RE: Products Liability and Innovation. Was: ...

2001-08-14 Thread Trei, Peter

It's been interesting seeing the back and forth on this,
especially since I kicked off this subthread.

I've found the anti-liability arguments quite persuasive.

Peter Trei




RE: Products Liability and Innovation. Was: ...

2001-08-14 Thread Trei, Peter

It's been interesting seeing the back and forth on this,
especially since I kicked off this subthread.

I've found the anti-liability arguments quite persuasive.

Peter Trei




RE: Products Liability and Innovation. Was: ...

2001-08-13 Thread Trei, Peter

 Black Unicorn[SMTP:[EMAIL PROTECTED]]
 
 From: Eugene Leitl [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 
  On Mon, 13 Aug 2001, Trei, Peter wrote:
 
   I hate to say this, but until software developers are held (at least
   at the corporate level) in some way liable for their failures, there
   will be little or no improvement in the situation.
 
  I think this is the wrong approach to the situation. Making people
 liable
  stifles innovation.
 
 I think 30+ years of active products liability jurisprudence might
 disagree
 with you.  Just in the automotive world and off the top of my head:
 Automatic
 Breaking Systems, designed failure points (crumple zones), 6mph bumpers,
 safety glass, shoulder belts, passive belts, air bags and a host of
 other
 technologies or innovations that may or may not have been developed but
 for
 litigation are most probably the result of strict liability in products
 liability cases.  The effect is to make safety profitable- or more
 accurately,
 to make unsafety unprofitable.  See generally Posner, Hallman and the
 Chicago
 School of Law and Economics, an entire movement in legal thought centered
 on
 the idea that you are very wrong about the effect of liability on
 innovation.
 
 Now less I be misinterpreted, misworded, misquoted and misunderstood by
 the
 various misanthropic types here:
 
 Do I think that software should have products liability attached to it?
 No.
 Do I think strict liability stifles innovation?  No.
 
[I hate to post something that makes it look as if I'm doing further 
BU bashing (which is not my intention), but:...]

When all you have is a hammer, everything looks like a nail. There are
other groups which can apply pressure than lawyers, courts and Men
with Guns.  Auditors and insurance companies come to mind. Schneier 
has noted how improvements in safe (as in a secure metal box)
technology was driven not by losses, not by customers, nor by lawsuits,
but rather by insurance requirements.

'You're running your ecommerce site on IIS? Ok, that's 10% extra on your
premiums. (This is already starting to happen).

Peter Trei
 






RE: Products Liability and Innovation. Was: ...

2001-08-13 Thread Trei, Peter

 Black Unicorn[SMTP:[EMAIL PROTECTED]]
 
 From: Eugene Leitl [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 
  On Mon, 13 Aug 2001, Trei, Peter wrote:
 
   I hate to say this, but until software developers are held (at least
   at the corporate level) in some way liable for their failures, there
   will be little or no improvement in the situation.
 
  I think this is the wrong approach to the situation. Making people
 liable
  stifles innovation.
 
 I think 30+ years of active products liability jurisprudence might
 disagree
 with you.  Just in the automotive world and off the top of my head:
 Automatic
 Breaking Systems, designed failure points (crumple zones), 6mph bumpers,
 safety glass, shoulder belts, passive belts, air bags and a host of
 other
 technologies or innovations that may or may not have been developed but
 for
 litigation are most probably the result of strict liability in products
 liability cases.  The effect is to make safety profitable- or more
 accurately,
 to make unsafety unprofitable.  See generally Posner, Hallman and the
 Chicago
 School of Law and Economics, an entire movement in legal thought centered
 on
 the idea that you are very wrong about the effect of liability on
 innovation.
 
 Now less I be misinterpreted, misworded, misquoted and misunderstood by
 the
 various misanthropic types here:
 
 Do I think that software should have products liability attached to it?
 No.
 Do I think strict liability stifles innovation?  No.
 
[I hate to post something that makes it look as if I'm doing further 
BU bashing (which is not my intention), but:...]

When all you have is a hammer, everything looks like a nail. There are
other groups which can apply pressure than lawyers, courts and Men
with Guns.  Auditors and insurance companies come to mind. Schneier 
has noted how improvements in safe (as in a secure metal box)
technology was driven not by losses, not by customers, nor by lawsuits,
but rather by insurance requirements.

'You're running your ecommerce site on IIS? Ok, that's 10% extra on your
premiums. (This is already starting to happen).

Peter Trei




Re: Products Liability and Innovation. Was: ...

2001-08-13 Thread Tim May

On Monday, August 13, 2001, at 10:14 AM, Trei, Peter wrote:

 [I hate to post something that makes it look as if I'm doing further
 BU bashing (which is not my intention), but:...]

 When all you have is a hammer, everything looks like a nail. There are
 other groups which can apply pressure than lawyers, courts and Men
 with Guns.  Auditors and insurance companies come to mind. Schneier
 has noted how improvements in safe (as in a secure metal box)
 technology was driven not by losses, not by customers, nor by lawsuits,
 but rather by insurance requirements.

 'You're running your ecommerce site on IIS? Ok, that's 10% extra on your
 premiums. (This is already starting to happen).

I've been pointing this out for many years, and did so at very early 
Cypherpunks meetings. If you say Schneier has noted this, I'll take 
your word.

The proper (moral, public choice theory, economically sound) approach is 
for those who want more security against theft to _pay_ for it. This 
through either their own choices, such as the choices I myself made for 
the type of gun safe I have in my house, or through the advice and 
pricing from their insurance companies. Holding a cheap safe maker 
strictly liable for loses when thieves use tin snips to cut through 
their safe is NOT the solution to the strong safe problem.

Unfortunately, as Declan also notes, the men with guns tend to go for 
do this or we will shoot you solutions. I count mandatory air bags and 
seat belt laws in this category.

Friedman's recent book Law's Order has many good economic analyses of 
tort situations, showing in nearly all cases that free market (mutually 
negotiated, noncoerced) produce more efficient results than non free 
market (imposed by government, coerced) solutions. Not surprising to 
libertarians, but useful to consider in the crypto context.

Bringing strict liability into the world of security and crypto would 
result in the usual market distortions. As an example, one might expect 
a recommended security standard, decided upon by industry committees 
(with government, probably the NSA, involvement). Like airbags, this 
would then be mandated to be included in all Net connectivity and 
related products. Vendors would scramble to meet this requirement. And 
probably some form of escrow (to help resolve disputes, for the 
children) would be mandated-in. And of course it probably couldn't be 
too strong.

Liability as currently interpreted can easily suppress innovation: 
Westinghouse froze the design of their boiling water nuclear reactors at 
roughly the 1960 level, except for minor changes in instrumentation and 
construction methods. The theory being that they had been given a kind 
of safe harbor on past designs (often done in conjunction with the 
Feds, as part of military reactor and AEC-led design projects) and that 
introducing innovations could alter the risk equation...even if it made 
the reactors better!

Similarly, innovations in automobile design are suppressed by liability 
concerns. A car maker who improves the layout of gas and brake pedals 
faces lawsuits over accidents caused by the changes. (cf. sudden 
acceleration, aka nitwit stepped on the wrong pedal.)

Peter Huber, in Galileo's Revenge, notes many cases where strict 
liability law has suppressed innovation. My favorite was the Florida 
case where a woman claimed a CAT scan made her lose her psychic powers. 
A jury awarded her $2 million in liability damages. (This also mixes in 
pseudoscience issues, but the liability laws are still implicated.)

And speaking of CAT scans, or NMR, PET, etc. scans, many hospitals now 
routinely order such scans in nearly all cases of minor injury. My 
father went in for an exam and the doctor recommended an NMR scan of 
some sort. My father asked why. The doctor: Don't worry, your insurance 
will cover most of it. My father: I asked why I need this. Doctor: 
We really recommend it.

To cut to the chase: Hospitals recommend such scans just in case. To 
cover their asses in a possible liability suit should some problem 
happen later in time. Is this due diligence? Well, NMR scans are not 
cheap, so the cost gets passed on in the usual ways. Is the average 
benefit worth it to the average patient who gets the we recommend it 
advice? Debatable. Except there _IS_ no debate about it, certainly not 
between the average patient and the average doctor.

BTW, my father said No to the doctor. The doctor argued, then gave up. 
Apparently he felt my father was exposing _him_ to strict liability. 
(Needless to say, a patient's waiver is challengeable in the usual 
ways: I didn't know what I was signing, The doctor didn't explain to 
me that the scan might have detected the tumor I now have, and the 
other usual Mommy State whines.)

Anyway, I think imposing FDA-type oversight and medical industry-type 
liability laws on the security and crypto industry would be a disaster.

Here's one of my articles from 1996 about this issue:


* To: 

Re: Products Liability and Innovation. Was: Re: Traceable Infrastructure is as vulnerable as traceable messages.

2001-08-13 Thread Ray Dillinger



On Mon, 13 Aug 2001, Black Unicorn wrote:

Do I think that software should have products liability attached to it?  No.
Do I think strict liability stifles innovation?  No.


I would actually like to make a smaller point here. Broadly I 
agree with BU, but I'd like to analyze it a little.

If software actually cost money per every unit produced, products 
liability would make more sense because then it could become part 
of the production costs.

However, given that copying bits is in fact free (copyright issues 
aside), adding a real per-unit expense has the potential to 
*dominate* the production cost.  Open-source software would become 
impossible to produce, because the whole open-source paradigm 
depends on copying bits being free.

I think MS would like nothing better than having products liability 
attached to software in general; it would solve a massive problem 
for them by putting open-source stuff out of production.  Even though 
the open-source stuff is better from a security standpoint, there 
is effectively no one who is making enough money from it to bear 
the costs of product liability. 

Some security consultants *do* bear the cost of product liability 
on software they install and configure; they are paid obscene amounts 
of money to take that risk and do the solid configurations that 
minimize it, and that is as should be.  The effect of product 
liability on the industry as a whole would be to remove the only 
secure products available (open-source products), making it 
effectively impossible for security consultants to do their jobs. 

Bear





More Liability Issues. Was: Re: Products Liability and Innovation.

2001-08-13 Thread Black Unicorn

- Original Message -
From: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Sent: Monday, August 13, 2001 12:34 PM
Subject: Re: Products Liability and Innovation.


 On 13 Aug 2001, at 9:42, Black Unicorn wrote:

 
  - Original Message -
  From: Eugene Leitl [EMAIL PROTECTED]
  To: Trei, Peter [EMAIL PROTECTED]
  Cc: [EMAIL PROTECTED]; Faustine [EMAIL PROTECTED];
[EMAIL PROTECTED]
  Sent: Monday, August 13, 2001 7:49 AM
  Subject: RE: Traceable Infrastructure is as vulnerable as traceable
messages.
 
   On Mon, 13 Aug 2001, Trei, Peter wrote:
  
I hate to say this, but until software developers are held (at least
at the corporate level) in some way liable for their failures, there
will be little or no improvement in the situation.
  
   I think this is the wrong approach to the situation. Making people
liable
   stifles innovation.
 
  I think 30+ years of active products liability jurisprudence might
disagree
  with you.  Just in the automotive world and off the top of my head:
Automatic
  Breaking Systems, designed failure points (crumple zones), 6mph bumpers,
  safety glass, shoulder belts, passive belts, air bags and a host of
other
  technologies or innovations that may or may not have been developed but
for
  litigation are most probably the result of strict liability in products
  liability cases.

 Well,  nobody can say with certainty exactly what would have
 happened in contrary-to-fact situations,  and litigation will
 probably encourage some innovations while discouraging others,

Points all taken.

 but it seems to me that litigation is highly unlikely to encourage
 innovation overall;  it seems to me that you are much more likely to
 lose a case if your product is hazardous in a way that
 distinguishes itself from the industry standard,  even if it's
 safer overall,  and in any case most potential innovations don't
 have anything to do with increasing safety.

Points also taken.

 In a more or less unregulated market,  consumers are
 free to value product safety as they choose.  Legislation which,
 say,  mandates air bags appears to assume that consumers tend
 to undervalue their own safety, a proposition I object to
 on philosophical grounds.  Liability works more or less the same
 way.

Think of it this way.  The proposition that the strict liability doctrine
makes is that certain activities are ultra hazardous.  One of these is
product design.  Strict liability- essentially the proposition that no showing
of negligence is required for the plaintiff to prevail- is generally thought
of as a mechanism to allocate the risk onto the market actor.  Economically
speaking this is intended to spur the innovator to self insure or to design
safety (safety from litigation anyhow) into the product, or at least have a
strong regard for it during the development process.  This in contrast to the
negligence standard- where the innovator has to have been shown to be
willfully negligent in design and therefore a good portion of the risk of the
product development is shifted back to the end user.

The theory is that if your goal is to reduce accidents and claims you allow
the market to incorporate that sort of risk (which in early innovation looks a
lot like an externality) into the innovation process.  Activities, it is
argued, which cannot be made sufficiently safe to be economically viable in
the market will not be undertaken because the market will not support such
activities.  Proponents of products liability point to this in justifying the
policy.  (Critics primarily point to the unfairness of assigning liability to
actors who have not acted negligently).

The showing for a plaintiff for products liability works something like this,
although admittedly this is very simplified:

1.  Plaintiff used the product according to directions.
2.  Plaintiff was injured.

That's pretty much it.  This is why safety is a big deal in automobile design
and why gun manufacturers have managed to duck major products liability issues
for the most part (misuse).   Since automobile design flaws of sufficient
magnitude can cause death and big money law suits, the market has incorporated
that component of the risk into the design cost of the product either ex ante
(during the design process) or ex post (by compensating the aggrieved
parties).  Costs are shifted onto the market when they are passed on (ex ante
or ex post) in the form of product cost.

This is the way that strict liability specifically, and the legal process in
general, tends to spur on innovation.

 The effect is to make safety profitable- or more accurately,
  to make unsafety unprofitable.

 Right.  Safety at all costs.  The cost of safety is already too
 high in most industries IMNSHO.

Well, I would argue that it is self adjusted by the market when we are talking
about products liability.  The market has put a price on safety by forcing
producers either to design safe, and limit ex post costs incurred by
litigation in favor of ex ante

Re: Products Liability and Innovation. Was: ...

2001-08-13 Thread Declan McCullagh

On Mon, Aug 13, 2001 at 01:14:10PM -0400, Trei, Peter wrote:
 other groups which can apply pressure than lawyers, courts and Men
 with Guns.  Auditors and insurance companies come to mind. Schneier 
 has noted how improvements in safe (as in a secure metal box)
 technology was driven not by losses, not by customers, nor by lawsuits,
 but rather by insurance requirements.

Minor note: I'd argue that insurance requirements, in a free market,
are in the end driven by losses or prospective losses.

-Declan



Re: Products Liability and Innovation.

2001-08-13 Thread georgemw

On 13 Aug 2001, at 9:42, Black Unicorn wrote:

 
 - Original Message -
 From: Eugene Leitl [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 To: Trei, Peter [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 Cc: [EMAIL PROTECTED]; Faustine [EMAIL PROTECTED]; [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 Sent: Monday, August 13, 2001 7:49 AM
 Subject: RE: Traceable Infrastructure is as vulnerable as traceable messages.
 
 
  On Mon, 13 Aug 2001, Trei, Peter wrote:
 
   I hate to say this, but until software developers are held (at least
   at the corporate level) in some way liable for their failures, there
   will be little or no improvement in the situation.
 
  I think this is the wrong approach to the situation. Making people liable
  stifles innovation.
 
 I think 30+ years of active products liability jurisprudence might disagree
 with you.  Just in the automotive world and off the top of my head:  Automatic
 Breaking Systems, designed failure points (crumple zones), 6mph bumpers,
 safety glass, shoulder belts, passive belts, air bags and a host of other
 technologies or innovations that may or may not have been developed but for
 litigation are most probably the result of strict liability in products
 liability cases.  

Well,  nobody can say with certainty exactly what would have 
happened in contrary-to-fact situations,  and litigation will
probably encourage some innovations while discouraging others,
but it seems to me that litigation is highly unlikely to encourage
innovation overall;  it seems to me that you are much more likely to
lose a case if your product is hazardous in a way that
distinguishes itself from the industry standard,  even if it's
safer overall,  and in any case most potential innovations don't
have anything to do with increasing safety. 
In a more or less unregulated market,  consumers are
free to value product safety as they choose.  Legislation which,
say,  mandates air bags appears to assume that consumers tend 
to undervalue their own safety, a proposition I object to
on philosophical grounds.  Liability works more or less the same 
way.
  
The effect is to make safety profitable- or more accurately,
 to make unsafety unprofitable. 

Right.  Safety at all costs.  The cost of safety is already too
high in most industries IMNSHO.

 See generally Posner, Hallman and the Chicago
 School of Law and Economics, an entire movement in legal thought centered on
 the idea that you are very wrong about the effect of liability on innovation.


An entire movement dedicated to the idea that Eugene is
very wrong?  Now I'm jealous,  I can be as wrong as him,
wronger even.   
 
 Now less I be misinterpreted, misworded, misquoted and misunderstood by the
 various misanthropic types here:
 
 Do I think that software should have products liability attached to it?  No.
 Do I think strict liability stifles innovation?  No.
 
 
On behalf of my fellow misanthropes,  thanks for the clarification.

George




Re: More Liability Issues. Was: Re: Products Liability and Innovation.

2001-08-13 Thread georgemw

On 13 Aug 2001, at 13:33, Black Unicorn wrote:


 The theory is that if your goal is to reduce accidents and claims you allow
 the market to incorporate that sort of risk (which in early innovation looks a
 lot like an externality) into the innovation process.  Activities, it is
 argued, which cannot be made sufficiently safe to be economically viable in
 the market will not be undertaken because the market will not support such
 activities.

Strikes me as being a circular argument, since  which activities
are sufficiently safe to be economically viable depends on
the size of the awards.   

  Proponents of products liability point to this in justifying the
 policy.  (Critics primarily point to the unfairness of assigning liability to
 actors who have not acted negligently).
 

Less misanthropic ones,  maybe.  We more misanthropic
critics are more likely to complain about being prevented from
engaging activities which we know damn well contain an
element of risk,  a risk we are willing to assume  because
in our judgement the benefits outweigh the risks.

 


 The showing for a plaintiff for products liability works something like this,
 although admittedly this is very simplified:
 
 1.  Plaintiff used the product according to directions.
 2.  Plaintiff was injured.
 
 That's pretty much it.  This is why safety is a big deal in automobile design
 and why gun manufacturers have managed to duck major products liability issues
 for the most part (misuse).   Since automobile design flaws of sufficient
 magnitude can cause death and big money law suits, the market has incorporated
 that component of the risk into the design cost of the product either ex ante
 (during the design process) or ex post (by compensating the aggrieved
 parties).  Costs are shifted onto the market when they are passed on (ex ante
 or ex post) in the form of product cost.


I had to read this about a dozen times before it made sense to me,
here's why:  there's an implicit assumption here that the damages
awarded in liability lawsuits acurately reflects the actual damages
suffered by the plaintiff.  The impression I get is that awards tend to
be orders of magnitude larger than they should be.
 
 This is the way that strict liability specifically, and the legal process in
 general, tends to spur on innovation.
 
  The effect is to make safety profitable- or more accurately,
   to make unsafety unprofitable.
 
  Right.  Safety at all costs.  The cost of safety is already too
  high in most industries IMNSHO.
 
 Well, I would argue that it is self adjusted by the market when we are talking
 about products liability.  The market has put a price on safety by forcing
 producers either to design safe, and limit ex post costs incurred by
 litigation in favor of ex ante costs, or minimize safety spending and catch
 the costs ex post.  Either way the costs are spread over the market and at
 least mostly linked to the actual effect of safety provisions in reducing
 harm/accidents/etc.  If a mini-van is too costly to make safe then it will
 not be produced.  That's the point of strict liability.  Force the actor to
 spend more time evaluating the wisdom of the action.  This often necessitates
 more RD and hence more innovation.  (Faster airbags, better seat belts, etc.)
 Saying the cost of safety is already too high is probably misplaced- at
 least in this isolated example of automotive manufacture.
 

I really don't think so.  I think we're at the point where around 10-50 
million dollars are spent per life saved,  and I don't think most 
people are worth anything near that.  I wouldn't even value my
own life that highly;  that is to say,  I probably wouldn't take certain 
death for 50 million, because I'm not sure what I'd spend the money 
on if I were dead, booze and hookers would do me no good,  but
I'd probably take a 10% chance of death for 5 million.

I suspect when you do the economical analysis,  if you
assume your damages awarded actually equal damages suffered,
with strict liability you end up with the same products on the
market and the same corporate profits as you would in a world 
where you assume no strict liability but that assume customers 
are able to correctly evaluate risks in their purchasing decisions,
the main difference being that with strict liability the costs are 
smeared over all consumers and without it the costs are 
born solely by the ones that suffer mishaps.  

George