http://www.nottingham.ac.uk/law/TEXTHNB.HTM

Marine Insurance & War Risks
Howard N. Bennett, Lecturer in Law, University of Nottingham.

Paper delivered to the Nottingham University Centre for International
Defence Law Studies, May 26, 1993. Copyright reserved.

I. THE HISTORY & STRUCTURE OF WAR RISKS COVER

Understanding the structure of modern war risks cover may be assisted by an
appreciation of the history of the London insurance market, a market which
owes its most famous name and much of its shape to the consumption of
coffee.

***
In 1711, faced with serious National Debt problems, the government
established a company, the South Sea Company, to exploit a trading monopoly
conferred by charter in return for taking over #156;9 million of the debt.
Holders of government securities could exchange them for shares in the
company, which would receive reduced interest from the Treasury. The
shareholders would, however, benefit from an assuredly and increasingly
profitable investment in the South Sea Company. The flaw was that the
company's trading monopolies in reality were of little if any value,
consisting of dealings in inwrought iron with Spanish subjects, some vague
fishing rights and trade with Spanish South America, trade which never
blossomed. By way of comparison, one commentator has postulated a company
floated in London in 1943 "to develop British trade with Japan, to buy and
sell base metals with Germany, and to run a fleet of trawlers to Iceland".

Between 1711 and 1720, when the company took over another œ31 million of the
National Debt, every speculator's trick was employed to maintain the
apparent buoyancy of South Sea Company stock. By hook and principally by
crook, its œ100 stock rose to a height of œ1000. But the government
sponsored gambling on South Sea stock spread:

A perfect rage for speculation seized the entire country: fraudulent
companies of every conceivable description were floated, and however absurd
their ostensible purpose, they found people willing to invest in them ...
The crowning imposition of all ... was a scheme "for carrying on an
undertaking of great advantage, but nobody to know what it is." The
ingenious deviser of this idea asked for a capital of half a million, and
provided that every investor paying down two guineas per cent was to have
œ100 per annum for every œ100 so subscribed. Extravagant as this sounds, the
projector received 1000 subscriptions in a single morning, and decamped with
his 2000 guineas in the afternoon. The nominal value of all these "Bubbles"
as they were called, was œ500,000,000 - about twice the value of all the
land in England.

The bubble of deceit was pricked in 1720. The incorporated company was the
key to stock amenable to speculation and, at the time, incorporation was by
Royal Charter or by Act of Parliament. As the success of a petition for a
charter was dependant primarily upon the success of extensive tactical
bribery, a number of companies resorted instead to purchasing obsolete
charters from firms which had ceased trading. Although charters granted the
right to pursue a particular trade, such restrictions were then cavalierly
ignored. However, in March 1720, a House of Commons committee met to
investigate fraudulent schemes for the subscription of capital including the
acquisition of obsolete charters. The result of its report was the
preparation and passing in June 1720 of the Bubble Act, which, inter alia,
rendered illegal the raising of public subscriptions either in the absence
of authority of charter or Act of Parliament or under an obsolete charter.
The institution of proceedings against companies with a view to forfeiture
of their obsolete charters, combined with the adverse publicity engendered
by the passing of the Bubble Act, triggered a stock market crash of
unprecedented devastation in September 1720. In the course of that month,
shares in the South Sea Company itself fell from 780 to 180 per cent.
Although the company was too entwined with the nation's finances to be
permitted to fail totally, it never regained public confidence. It "dragged
out a struggling existence till 1807; and the faded splendours of its South
Sea House survived long enough to secure immortality in the Essays of Elia".

Throughout the eighteenth century and beyond "the shadow of 1720 retarded
the development of incorporated companies". New charters and authorising
Acts of Parliament for any type of company were few and far between. But the
Bubble Act itself had a more direct impact upon the evolution of the marine
insurance industry. At the time of preparation of the Act, charters were
being sought for a new marine insurance corporation and for an underwriting
company operating under the purchased obsolete Elizabethan charters of the
combined Mines Royal and Mineral and Battery Works. The petitions to
Parliament for charters proving unavailing, the promoters appealed unto
Caesar, "or rather (to be more accurate) they offered Caesar a bribe and
Caesar accepted it". An impecunious government had fallen into arrears of
œ600,000 on the Civil List. The Prime Minister, Robert Walpole, engineered a
scheme whereby the promoters of each of the petitions would pay the
Government œ300,000 for the award of charters granting exclusive rights to
corporate marine underwriting. The ensuing support of the King, George I,
led to the grant of exclusive charters to the Royal Exchange Assurance and
the London Assurance, the relevant provisions being included in the Bubble
Act. Permission for two charters was granted by s. 1, each of the
beneficiaries being required by s. 2 to pay œ300,000 "into the Receipt of
the Exchequer ... for the Use of the King's Majesty, in order to discharge
the Debts and Expenses of his Civil Government". The crucial provision,
however, was s. 12 which prohibited ... all other Corporations or Bodies
Politick, before this time erected or established, or hereafter to be
erected or established, whether such Corporations or Bodies Politick, or any
of them, be sole or aggregate, and all such Societies and Partnerships as
now are, or hereafter shall or may be entered into by any Person or Persons,
for assuring Ships or Merchandises at Sea ... from entering into any
contract of marine insurance. However, s. 12 also declared that: ... any
private Person or Persons shall be at Liberty to write or underwrite any
Policies, or engage himself or herself in any Assurances of [marine
insurance] as fully and beneficially as if this Act had not been made, so as
the same be not upon the Account or Risque of a Corporation or Body
Politick, or upon the Account or Risque of Persons acting in a Society or
Partnership for that Purpose ...

At face value, therefore, the impact of the Bubble Act was threefold. First,
individual underwriting via brokers remained unfettered. Secondly,
competition was introduced in the form of the Royal Exchange Assurance and
the London Assurance. Thirdly, the marine insurance market was closed
absolutely except to individual underwriters and the two corporations. The
reality, however, was that individual underwriting received an almost total
monopoly. The stock market collapse of 1720 led to the corporations
defaulting on their œ300,000 statutory debts/bribes. 50% remissions enabled
them to survive, but they made little impact on the marine market. They were
not competitive; they imposed a limit of œ10,000 on the sum assured; they
were reluctant to accept risks attached to voyages between two overseas
ports (known as "cross risks") or to cover neutral ships against the war
risk of capture in enemy ports; they tended to impose restrictive terms and
conditions. Individual underwriters helped themselves to over 90% of the
marine market.

What, however, led to the marine market adopting Lloyd's as its centre?
Edward Lloyd established a maritime connection but not an underwriting
tradition. The 1730s and 1740s saw an export boom and a correlative growth
in the demand for marine insurance, monopolised, in the wake of the Bubble
Act, by individual underwriters. A leading criticism of the marine market
prior to 1720 had been its scattered nature. Commercial expedience dictated
concentration and Lloyd's became the centre, probably because of the
development of the coffee house by its proprietors as a centre for shipping
intelligence, exemplified by the establishment in the 1720s of the newspaper
Lloyd's List, which has been published continuously ever since and survives
today as the Lloyd's List and Shipping Gazette.

The Bubble Act had one further consequence. Shipowners dissatisfied with the
coverage and premium rates available at Lloyd's came together to constitute
unincorporated associations in the form of mutual assurance associations or
clubs so as to divide their losses between themselves. Although the Bubble
Act corporate duopoly on marine insurance business was repealed by the
Marine Insurance Act 1824, and the mid-nineteenth century saw the advent of
incorporation by registration and limited liability, both Lloyd's and the
associations survived the advent of fresh competition, although it was
established in 1875 that associations with more than twenty members were in
law companies requiring registration under the Companies Act 1862.

Association members do not pay premiums as such. A provisional contribution
is required from all association members. At the end of the association
year, the management calculates the liabilities for the previous twelve
months and makes a supplementary call or gives a refund as appropriate. The
association year commences and ends at noon February 20, Greenwich time. The
terms of coverage are determined by the association rules, which usually
provide, inter alia, for automatic renewal subject to termination by either
the member or the association in accordance with the procedure specified in
the rules.

The evolution of marine war risks coverage. In 1898 a small group of French
explorers under the command of Captain Jean Baptiste Marchand planted a
French flag in the village of Fashoda in the Sudan, then under the dominion
of Great Britain. The resulting diplomatic incident threatened to develop
into war between Britain and France until Marchand was ordered to withdraw.
The 1890s also saw considerable tension between Britain and the United
States. The watching marine underwriters were acutely aware of the power of
the navies of both France and the United States and a General Meeting of
Lloyd's, held on June 15, 1898, adopted for the first time a formal policy
of severing marine and war risks.

The agreements concluded in Lloyd's coffee house in the eighteenth century
for the assumption of risk in return for payment of a premium developed into
a standard form contract, the S.G. Policy. This policy developed on an
entirely ad hoc basis. It was "not a planned document and never during the
whole of its long life did it acquire this characteristic". As both law and
practice developed, risks were amended and exceptions developed. Moreover, a
complex way of presenting the cover evolved. Although the S.G. Policy itself
spelt out the cover granted in terms of a list of risks and exceptions, the
market also developed a series of standard clauses for particular types of
risk, e.g. for cargo, hulls or freight, for hulls for a period of time or
for a voyage. These more detailed statements of the cover would be appended
to the S.G. Policy. However, as both the S.G. Policy and the standard
clauses had the force merely of contractual terms, they were open to
amendment. Thus a particular risk might be crossed out, or an endorsement
slip might be attached to the policy or standard clauses by glue. The result
was hardly a model of clarity. As early as 1791, Buller J. remarked that "it
is sufficient to say that a policy of assurance has at all times been
considered in courts of law as an absurd and incoherent instrument".

***
The London market is not, however, the only war risks insurer. Towards the
end of the nineteenth century, the incidence of revolutions in South
American republics resulted in underwriters requiring enhanced premiums for
war risks cover for vessels operating in their waters. Consequently, 1898
saw the first mutual war risks association to provide cover at a lower cost.
The Government also has an important involvement stemming from the first
World War. In 1903, it appointed a committee under the chairmanship under
Austen Chamberlain to consider whether private enterprise could accommodate
marine insurance in time of war involving the United Kingdom. The committee
concluded that it could, but losses from the Russo-Japanese War, which
confirmed the efficacy of the torpedo, and the growing power of the German
navy, prompted a considerable retreat from war risks cover by both the
London market and the associations. Consequently, in 1913 a second committee
chaired by Huth Jackson drew up the scheme adopted by the Government on
August 5, 1914. With respect to hulls, the Government offered 80%
reinsurance cover, controlling by regulation both premium rates and
settlement of claims. As regards cargoes, the Government opened a State
Insurance Office offering primary insurance directly to merchants for
cargoes in British hulls at a uniform rate for all voyages. The Government,
however, did not appropriate to itself any monopoly and permitted the
private sector to compete for cargo cover.

The effect of the scheme was that the Government ended up covering poor
cargo risks, whilst Lloyd's and the companies undercut it with respect to
the better risks and made considerable profits. Since the purpose of the
scheme was not to enable the Government to participate in the insurance
market but to ensure the continuance of certain voyages, the result was not
without justification. But it led to abandonment of the uniform rate for
cargoes. Overall the Government made a profit of œ32 million on hulls
insurance against a œ7.5 million loss on cargo cover. The State Insurance
Office covered approximately 27% of the total value of war-time cargoes,
while the remaining œ6,000 million went to the private sector.

***



Reply via email to