[EM] Explaining PR

2009-09-20 Thread Brian Olson
Catching up from a couple weeks ago, I just wanted to add my short- 
short version of explaining Proportional Representation that usually  
gets a good response from people:


A 20% group should get 20% of the seats.

It's pretty easy for people to be agreeable to that. I think in  
general it might be easier for people to be agreeable to goals of  
election reform, and relatively few actually care to analyze the  
mechanics of how it works. If they are interested in the mechanics,  
they usually just want to understand it enough to feel they wouldn't  
be cheated by a mysterious system. Explaining it to the point of, oh  
yeah, that sounds reasonable is often enough.
Depending on the audience, it might even be better to say that a 10%  
group should get 10% of the seats. Many US Green Party people would  
love that.


Another 'goal' statement I like to use:

I want to vote for candidates, not parties.

I think a fair number of people have heard vague ideas about how in  
some places you vote for a party and the party fills in seats with  
people depending on how many they get allocated. I don't trust party  
machines even when it's my party, so I want to vote directly for  
candidates. STV allows this, and I like that (never mind its warts,  
we'll figure out better ways that also allow candidate voting).


Anyway, those are my pithy two bits for the PR debate for now.

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Explaining PR

2009-09-20 Thread Jonathan Lundell

On Sep 20, 2009, at 7:49 AM, Brian Olson wrote:

Catching up from a couple weeks ago, I just wanted to add my short- 
short version of explaining Proportional Representation that usually  
gets a good response from people:


A 20% group should get 20% of the seats.


Kathleen Barber has a nice line in her book A Right to Representation:

Proportional representation is a simple principle, derived from  
democratic theory, that in a representative body the share of seats  
won should correspond to the share of votes won. The electoral  
system is thus the link between the preferences of the voters and  
the making of policy. As Ernest Naville wrote in 1865, In a  
democratic government the right of decision belongs to the majority,  
but the right of representation belongs to all.




Brian's line gets at the what of PR; Barber and Naville take a stab  
at why. Raph, I think, was also trying to get at how, specifically  
for STV. They're all useful questions to ask  answer.


Tideman does a nice job, I think, in his recent book and a couple of  
earlier papers, where, in a somewhat longer form, he looks at the  
evolution of STV, beginning with the easy-to-understand method of  
Thomas Hill, and proceeding through several refinements to Meek and  
Tideman's own CPO-STV.


One thing I like about this line of explanation is that the starting  
point is easy to grasp, but it's also easy to grasp its real  
shortcomings, which makes the next refinement in turn easy to  
understand as a means of addressing one or more of the shortcomings.


Unfortunately, I don't think there's a version freely accessible  
online (though I haven't searched Google Books recently).
Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Explaining PR-STV

2009-08-30 Thread Kathy Dopp
 From: Raph Frank raph...@gmail.com

 Looking at the 3 choices as parts of one whole vote does not change
 the *truth* is that voters' votes are treated unequally. ?Considered
 as parts of a vote, some voters have only 1/3rd of their vote
 considered, while others have 2/3rds or all of their entire vote
 considered at all, or in a timely fashion.

 Your vote allows you to increase the total for any any candidate by 1
 vote (or group of candidates by 1 vote in total).

This statement is misleading at best.  To give voters a true picture
you need to say:

Your vote allows you to increase the total for one or two candidates
per round up to at most one vote in sum per round. However in some
rounds some voters will have a full one vote and other voters will
have less than one or zero votes.

Tell the people the full truth about IRV.


 The rankings are just instructions to the counters on where you want
 that vote assigned during the counting procedure.

Let's be honest and add the phrase that just because you give
instructions for how you want that vote assigned does not mean that
any vote is assigned to any candidate (even your 1st choice) in a way
that will help that candidate's chances of winning.


 True only in round #1, so entirely misleading unless the statement is 
 qualified.

 Ok, is the the updated expression above acceptable?

Yes. Acceptable to those who would mislead the public on what IRV does.


 1. ?their 2nd choice candidate gets ?a vote that could help their 2nd
 choice candidate win whenever their 1st candidate loses, and that

 He does, unless the 2nd choice is eliminated before the first choice.

Yes, so to give an honest picture, state that.


 2. majority favorite candidates win, and that

 True, this is an issue.  The equivalent is that only candidates who
 meet the Droop quota would be given a seat in PR-STV.

Huh? That is equivalent to the lie being told to the public that IRV
finds majority winners? I don't see it.


 I think that would be reasonable, but some people might not like that
 their district ends up with 1 fewer representatives.


Well IRV can not elect candidates to all the seats if it follows its
own rules for quotas.


 3. a vote for a candidate always helps, rather than hurts that
 candidate's chances of winning, etc.

 I think the non-monotonicity is not as big an issue with PR-STV when
 the number of seats gets larger.  The more seats being filled, the
 more accurate your polling.

Well the 75 voters in Aspen who caused their favorite candidate to
lose by ranking him first (whereas he would have won if they hadn't),
may disagree with you, as per this oped in the Aspen Times this week:

Aspen City's Waning Credibility

http://votingnews.blogspot.com/2009/08/aspen-times-citys-waning-credibility.html


 Also, giving a candidate a higher ranking certainly helps on average.

Well that is where you and I disagree philosophically -- I think
voters have a right to know that their vote helps, rather than hurts a
candidate's chances of winning.

 Lots of canvassers in Ireland, when they are canvassing, will ask for
 a first choice and if you say you are voting for another party, they
 will ask for the 2nd chocie.

So what?


 I fully understand the mechanics of the wholly unfair inequitable
 IRV/STV counting methods whereby the supporters of the least popular
 (first eliminated) candidates get to have their votes reallocated to
 decide which other candidates are eliminated first and whereby the
 voters of the early round winners in STV get to cast part of their
 votes for their 2nd and/or 3rd choice candidates.

 IRV does seem an improvement over plurality.  Plurality also can
 result in a winner who doesn't have majority support.

IRV is a big big step down from plurality voting due to its
fundamental unfairness of the way it treats ballots and due to its
removing voting rights, eviscerating election transparency and
verifiability, huge cost increases, etc. etc.

Read my long, but easy to read report on IRV with an open mind:

http://electionmathematics.org/ucvAnalysis/US/RCV-IRV/InstantRunoffVotingFlaws.pdf


 and add if any uneliminated candidates remain on your ballot at that
 point to give a more accurate picture of what happens to your choice
 votes.

 Sounds reasonable.

 Right, there is up to 1 Droop quota of voters who don't get
 represented. ?However, this is much better than potentially 49% of the
 voters not being represented in a single seat district.

 In a single seat election, IRV can do much worse than that and elect a
 candidate whom the majority of voters *opposes*.

 So can plurality.  (and again, I don't think IRV is a very good method
 for single seat elections).

STV has all the same flaws as IRV, plus some.


 However, it is an improvement (at least slightly) over plurality.

IRV/STV is a HUGE threat to the fairness and integrity of elections as
compared to plurality.


 You do not seem to understand that in IRV you can **never* give your
 first 

Re: [EM] Explaining PR-STV

2009-08-30 Thread Raph Frank
On Sun, Aug 30, 2009 at 4:15 PM, Kathy Doppkathy.d...@gmail.com wrote:
 I think that would be reasonable, but some people might not like that
 their district ends up with 1 fewer representatives.

 Well IRV can not elect candidates to all the seats if it follows its
 own rules for quotas.

I think people would prefer all seats filled in their district than to
have some majority failure seats.

Also, why do you have a problem with IRV not obtaining a majority, but
no problem with using plurality which also doesn't always obtain a
majority?

 I think the non-monotonicity is not as big an issue with PR-STV when
 the number of seats gets larger.  The more seats being filled, the
 more accurate your polling.

 Well the 75 voters in Aspen who caused their favorite candidate to
 lose by ranking him first (whereas he would have won if they hadn't),
 may disagree with you, as per this oped in the Aspen Times this week:

Right, IRV is not a good single seat method.

However, the impact of the problems are lessened with PR-STV.

 Well that is where you and I disagree philosophically -- I think
 voters have a right to know that their vote helps, rather than hurts a
 candidate's chances of winning.

But in PR-STV, it is likely to help.  The issue is greater in IRV (as
polls are more accurate, so it is possible to abuse the
non-monotonicity, more easily).

 Lots of canvassers in Ireland, when they are canvassing, will ask for
 a first choice and if you say you are voting for another party, they
 will ask for the 2nd chocie.

 So what?

It shows that in actual elections candidates want voters to give them
second choices.

In fact, I have never heard a candidate say that it would be better
for a voter not to risk it.

In real elections, ranking a candidate higher is likely to help the candidate.

After the fact analysis of a specific election might show that it
wasn't the case.

It is almost impossible to take advantage of the non-monotonicity, in
practical PR-STV elections.

However, when dealing with a single seat, it can be an issue.

 IRV is a big big step down from plurality voting due to its
 fundamental unfairness of the way it treats ballots and due to its
 removing voting rights, eviscerating election transparency and
 verifiability, huge cost increases, etc. etc.

In Ireland, PR-STV counts are done by hand in public view, and they
are considered very transparent.

 STV has all the same flaws as IRV, plus some.

But they have less negative effects.

 PLUS IRV adds nonmonotonicity, removes voting rights, adds costs and
 complexities, and reduces fairness, etc.

Well, in the 2 candidate case (plus minor candidates), then one of the
top-2 wins as currently.

Each voter still gets 1 (movable) vote.

 However, this method means that if you want to support a party, you
 have no choice but to vote for the party's candidates.

 Huh!? Does that statement make any sense?

Maybe I like a party but hate their current candidate.

With PR-STV, I can just vote for a different candidate from the same party.

 I have yet to see any method proposed that is worse than IRV/STV short
 of dictatorship.

IRV may be little better (and possibly worse) than plurality, but it
is not dictatorship.

PR-STV with reasonably large districts puts most of the power in the
hands of the people.  They get to pick which parties win and also
which candidates within the parties win.

 Absolutely false, In fact most of the methods that solve that problem
 are precinct-summable, as are both Condorcet and range and approval
 voting and Bucklin methods - and do not remove voting rights and are
 FAIR, unlike STV/IRV.

Again, I am talking *PR* methods.  The condorcet equivalents for
PR-STV are all very complex (CPO-STV and Schulze-STV).

If not for the complexity, I would much prefer those methods.
However, I think that standard-grade PR-STV is still a big improvement
over single seat election methods.

 I am willing to accept that ranking a candidate higher increases the
 probability of him winning,

 Then you are accepting a blatant falsehood because IRV/STV elicits
 nonmonotonicity more as the number of candidates running increases, as
 has been mathematically proven, and nonmonotonicity, (hurting your
 candidates' chances of winning by voting for them) frequently occurs
 in IRV/STV.

A non-monotonic method can pass my criterion.

It just has to increase the chance of the candidate winning.  The
probability is worked out when casting the vote (based on generally
available information), not when looking at the final result.

For example, imagine a (granted crazy) method where each person votes
for 1 candidate.  However, a higher last digit is a worse result (if
the other digits are equal).

So, 123,456 loses to 123,451 (as 1 is better than 6 as a last digit)
but 123,456 beats 123,000 (as the last digit rule only applies when
the other digits are tied).

If I vote for some, it will probably increase his last digit (so be
bad), but on average it is still 

Re: [EM] Explaining PR-STV

2009-08-30 Thread Kathy Dopp
On Sun, Aug 30, 2009 at 11:39 AM, Raph Frankraph...@gmail.com wrote:
 On Sun, Aug 30, 2009 at 4:15 PM, Kathy Doppkathy.d...@gmail.com wrote:
 I think that would be reasonable, but some people might not like that
 their district ends up with 1 fewer representatives.

 Well IRV can not elect candidates to all the seats if it follows its
 own rules for quotas.

 I think people would prefer all seats filled in their district than to
 have some majority failure seats.

Yes.We agree. Then you agree that the IRV/STV method should not be
used since it virtually always fails the majority criteria quotas that
it sets and fails to elect a sufficient number of candidates to fill
all the seats?


 Also, why do you have a problem with IRV not obtaining a majority, but
 no problem with using plurality which also doesn't always obtain a
 majority?

Often IRV/STV is sold as replacing top-two runoff systems, thus why do
you support replacing a majority system with a non-majority IRV/STV
system, necessitating that any jurisdiction that adopts RCV or IRV
eliminates any of its majority requirements?



 Well the 75 voters in Aspen who caused their favorite candidate to
 lose by ranking him first (whereas he would have won if they hadn't),
 may disagree with you, as per this oped in the Aspen Times this week:

 Right, IRV is not a good single seat method.

The Aspen election used STV and that is how the nonmonotonicity
resulted, in a multi-seat city council election.

You should do due diligence to investigate the facts, actually read
the articles or reports on STV in Aspen and Burlington, etc. so you
don't confuse your imagination of what STV/IRV do with the reality of
what they do,and be willing to tell people the truth about how IRV/STV
really works, namely that it removes their voting right to cast a vote
for a candidate that positively effects that candidate's chances to
win in both IRV and in STV.



 However, the impact of the problems are lessened with PR-STV.

Again, the majority-favored, most popular city council candidate who
lost thanks to STV's nonmonotonicity and all his supporters in Aspen
might disagree with you.


 Well that is where you and I disagree philosophically -- I think
 voters have a right to know that their vote helps, rather than hurts a
 candidate's chances of winning.

 But in PR-STV, it is likely to help.  The issue is greater in IRV (as
 polls are more accurate, so it is possible to abuse the
 non-monotonicity, more easily).

Again, we disagree because  I think that voters have a right to know
that their vote helps, rather than hurts a
 candidate's chances of winning, whereas you think voting should be
like gambling where voters have a *chance* that their votes *may* help
or *may* hurt their candidate's chances of winning.



 It shows that in actual elections candidates want voters to give them
 second choices.

OK. So what?

 In real elections, ranking a candidate higher is likely to help the candidate.

Or in STV/IRV it may hurt that candidate's chances of winning or not
affect it at all.


 It is almost impossible to take advantage of the non-monotonicity, in
 practical PR-STV elections.

Yes, but it certainly advantages the less popular candidates and it
certainly is possible for voters of more widely supported candidates
to be penalized by it and for nonmonotonicity to cause a
majority-opposed candidate win while a majority-favorite loses in
STV/IRV.

It is impossible to take advantage of lots of very negative things in
life, does that mean we should support every negative thing that some
advantage can not be planned of it in advance?

I mean I can't take advantage of all the crime that is committed in
the town I live in, but it still hurts me. According to your logic I
should support all the crime in my neighborhood since I can't take
advantage of it?

I truly don't have time to continue rebutting what I consider to be
wholly irrational and worst imaginable method of counting votes,
STV/IRV.


-- 

Kathy Dopp

Town of Colonie, NY 12304
phone 518-952-4030
cell 518-505-0220

http://utahcountvotes.org
http://electionmathematics.org
http://kathydopp.com/serendipity/

Realities Mar Instant Runoff Voting - 18 Flaws and 4 Benefits
http://electionmathematics.org/ucvAnalysis/US/RCV-IRV/InstantRunoffVotingFlaws.pdf

Voters Have Reason to Worry
http://utahcountvotes.org/UT/UtahCountVotes-ThadHall-Response.pdf

Checking election outcome accuracy --- Post-election audit sampling
http://electionmathematics.org/em-audits/US/PEAuditSamplingMethods.pdf

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Explaining PR-STV

2009-08-30 Thread Raph Frank
On Sun, Aug 30, 2009 at 6:55 PM, Kathy Doppkathy.d...@gmail.com wrote:
 Yes.We agree. Then you agree that the IRV/STV method should not be
 used since it virtually always fails the majority criteria quotas that
 it sets and fails to elect a sufficient number of candidates to fill
 all the seats?

And replaced with what?

I wouldn't vote for IRV as a single seat method (except perhaps
relative to plurality).

I agree it isn't a good method for single seat districts.

 Often IRV/STV is sold as replacing top-two runoff systems, thus why do
 you support replacing a majority system with a non-majority IRV/STV
 system, necessitating that any jurisdiction that adopts RCV or IRV
 eliminates any of its majority requirements?

Well different voters vote in the run-off.  If a voter doesn't fully
rank, then you could argue that they had abstained from the subsequent
rounds.

 Right, IRV is not a good single seat method.

 The Aspen election used STV and that is how the nonmonotonicity
 resulted, in a multi-seat city council election.

Hmm, I assumed by IRV, they meant the single seat method.


 You should do due diligence to investigate the facts, actually read
 the articles or reports on STV in Aspen and Burlington

I read the linked page.  I assumed that IRV meant the single seat method.

Is this not the case?  The council is elected from a single multi-seat district?

 etc. so you
 don't confuse your imagination of what STV/IRV do with the reality of
 what they do,and be willing to tell people the truth about how IRV/STV
 really works, namely that it removes their voting right to cast a vote
 for a candidate that positively effects that candidate's chances to
 win in both IRV and in STV.

I still stand by my claim that it is advantageous on average for multi-seat.

In my experience, the non-monotonicity only can be determined after the fact.

 However, the impact of the problems are lessened with PR-STV.

 Again, the majority-favored, most popular city council candidate who
 lost thanks to STV's nonmonotonicity and all his supporters in Aspen
 might disagree with you.

So, Aspen is single seat IRV then?

 In real elections, ranking a candidate higher is likely to help the 
 candidate.

 Or in STV/IRV it may hurt that candidate's chances of winning or not
 affect it at all.

Are you saying that the candidates don't understand the system either
(or at least don't understand the best way to get elected)?

Polls aren't accurate enough to take advantage of the
non-monotonicity.  On average, you help a candidate by ranking the
candidate higher.

 Yes, but it certainly advantages the less popular candidates and it
 certainly is possible for voters of more widely supported candidates
 to be penalized by it and for nonmonotonicity to cause a
 majority-opposed candidate win while a majority-favorite loses in
 STV/IRV.

Again, the tread is about the multi-seat PR version.

 It is impossible to take advantage of lots of very negative things in
 life, does that mean we should support every negative thing that some
 advantage can not be planned of it in advance?

No, the point is that on average you are better off ranking a
preferred candidate higher.

 I truly don't have time to continue rebutting what I consider to be
 wholly irrational and worst imaginable method of counting votes,
 STV/IRV.

I think you are letting your dislike for IRV spill over into PR-STV.

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Explaining PR-STV

2009-08-29 Thread Raph Frank
On Fri, Aug 28, 2009 at 11:08 PM, Kathy Doppkathy.d...@gmail.com wrote:
 Ralph,

 I think you've forgotten some crucially important points in your
 explanation of how STV is counted. My comments below...

 From: Raph Frank raph...@gmail.com
 Subject: [EM] Explaining PR-STV

 PR-STV is based on 4 main principles

 1) Each voter gets 1 vote and they can vote for any candidate they want.

 ** All votes are equal. **

 To clarify, add..

 All votes are equal... *if* they are counted but some voters' never
 have their 2nd or 3rd choices counted at all or before their 2nd or
 3rd choice candidates are eliminated

I think we have a philosophical difference here (in fact, I know we do).

You consider each individual ranking a vote.  However, I don't look at
it that way.

Each voter has exactly 1 vote.  This vote means that they can increase
by 1 the vote total for any candidate.

The ranks are not votes, they are just instructions to the counting
official on how you want your vote handled.

If a candidate is eliminated, you instruct the counter to move you
vote to the next highest candidate who is still running.

Similarly, if a candidate is elected, you instruct the counter to move
the part of your vote that they don't need to the next preference.
.

 often *not true* but it is complex to explain how in STV a candidate
 with more votes might be eliminated and a candidate with fewer votes
 win instead due to nonmonotonicity which itself is due to the unequal
 treatment of voters' votes whereby voters who support the least
 popular candidates have the most say in which candidates are
 eliminated, etc.

It is true.  You won't be eliminated unless you have the least number
of votes at that point.

 3) If you vote for a losing candidate, your vote is transferred to
 your next choice

 This is only true in special circumstances in STV/IRV, namely your
 vote for a losing candidate is *only transferred to your next choice
 **if** either:

 1. your vote for a losing candidate occurs in early rounds so that
 your next choice has not yet been eliminated, and


Fair enough, I should have said most preferred candidate who has not
been eliminated or elected.

 2. your vote for a losing candidate is for a losing candidate who does
 not lose in the final elimination round, in which case your later
 choices will never be considered.

Right, there is up to 1 Droop quota of voters who don't get
represented.  However, this is much better than potentially 49% of the
voters not being represented in a single seat district.

 This reason for this rule is is so that you can safely give your first
 choice to your favourite even if he is a weak candidate.

 This is a wholly, entirely, deceptively false statement. In IRV/STV
 your first choice vote can always hurt the chances of your 2nd choice
 candidate winning.

Mostly, I don't think non-monotonicity is an issue with PR-STV (or at
least the benefits outweigh that disadvantage)

Would you prefer the simple version where the 5 candidates who
received the most votes in the first round win?  That is monotonic,
but is much less fair and gives more power to the parties.

 Yes. this would be more accurately rephrased Be careful to vote for a
 very very weak candidate first if you do not want your later more
 popular candidates to lose.

Actually, one of the strategies for increasing the power of your vote
is to vote for a weak candidate first.

Your later more popular candidate will not be eliminated before a
weaker but preferred candidate.

 4) If you vote for a candidate who gets more votes than he needs, the
 surplus is transferred to your next choice.

 Again, this is only true in special situations similar to those
 mentioned above for having your vote for a losing candidate
 transferred.

Ok, it is only transferred if you have indicated which candidate you
want to transfer it to.

I don't see how that is unreasonable.

 You forget to mention that often STV can not fill all the seats unless
 the quota is reduced to account for all the voters whose ballot
 choices have been expired or eliminated so that many many voters in
 STV are prohibited from participating in the final counting rounds.

I don't think voters should be required to fill out all their rankings.

If voters don't indicate a preference, then that is their choice.

Having said that, I would support decreasing the quota on the fly.
However, that is just making the method more complex for little
benefit.

 Hence any jurisdiction which has adopted STV have had to eliminate any
 requirement for majority winners, etc. since the method most often
 fails to find sufficient candidates that meet the quota.

Well, the post is about PR-STV.

I agree that in IRV, the disadvantages outweigh the benefits.
However, the sheer power that PR-STV gives to the voters outweighs any
disadvantages (and the disadvantages are lessened by it being
multiseat anyway).

It shifts power over candidate selection from party to the voters.

 totally false

[EM] Explaining PR-STV

2009-08-28 Thread Raph Frank
One of the hardest parts about PR-STV is actually explaining it.

Anyway, this was an approach I was thinking of.

I think it hits the main points by covering the reasons rather than
the detailed maths.  Most people in PR-STV countries understand the
method, as they experience it from a voter's perspective, rather than
a counter's perspective.


PR-STV is based on 4 main principles

1) Each voter gets 1 vote and they can vote for any candidate they want.

** All votes are equal. **

2) The 5 candidates who get the most votes get a seat.

I am assuming 5 seats are to be filled, but the system works for any number.

3) If you vote for a losing candidate, your vote is transferred to
your next choice

This reason for this rule is is so that you can safely give your first
choice to your favourite even if he is a weak candidate.

If he doesn't win, your vote will be transferred to your next highest
choice, until it gets to a candidate who can win a seat.

** Voting for a weak candidate doesn't mean you are throwing your
vote away. **

4) If you vote for a candidate who gets more votes than he needs, the
surplus is transferred to your next choice.

The Quota is simply the minimum number of votes a candidate needs in
order to be guaranteed to be one of the top 5.

If 5 candidates had a quota of votes, then even if all the rest of the
votes go to one of the other candidate, he would have less than the
quota.

If you vote for a candidate and he gets twice the Quota, then he only
needs half of your vote to get elected.

He keeps half of your vote and the rest of your vote would go to your
next choice.

** Voting for a strong candidate also doesn't mean you are throwing
your vote away. **

The Ballot

The ballot allows the voter the rank the candidates (who is your
favourite candidate, who is your next favourite and so on).

** This gives the voter full control over how their vote is transferred. **

The Count

In the first round, all the first choices are counted.

If no candidate is greater than the quota, then the weakest candidate
is eliminated and his votes are transferred.

Otherwise, the candidate with more than the quota is declared elected
and his surplus votes are transferred.

This is repeated round by round until all 5 seats are filled.

--

There would need to be a discussion on the loss (or lack thereof) of
the local-link due to the larger constituencies and unstable
governments.  Also, there would need to be a discussion of
proportionality.  For example, show some first past the post results
and some PR-STV country results.

Also, there could be a discussion of the effective threshold due to a
small number of seats.

If there was an example of the count, it might also be worth giving
the viewer an example ballot that is his ballot.  You could then say
stuff like unfortunately, your first choice (A) didn't get elected,
so your vote goes to your next choice (B).

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Explaining PR-STV

2009-08-28 Thread Jan Kok
This is a very nice, clear explanation or PR-STV. I would suggest
mentioning that the quota is commonly set at greater than 1/(N+1)
times number of valid votes. Thus, with 5 seats and 600 votes, a
candidate who gets more than 100 votes is guaranteed a seat.

I'm not convinced that PR can lead to instability. Isn't that more a
property of the parliamentary system? After all, in the US we can have
congress be at 50/50 Dems/Republicans, where just one defection can
swing control to the other side, yet our government doesn't seem all
that unstable.

Cheers,
- Jan

On Fri, Aug 28, 2009 at 7:08 AM, Raph Frankraph...@gmail.com wrote:
 One of the hardest parts about PR-STV is actually explaining it.

 Anyway, this was an approach I was thinking of.

 I think it hits the main points by covering the reasons rather than
 the detailed maths.  Most people in PR-STV countries understand the
 method, as they experience it from a voter's perspective, rather than
 a counter's perspective.


 PR-STV is based on 4 main principles

 1) Each voter gets 1 vote and they can vote for any candidate they want.

 ** All votes are equal. **

 2) The 5 candidates who get the most votes get a seat.

 I am assuming 5 seats are to be filled, but the system works for any number.

 3) If you vote for a losing candidate, your vote is transferred to
 your next choice

 This reason for this rule is is so that you can safely give your first
 choice to your favourite even if he is a weak candidate.

 If he doesn't win, your vote will be transferred to your next highest
 choice, until it gets to a candidate who can win a seat.

 ** Voting for a weak candidate doesn't mean you are throwing your
 vote away. **

 4) If you vote for a candidate who gets more votes than he needs, the
 surplus is transferred to your next choice.

 The Quota is simply the minimum number of votes a candidate needs in
 order to be guaranteed to be one of the top 5.

 If 5 candidates had a quota of votes, then even if all the rest of the
 votes go to one of the other candidate, he would have less than the
 quota.

 If you vote for a candidate and he gets twice the Quota, then he only
 needs half of your vote to get elected.

 He keeps half of your vote and the rest of your vote would go to your
 next choice.

 ** Voting for a strong candidate also doesn't mean you are throwing
 your vote away. **

 The Ballot

 The ballot allows the voter the rank the candidates (who is your
 favourite candidate, who is your next favourite and so on).

 ** This gives the voter full control over how their vote is transferred. **

 The Count

 In the first round, all the first choices are counted.

 If no candidate is greater than the quota, then the weakest candidate
 is eliminated and his votes are transferred.

 Otherwise, the candidate with more than the quota is declared elected
 and his surplus votes are transferred.

 This is repeated round by round until all 5 seats are filled.

 --

 There would need to be a discussion on the loss (or lack thereof) of
 the local-link due to the larger constituencies and unstable
 governments.  Also, there would need to be a discussion of
 proportionality.  For example, show some first past the post results
 and some PR-STV country results.

 Also, there could be a discussion of the effective threshold due to a
 small number of seats.

 If there was an example of the count, it might also be worth giving
 the viewer an example ballot that is his ballot.  You could then say
 stuff like unfortunately, your first choice (A) didn't get elected,
 so your vote goes to your next choice (B).
 
 Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Explaining PR-STV

2009-08-28 Thread Raph Frank
On Fri, Aug 28, 2009 at 3:30 PM, Jan Kokjan.kok...@gmail.com wrote:
 This is a very nice, clear explanation or PR-STV.

Thanks.  My aim was to get down to the reasons for each of the rules.

PR-STV is an attempt to solve the issues with PR-SNTV.

 I would suggest
 mentioning that the quota is commonly set at greater than 1/(N+1)
 times number of valid votes. Thus, with 5 seats and 600 votes, a
 candidate who gets more than 100 votes is guaranteed a seat.

I was aiming for zero maths formulas.

I am not sure how much it really adds.  The important point is that
the quota is the number of votes you need to be sure of being
guaranteed to be 5th or better.  The exact way of calculating it is
not important.

Anyone interested in the maths would be able to work it out pretty quickly from

If 5 candidates had a quota of votes, then even if all the rest of
the votes go to one of the other candidate, he would have less than
the quota.

Also, the way I define it, the Droop quota is the only one which meets
the condition.

 I'm not convinced that PR can lead to instability. Isn't that more a
 property of the parliamentary system? After all, in the US we can have
 congress be at 50/50 Dems/Republicans, where just one defection can
 swing control to the other side, yet our government doesn't seem all
 that unstable.

Plurality will take a 55 to 45 split in support and magnify that into
say a 65 to 35 split in seats.

However, PR with lots of parties is less likely to swing to extremes.
If a centerist party holds balance of power, then if they shift
support the resulting government will still probably be generally
centerist (just leaning in the other direction).

I think also the point is that if a small party ends up with balance
of power, that creates an incentive for new parties (and independents)
to arise.

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Explaining PR-STV

2009-08-28 Thread Fred Gohlke

Good Afternoon, Raph

Thank you very much for that description of PR-STV.  It is so clear that 
even I can understand it.


Fred Gohlke

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Explaining PR-STV

2009-08-28 Thread Kathy Dopp
Ralph,

I think you've forgotten some crucially important points in your
explanation of how STV is counted. My comments below...

 From: Raph Frank raph...@gmail.com
 Subject: [EM] Explaining PR-STV

 PR-STV is based on 4 main principles

 1) Each voter gets 1 vote and they can vote for any candidate they want.

 ** All votes are equal. **

To clarify, add..

All votes are equal... *if* they are counted but some voters' never
have their 2nd or 3rd choices counted at all or before their 2nd or
3rd choice candidates are eliminated.



 2) The 5 candidates who get the most votes get a seat.

often *not true* but it is complex to explain how in STV a candidate
with more votes might be eliminated and a candidate with fewer votes
win instead due to nonmonotonicity which itself is due to the unequal
treatment of voters' votes whereby voters who support the least
popular candidates have the most say in which candidates are
eliminated, etc.


 I am assuming 5 seats are to be filled, but the system works for any number.

 3) If you vote for a losing candidate, your vote is transferred to
 your next choice

This is only true in special circumstances in STV/IRV, namely your
vote for a losing candidate is *only transferred to your next choice
**if** either:

1. your vote for a losing candidate occurs in early rounds so that
your next choice has not yet been eliminated, and

2. your vote for a losing candidate is for a losing candidate who does
not lose in the final elimination round, in which case your later
choices will never be considered.

(in other words, it is more accurate to say that in STV if your vote
for a losing candidate is for one of the least popular losing
candidates who is eliminated early on, then your vote will be
transferred to your next choice.)


 This reason for this rule is is so that you can safely give your first
 choice to your favourite even if he is a weak candidate.

This is a wholly, entirely, deceptively false statement. In IRV/STV
your first choice vote can always hurt the chances of your 2nd choice
candidate winning.


 If he doesn't win, your vote will be transferred to your next highest
 choice, until it gets to a candidate who can win a seat.

 ** Voting for a weak candidate doesn't mean you are throwing your
 vote away. **

Yes. this would be more accurately rephrased Be careful to vote for a
very very weak candidate first if you do not want your later more
popular candidates to lose.



 4) If you vote for a candidate who gets more votes than he needs, the
 surplus is transferred to your next choice.

Again, this is only true in special situations similar to those
mentioned above for having your vote for a losing candidate
transferred.



 The Quota is simply the minimum number of votes a candidate needs in
 order to be guaranteed to be one of the top 5.

 If 5 candidates had a quota of votes, then even if all the rest of the
 votes go to one of the other candidate, he would have less than the
 quota.

You forget to mention that often STV can not fill all the seats unless
the quota is reduced to account for all the voters whose ballot
choices have been expired or eliminated so that many many voters in
STV are prohibited from participating in the final counting rounds.

Hence any jurisdiction which has adopted STV have had to eliminate any
requirement for majority winners, etc. since the method most often
fails to find sufficient candidates that meet the quota.


 If you vote for a candidate and he gets twice the Quota, then he only
 needs half of your vote to get elected.

 He keeps half of your vote and the rest of your vote would go to your
 next choice.

 ** Voting for a strong candidate also doesn't mean you are throwing
 your vote away. **

totally false statement depending on the definition of strong. There
are many examples where voters in STV are only allowed to have a vote
counted for one candidate even though they are supposed to be electing
a multi-seat *at-large* council, or where the *strong* candidate makes
it to the final counting round and then loses, where a *strong*
candidate (the first choice of *all* voters in a pairwise comparison)
is eliminated in an early round and a less *strong* candidate wins,
etc. etc.

I don't have time to finish rebutting this plethora of misinformation,
but no one should be fooled by it.

Cheers,
-- 

Kathy Dopp

Town of Colonie, NY 12304
phone 518-952-4030
cell 518-505-0220

http://utahcountvotes.org
http://electionmathematics.org
http://kathydopp.com/serendipity/

Realities Mar Instant Runoff Voting - 18 Flaws and 4 Benefits
http://electionmathematics.org/ucvAnalysis/US/RCV-IRV/InstantRunoffVotingFlaws.pdf

Voters Have Reason to Worry
http://utahcountvotes.org/UT/UtahCountVotes-ThadHall-Response.pdf

Checking election outcome accuracy --- Post-election audit sampling
http://electionmathematics.org/em-audits/US/PEAuditSamplingMethods.pdf

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Explaining PR-STV

2009-08-28 Thread Markus Schulze
Hallo,

I would explain proportional representaion
by the single transferable vote as follows:

1) Each voter gets a complete list of all
candidates and ranks these candidates in
order of preference.

2) Suppose M is the number of seats and
V is the number of votes. If there is a
set of X candidates such that strictly more
than (Y*V)/(M+1) votes strictly prefer
each candidate of this set to each candidate
outside this set, then at least min{X,Y}
candidates of this set must be elected.

Markus Schulze



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Explaining PR-STV

2009-08-28 Thread Kristofer Munsterhjelm

Markus Schulze wrote:

Hallo,

I would explain proportional representaion
by the single transferable vote as follows:

1) Each voter gets a complete list of all
candidates and ranks these candidates in
order of preference.

2) Suppose M is the number of seats and
V is the number of votes. If there is a
set of X candidates such that strictly more
than (Y*V)/(M+1) votes strictly prefer
each candidate of this set to each candidate
outside this set, then at least min{X,Y}
candidates of this set must be elected.


Isn't that true of all methods that obey the Droop proportionality 
criterion (including your own STV variant, which does not transfer any 
ballots)?


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info