AFTER A YEAR - George J. Borjas

2003-09-05 Thread alypius skinner
 Perhaps even more fundamentally, if the Americans who pay the immigrants
 didn't benefit by paying the immigrants the Americans wouldn't pay them.
 Obviously both parties--American and immigrant--benefit from the exchange
of money for
 labor.


Sure *some* Americans benefit--just like some Americans would benefit from
invading Communist China, as I pointed out before.  But do Americans in the
aggregate or on average benefit? Where does this benefit show up in the
economic stats?  Cuban-American immigrant Borjas says we benefit to the tune
of 10 billion dollars in an economy of 10 thousand billion--that's a .001%
benefit to the average US citizen, and it may well be canceled out or worse
by net negative externalities, which are much easier to enumerate than
positive externalities, perhaps because there are more of them.

~Alypius Skinner


immigration's effect on per capita GDP

2003-09-04 Thread alypius skinner
Robert Book wrote:

Do any of these studies take into account the effect of immigrants on
demand?  It would see these people have to eat.


Judging from the article below (Note carefully what Professor Borjas is
saying here. Sure, those immigrants who work do raise overall GDP. But the
bulk of that increase goes to the immigrants themselves, in the form of
wages. The benefit to native-born Americans, after everything is taken into
account, is infinitesimally small.), the effect of immigrants on demand
does appear to be taken into account.

What I want to know is whether the labor economists' studies take into
account the cost of the immigrants' crime rates (which are above the native
born average), their welfare dependency (again, above the national average),
and the higher transaction costs and ethnic friction and rivalry that comes
from high rates of immigration.  Most immigrants also come from cultures
that are more socialistic than the United States and, upon gaining
citizenship, vote heavily for the more socialistic of the two major parties.
(An exception here may be the relatively small East Asian/Oriental
population, which seems to straddle the fence, although the large Chinese
element seemed to lean toward the Democrats during Clinton's second term,
when he was perceived as China-friendly, even though it may have been at the
expense of US national security.  Miami's Cubans are also an exception,
perhaps because most Cuban refugees were from Cuba's more well-to-do classes
and also tend to be vehemently anti-Communist.  But exceptions are rare and
relatively small.)  It always struck me as odd that contemporary
libertarians (although not von Mises or the objectivist Ayn Rand) are the
strongest supporters of open borders, even though most of the people who
would enter under such an arrangement would be hostile to libertarian
political thought.

~Alypius Skinner


 http://www.vdare.com/pb/cc_times.htm

Contra Costa Times
December 4, 1999
Immigration policy stupid, evil and hurting Americans
By Peter Brimelow

IN AMERICA, WE have a two-party system, a Republican congressional staffer
is supposed to have told a visiting group of Russian legislators some years
ago.

There is the stupid party. And there is the evil party. I am proud to be a
member of the stupid party.

He added: Periodically, the two parties get together and do something that
is both stupid and evil. This is called -- bipartisanship.

Our current mass immigration policy is a classic example of this fatal
Washington bipartisanship. It is a stupid policy because there is absolutely
no reason for it -- in particular, Americans as a whole are no better off
economically because of mass immigration.

It is an evil policy because it second-guesses the American people, who have
shown through smaller families that they want to stabilize population size.

Unfortunately, our current immigration policy is consuming the environment
with urban sprawl, hurting the poor and minorities with intensified wage
competition, and ultimately threatening the American nation itself -- what
Abraham Lincoln called the last, best hope of earth -- with cultural and
linguistic fragmentation.

And, of course, the current mass immigration policy is bipartisan. Both
major party leaderships have tacitly agreed to keep the subject out of
politics. No single figure is more responsible for this than Sen. Spencer
Abraham, R-Mich., chairman of the Senate's Immigration Subcommittee.

Abraham was a key figure in sabotaging the most recent chance of reform, the
Smith-Simpson immigration bill, in 1996.

Ironically, this was a truly bipartisan measure, proposed by Republicans but
based on the work of the Jordan Commission, headed by the former black
liberal Democratic Congresswoman Barbara Jordan. She recommended almost
halving immigration, in part because of its impact on the poor.

The economic stupidity of current mass immigration policy is illustrated by
a brilliant new book, Heaven's Door: Immigration Policy and the American
Economy (Princeton University Press).

The author, Professor George Borjas of Harvard University's John F. Kennedy
School of Government, is widely regarded as the leading American immigration
economist. And he is an immigrant, arriving here penniless from Castro's
Cuba in 1962, when he was 12 years old.

Borjas has every reason to favor immigration. He writes movingly about his
own early experiences, and compassionately about the immigrant waves that
have followed him.

But, as a scholar, he recognizes what he calls accumulating evidence that
immigration has costs as well as benefits. My thinking on this issue has
changed substantially over the years, he admits.

Professor Borjas' devastating findings:

The current wave of mass immigration is not benefiting Americans overall.
All of the available estimates suggest the annual net gain is astoundingly
small, writes Professor Borjas, ... less than 0.1 percent of the Gross
Domestic Product. Roughly: less than