Re: [EM] My summary of the recent discussion

2012-06-04 Thread James Gilmour
  I think Plurality can be claimed to be the ideal method for the 
  single-member districts of a two-party system, but then one should 
  maybe also think that third parties should not be allowed  to run, and 
  we should stick to the same two parties forever.
  
  I don't get it.
  
  of course, if there are only two candidates, there is no problem with 
  Plurality (because it's also a Majority).
  
  so how is Plurality so flawed if we accept that a two-party system is 
  fine and dandy?  if not Third parties, for Independents?
  
  what is the scenario with two parties where FPTP is so flawed?
 
 I think you already said it. If you want a system that allows 
 also third parties and independents take part in the 
 election, then Plurality is flawed. Only if you think that 
 third parties and independents should nor run, and there 
 should be only two parties, then Plurality is fine.

These contributions to this discussion take an extremely narrow view of 
representation of voters as it is clear this discussion is
not about a single-winner election (state governor, city mayor) but about 
electing representative assemblies like state legislatures
and city councils.  There can be major problems of representation if such 
representative assemblies are elected by FPTP from
single-member districts even when there are only two parties.

Even when the electorates of the single-member districts are as near equal as 
possible and even when the turnouts are near equal,
FPTP in single-member districts can deliver highly unrepresentative results if 
the support for the two parties is concentrated in
particular districts -  as it is in most electorates.  Thus party A that wins 
51 of the 100 seats in the assembly may win those
seats by small margins (say 550 votes to 450 votes) but party B that looses the 
election with 49 of the 100 seats may have won its
seats by overwhelming margins (say 700 votes to 300 votes).  Thus the 51 A to 
49 B result is highly unrepresentative of those who
actually voted: 42,750 for party A but 57,250 for party B.

These numbers are deliberately exaggerated to show the point, but here in the 
UK we see this effect in every UK General Election
since 1945, where the win small, loose big effect of FPTP has consistently 
benefited the Labour Party at the expense of the
Conservative Party.

And where such vote concentration exists  -  at is does everywhere  -  the 
result can be greatly influenced by where the boundaries
of the single-member districts are drawn.  Move the boundary, change the 
result.

These are fundamental defects of FPTP in single-member districts that must be 
addressed if you want your elected assemblies to be
properly representative of those who vote.

Both of these defects has greater effect if the electorates are not so equal or 
if the turnouts vary with party support (as they
certainly do in the UK).

So even when there are only two parties, FPTP is very far from fine.

James Gilmour





-
No virus found in this message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com
Version: 2012.0.2178 / Virus Database: 2425/5044 - Release Date: 06/04/12



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] My summary of the recent discussion

2012-06-04 Thread Juho Laatu
On 4.6.2012, at 13.49, James Gilmour wrote:

 I think Plurality can be claimed to be the ideal method for the 
 single-member districts of a two-party system, but then one should 
 maybe also think that third parties should not be allowed  to run, and 
 we should stick to the same two parties forever.
 
 I don't get it.
 
 of course, if there are only two candidates, there is no problem with 
 Plurality (because it's also a Majority).
 
 so how is Plurality so flawed if we accept that a two-party system is 
 fine and dandy?  if not Third parties, for Independents?
 
 what is the scenario with two parties where FPTP is so flawed?
 
 I think you already said it. If you want a system that allows 
 also third parties and independents take part in the 
 election, then Plurality is flawed. Only if you think that 
 third parties and independents should nor run, and there 
 should be only two parties, then Plurality is fine.
 
 These contributions to this discussion take an extremely narrow view of 
 representation of voters as it is clear this discussion is
 not about a single-winner election (state governor, city mayor) but about 
 electing representative assemblies like state legislatures
 and city councils.  There can be major problems of representation if such 
 representative assemblies are elected by FPTP from
 single-member districts even when there are only two parties.
 
 Even when the electorates of the single-member districts are as near equal as 
 possible and even when the turnouts are near equal,
 FPTP in single-member districts can deliver highly unrepresentative results 
 if the support for the two parties is concentrated in
 particular districts -  as it is in most electorates.  Thus party A that wins 
 51 of the 100 seats in the assembly may win those
 seats by small margins (say 550 votes to 450 votes) but party B that looses 
 the election with 49 of the 100 seats may have won its
 seats by overwhelming margins (say 700 votes to 300 votes).  Thus the 51 A to 
 49 B result is highly unrepresentative of those who
 actually voted: 42,750 for party A but 57,250 for party B.
 
 These numbers are deliberately exaggerated to show the point, but here in the 
 UK we see this effect in every UK General Election
 since 1945, where the win small, loose big effect of FPTP has consistently 
 benefited the Labour Party at the expense of the
 Conservative Party.
 
 And where such vote concentration exists  -  at is does everywhere  -  the 
 result can be greatly influenced by where the boundaries
 of the single-member districts are drawn.  Move the boundary, change the 
 result.
 
 These are fundamental defects of FPTP in single-member districts that must be 
 addressed if you want your elected assemblies to be
 properly representative of those who vote.
 
 Both of these defects has greater effect if the electorates are not so equal 
 or if the turnouts vary with party support (as they
 certainly do in the UK).
 
 So even when there are only two parties, FPTP is very far from fine.
 
 James Gilmour

Yes, that makes sense. FPTP in single-member districts is not fair in the sense 
that it gives only approximate results (due to the inaccuracy of counting the 
seats in single-member districts) and is vulnerable to gerrymandering.

A system that counts the proportions at national level (typically a multi-party 
system) would be more accurate. Also gerrymandering can be avoided this way.

The discussed proposal of changing the Plurality/FPTP method of the 
single-member districts to some other single-winner method has still many of 
the discussed problems (inaccuracy, gerrymandering). One could try to construct 
also two-party systems or single-member district based systems that would avoid 
those problems. But maybe proportional representation is a more likely ideal 
end result. Practical reforms may however start with whatever achievable steps.

Juho




Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] My summary of the recent discussion

2012-06-04 Thread James Gilmour

  what is the scenario with two parties where FPTP is so flawed?

  Only if you think that 
  third parties and independents should nor run, and there 
  should be only two parties, then Plurality is fine.

  On 4.6.2012, at 13.49, James Gilmour wrote: 
  These contributions to this discussion take an extremely narrow view 
  of representation of voters as it is clear this discussion is not 
  about a single-winner election (state governor, city mayor) but about 
  electing representative assemblies like state legislatures and city 
  councils.  There can be major problems of representation if such 
  representative assemblies are elected by FPTP from single-member 
  districts even when there are only two parties.
  
  Even when the electorates of the single-member districts are as near 
  equal as possible and even when the turnouts are near equal, FPTP in 
  single-member districts can deliver highly unrepresentative results if 
  the support for the two parties is concentrated in particular 
  districts -  as it is in most electorates.  Thus party A that wins 51 
  of the 100 seats in the assembly may win those seats by small margins 
  (say 550 votes to 450 votes) but party B that looses the election with 
  49 of the 100 seats may have won its seats by overwhelming margins 
  (say 700 votes to 300 votes).  Thus the 51 A to 49 B result is highly 
  unrepresentative of those who actually voted: 42,750 for party A but 
  57,250 for party B.
  
  These numbers are deliberately exaggerated to show the point, but here 
  in the UK we see this effect in every UK General Election since 1945, 
  where the win small, loose big effect of FPTP has consistently 
  benefited the Labour Party at the expense of the Conservative Party.
  
  And where such vote concentration exists  -  at is does everywhere  -  
  the result can be greatly influenced by where the boundaries of the 
  single-member districts are drawn.  Move the boundary, change the 
  result.
  
  These are fundamental defects of FPTP in single-member districts that 
  must be addressed if you want your elected assemblies to be properly 
  representative of those who vote.
  
  Both of these defects has greater effect if the electorates are not so 
  equal or if the turnouts vary with party support (as they certainly do 
  in the UK).
  
  So even when there are only two parties, FPTP is very far from fine.


 Juho   Sent: Monday, June 04, 2012 4:06 PM 
 Yes, that makes sense. FPTP in single-member districts is not 
 fair in the sense that it gives only approximate results (due 
 to the inaccuracy of counting the seats in single-member 
 districts) and is vulnerable to gerrymandering.

It is not a question of not fair (which can be a highly subjective 
assessment), it is simply that the result is not properly
representative.  And the distortion is not due to inaccuracy  -  the defect 
is inherent in the system as it is based on
single-member districts.  And it is a defect, given the purpose of the election 
 -  to elect a representative assembly..

Such a system is vulnerable to gerrymandering, i.e. to the DELIBERATE 
manipulation of the district boundaries.  But the real point
is that these boundary effects occur even when there is no gerrymandering, i.e. 
no deliberate manipulation.


 A system that counts the proportions at national level 
 (typically a multi-party system) would be more accurate. Also 
 gerrymandering can be avoided this way.

Yes, the votes could be summed at national level and the seats allocated at 
national level.  But you do not need to go to national
level to achieve proper representation.  Where the electors also want some 
guarantee of local representation, a satisfactory
compromise can be achieved with a much more modest 'district magnitude' than 
one national district.


 The discussed proposal of changing the Plurality/FPTP method 
 of the single-member districts to some other single-winner 
 method has still many of the discussed problems (inaccuracy, 
 gerrymandering). One could try to construct also two-party 
 systems or single-member district based systems that would 
 avoid those problems. But maybe proportional representation 
 is a more likely ideal end result. Practical reforms may 
 however start with whatever achievable steps.

All single-member district voting systems will have similar defects.  But 
remember my comments were made in direct response to the
statements quoted at the top:  (more or less) If there are only two parties, 
FPTP is fine.I think the problem with what may be
regarded achievable steps is that many contributors to this list start in the 
wrong place.  Elections are for electors  - so
where the objective is to elect a 'representative assembly' (state legislature, 
city council), the first requirement should be that
the voting system delivers an assembly that it is properly representative  -  
all else is secondary.

James







-
No virus found in this message.
Checked by AVG - 

Re: [EM] My summary of the recent discussion

2012-06-04 Thread Juho Laatu
On 4.6.2012, at 19.18, James Gilmour wrote:

 A system that counts the proportions at national level 
 (typically a multi-party system) would be more accurate. Also 
 gerrymandering can be avoided this way.
 
 Yes, the votes could be summed at national level and the seats allocated at 
 national level.  But you do not need to go to national
 level to achieve proper representation.  Where the electors also want some 
 guarantee of local representation, a satisfactory
 compromise can be achieved with a much more modest 'district magnitude' than 
 one national district.

In Finland there was a reform proposal that counted the proportions at national 
level, but the seats were still allocated in the existing districts. (Current 
government doesn't want to drive that proposal forward.) One can do this trick 
also with quite small districts. In Finland the size of the smallest districts 
is 6, but even smaller districts could work.

Both targets can thus be met simultaneously, accurate proportionality and 
local(ish) representation. All systems will however have some rounding 
errors. In this proposal the seats of the parties are allocated to the 
districts so that the total sum of seats per district and seats per party are 
exactly correct, which means that some of the last seats have to be forced to 
go right, and this may violate the personal interests of some candidates (some 
other party may get the seat with fewer votes), but in a rather random / 
unpredictable / unbiased way that people are likely to accept. Political 
proportionality in the districts is also not as accurate as at the national 
level, but I guess the national level proportionality is the one that counts.

In theory one could use this system also with single-member disticts, but the 
forcing operations would already be quite violent. If current single-member 
district countries want to keep the idea of very local representation, one 
approach could be to use only slightly larger districts tahn today (maybe 3, 
4), calculate proportionality at national level, and then allocate the seats to 
the districts using some similar algorithm as in the Finnish reform proposal. 
Just an idea, to keep as much of the familiar and maybe liked feaures of the 
existing system.

Juho




Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Another reason why Greens won't vote Dem, due to previous count results.

2012-06-04 Thread Paul Kislanko
I say again, the academic argument does not meet the real-world. My vote is
not going to be influenced by these arguments, and since I'm the only voter
in my district likely to read them, they are not likely to match real-world
voter experience.

NOBODY's expectation is really a sum over anything. That's just a an
analytical tool to try to attach a number to how we form our votes. 

 On EM, it's been shown by at least three people, in at least two ways,
that the expectation-maximizing strategy of Approval is to approve the
above-expectation candidates.

It has been shown in my district that nobody except me reads the EM list. So
most vote without ever having encountered a phrase such as  the
expectation-maximizing strategy. Americans in general aren't interested in
any message that requires more than an eighth-grade education.

No offense, but until the part of the EM community that is advocating
something dis-entangles their advocacy from the study of EMs in general,
advocates for one EM or another are, as we say in the American South,
pissing into the wind. 

-Original Message-
From: election-methods-boun...@lists.electorama.com
[mailto:election-methods-boun...@lists.electorama.com] On Behalf Of Michael
Ossipoff
Sent: Thursday, May 31, 2012 9:39 PM
To: election-meth...@electorama.com
Subject: [EM] Another reason why Greens won't vote Dem, due to previous
count results.

As I was saying in a recent previous post about this, Approval's count
results will tell Green-preferrers whether or not they need Dem to protect
against Repub.

And I gave a reason why that is: Preferrers of the middle of 3 parties have
no reason to approve either extreme. I told of a reason why that is.

Now I'd like to tell of another:

On EM, it's been shown by at least three people, in at least two ways, that
the expectation-maximizing strategy of Approval is to approve the
above-expectation candidates.

It's obvious why that's so: Your expectation is the sum, over all of the
candidates, of the product of a candidate's win-probability and hir utility.
It's obvious that when you increase the win-probability of a candidate who
is better than your expectation (you do that when you approve hir), that
will raise your expectation. 

Well, suppose you're a Democrat-preferrer (if there really are any). Say
it's Green, Dem, Repub. If it's certain that some particular candidate will
win, then your expectation is the utility of that candidate. Otherwise your
expectation is somewhere between the utility of the Green and the Dem, or
somewhere between the utility of the Repub and the Dem.

Say it's somewhere between the Green and the Dem. As I said above, your best
expectation-maximizing strategy is to approve  (only) all of the
above-expectation candidates. By assumption, the Green is farther from you
than is the point representing the utility equal to your expectation. So you
don't approve the Green.

What would it take to make your expectation worse than the Green? No, even
if it were almost certain that the Repub would win, that wouldn't do it,
because Dem and Repub are so close that you couldn't squeeze an amoeba
between them. The expected utility for you would have to be a candidate
farther away from you than the Green and the Repub. And that would be
impossible with just 3 candidates.

So then, what if there were more candidates? Maybe there's a candidate who,
as seen by you (a Dem-preferrer) is beyond the Green, in the same direction.
Maybe the it looks as if someone that far away from you, in that direction,
will win. Well, if that's so, then we can forget all about the Repub as a
threat, can't we. In that case, the Green preferrers certainly have no
reason to approve Dem.

So, if there are any Democrat-preferrers, they aren't going to vote for the
Green, except under conditions that would make the Rep is so unwinnable that
the Dems aren't needed as a compromise. 

And with the Dems not approving in either direction, the count totals of
Greens and Repubs will be a good estimate of their preferrers' numbers. And
when the Green shows as bigger than the Repub (as s/he immediately will) it
will be obvious that Green can beat Repub, and that Green preferrers don't
need to approve Dem.

As I was saying, in fact, I suggest that, in the 1st Approval election, the
Repubs count-total will be so low the suggestion of Dem as a necessary
compromise would be quite out of the question.

Aside from all this, remember that, when non-Republocrats are seen as
viable, there will be statisticians and (honest) poll-takers who are very
interested in finding out about the relative numbers of preferrers of the
various parties.

Mike Ossipoff





Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] My summary of the recent discussion

2012-06-04 Thread Juho Laatu
On 5.6.2012, at 1.52, James Gilmour wrote:

 On 4.6.2012, at 19.18, James Gilmour wrote:
 A system that counts the proportions at national level
 (typically a multi-party system) would be more accurate. Also 
 gerrymandering can be avoided this way.
 
 Yes, the votes could be summed at national level and the seats 
 allocated at national level.  But you do not need to go to national 
 level to achieve proper representation.  Where the electors also want 
 some guarantee of local representation, a satisfactory compromise can 
 be achieved with a much more modest 'district magnitude' than one 
 national district.
 
 Juho  Sent: Monday, June 04, 2012 7:48 PM
 In Finland there was a reform proposal that counted the 
 proportions at national level, but the seats were still 
 allocated in the existing districts. (Current government 
 doesn't want to drive that proposal forward.) One can do this 
 trick also with quite small districts. In Finland the size of 
 the smallest districts is 6, but even smaller districts could work.
 
 Both targets can thus be met simultaneously, accurate 
 proportionality and local(ish) representation. All systems 
 will however have some rounding errors. In this proposal 
 the seats of the parties are allocated to the districts so 
 that the total sum of seats per district and seats per party 
 are exactly correct, which means that some of the last seats 
 have to be forced to go right, and this may violate the 
 personal interests of some candidates (some other party may 
 get the seat with fewer votes), but in a rather random / 
 unpredictable / unbiased way that people are likely to 
 accept. Political proportionality in the districts is also 
 not as accurate as at the national level, but I guess the 
 national level proportionality is the one that counts.
 
 In theory one could use this system also with single-member 
 districts, but the forcing operations would already be quite 
 violent. If current single-member district countries want to 
 keep the idea of very local representation, one approach 
 could be to use only slightly larger districts than today 
 (maybe 3, 4), calculate proportionality at national level, 
 and then allocate the seats to the districts using some 
 similar algorithm as in the Finnish reform proposal. Just an 
 idea, to keep as much of the familiar and maybe liked features 
 of the existing system.
 
 Iceland currently uses a system that sounds very like the Finish proposal.  
 Votes are tallied at national level and in six
 constituencies, each of which has nine constituency seats in parliament.  
 Nine additional equalization seats are distributed to
 constituencies and allocated to political parties so that the parliamentary 
 representation of each party and each constituency will
 reflect as closely as possible the total votes received.  This is done by 
 solving a pair of simultaneous equations!  It does have
 the effect you describe, forcing out some constituency winners and 
 replacing them with equalisation candidates.  This seems to
 be accepted because the constitution demands that every vote shall have equal 
 value.

In the Finnish proposal there are no equalization seats. There are only the 
regional seats that have been allocated to the districts in proportion to their 
population.

 
 But of course, you don't need to do it this way, nor does the proportionality 
 have to be just party PR.  With STV-PR in
 multi-member districts the voters have the power to choose the winning 
 candidates on whatever PR basis matters to those voters.   I
 do appreciate that STV is totally unacceptable to quite a number of the more 
 vociferous members of this list, but STV-PR does
 address effectively many of the issues that arise in electing properly 
 representative assemblies.

party PR
- can achieve accurate proportionality between parties
- does not (usually) support accurate proportionality between different 
sections of a party
- allows high number of candidates and seats per district
- some methods allow votes to parties only, some allow votes to individual 
candidates

STV-PR
- can achieve accurate proportionality between parties
- supports proportionality between different sections of a party
- allows only smallish number of candidates and seats per district
- allows voters to cast mixed votes that list candidates from more than one 
party
- works also in (non-political) elections with no party structure

Juho



 
 James
 
 
 
 
 
 
 -
 No virus found in this message.
 Checked by AVG - www.avg.com
 Version: 2012.0.2178 / Virus Database: 2425/5044 - Release Date: 06/04/12
 


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Gerrymandering solutions.

2012-06-04 Thread Michael Ossipoff
About gerrymanmdering;

PR would be a solution to gerrymandering, but certainly not the only one:

1. Proxy Direct Democracy wouldn't have a gerrymandering problem either. If
Proxy DD can be made count-fraud-secure, then it would make PR obsolete.

2. Whatever can be accomplished by PR can be accomplished by an at-large
single winner election, because every single winner method can output a
ranking of candidates instead of just one winner: Elect the winner. Then
delete the winner from the ballots and count them again. That will elect the
rank 2 winner. Then eliminate the rank 2 winner too, and count the ballots
again. Each time, delete every previous winner before counting to determine
the next winner. So you can elect N winners at large in a state, or
nationally, for a body such as Congress (or its separate houses, if you want
to keep them) or a state legislature. Of course, with Approval, it only
requires one count, and you elect the N candidates with the most approvals.

3. But districting needn't have a gerrymandering problem, even if
single-member districts are kept. Who said that districts have to be
arbitrary and freehand-drawn?? Where did we get that silly assumption?

Draw the district lines by some simple rule that doesn't leave any human
discretion or choice. It would be completely automated, but it would be so
simple that it would be very easy for anyone to check.

For example: You could divide the country (or state) into N1 latitudinal
bands such that each has the same population/average longitudinal width.
Then divide each latitudinal band into longitudinal sections, in such a way
as to give each section the same population, and so that there are the right
number of such sections overall.

But of course you wouldn't have to use latitude and longitude if you don't
want to. On a map, on any projection, that you choose, use a rectangular
grid of lines, drawn similarly to the way described above. If you use a
gnomonic projection, then all of your district lines will be straight lines
on the Earth (great circles). If you use a cylindrical projection, then it
will be as described in the previous paragraph. But it could be any
projection you like. I'd suggest that gnomonic and cylindrical (using
parallels and meridians as described in the previous paragraph) would be the
main two choices. Districts divided by parallels and meridians, or by
straight lines (great circles).

The point is that it could be done by a simple rule that would have no human
input, no human choice. What if it divides a county or a city? So what? No
problem. The rule could be that houses would be all counted on whichever
side of a line most of the house's area lies.

It could be automated of course, but the result could easily be checked by
anyone.

To change the  subject a little, I'd like to bring up another geographical
government suggestion, while I'm at it: Partition.

It doesn't make any sense for people to have to live under a government that
they don't like, with people whom they don't agree with or don't like. So
why not just divide the country up into separate countries, according to
what kind of government people like? It's ridiculous to make everyone share
the same county, when they want different kinds of country.

It would be like a PR election, except that it would be for square miles
instead of for seats.

Though, like districting, the partitioning of the country could be (1) by an
automatic rule, with those same rectangles (I like that),  or (2) it could
also be done by national negotiation in a PR negotiating body, or maybe by a
proxy DD negotiation.

I like the quick simplicity of (1). But (2) could _maybe_ be done in such a
way as to ensure that each new partition-country has, to the best extent
possible by negotiation, equally good land, by whatever standards its people
want to bargain for.

Of course an overall census could be taken periodically, and the process
repeated, to take into account people who have voted with their feet. But
those adjustments wouldn't be necessary, because the initial partition would
let everyone live in the govt they like best. But, though I don't watch tv,
I used to watch it along with the family I was part of, so what about a
family like the one in All in the Family? Should Archie Bunker's daughter
have to remain in his country? Likewise the family in A family Affair (if
I've got the show-name right). It is not your fault what country you're born
in. So there would be a strong case for letting people continue to choose
what country they want to live in, even after partition. 

Of course then it would be necessary to repeat the initial partition process
to adjust the national borders to the new populations. Maybe migration
should only affect borders when it's by people who were born in the country
that they're in, as opposed to people who chose that country at partition
time.

But migration must be distinguished from fecundity, for this purpose. A
country shouldn't be able to