Re: [EM] Why I think IRV isn't a serious alternative KD

2008-12-21 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax

At 04:31 AM 12/21/2008, Kristofer Munsterhjelm wrote:
In any case, it may be possible to have one of the LNHs and be 
monotonic and have mutual majority. I'm not sure, but perhaps 
(doesn't one of DAC or DSC do this?). If so, it would be possible to 
see (at least) whether people strategize in the direction of early 
truncation by looking at methods that fail LNHarm but pass LNHelp; 
that is, Bucklin. Was bullet voting pervasive under Bucklin?


In some contexts, yes. However, we see upwards of 30% or so usage of 
additional preferences in the municipal elections I've looked at. I 
consider that high. Bullet voting occurs for reasons other than LNH 
concern. As Lewis Carroll pointed out, it's simply how many people 
will vote, representing their best knowledge, they may not have 
sufficient knowledge to intelligently rank or rate the rest of the 
candidates. Further, if they have strong preference for their 
favorite over all others, they may not care to vote for any of the 
others, not wanting to contribute to the victory of any of them. 
Voting is a moral action, and choosing the lesser of two evils isn't 
always the best thing to do. Sometimes the best action is to reject 
both evils, and that's what a bullet vote for the best candidate 
could be doing.


In other words, Nader supporters in 2000, if they really believed 
that Gore and Bush were Tweedledum and Tweedledee, might not have 
added an additional ranked choice for Gore even if the method had 
allowed it, and LNH has nothing to do with that.


We don't know, unless we do some serious ballot analysis -- the 
necessary information is available from a few elections now -- how 
many IRV voters truncate, because we don't know the lower preference 
expressions from those who did vote for a frontrunner. My guess is 
that the numbers are quite similar to what I've seen with Bucklin 
historically and what I'd expect from Bucklin today.



We can stil get some idea of how easily voters would strategize by 
looking at Bucklin, though; or for that matter, at ranked voting 
methods that fail both LNHs. Schulze's used in some technical 
associations (Debian, Wikimedia), and, although I don't have raw 
voting data, they seem to be mostly honest. The Wikimedia election 
had no Condorcet cycles down to the sixth place, for instance.


What I've seen from Bucklin, there is a very extensive analysis of 
the Cleveland election of 1915, I think it was, is that voters who 
didn't want to vote for a candidate didn't. Truncation, at least in 
Bucklin, is not insincere! All things considered, the numbers of 
additional preference votes are actually higher than I'd have 
expected. FairVote claims additional preference votes on the order of 
11% in a series of Alabama party primary elections, and that majority 
failure was universal. I'm not sure what to make of that, beyond a 
possibility that most primary voters simply knew who their favorite 
was and trusted that the plurality favorite would be good enough. In 
nonpartisan elections, it seems, regardless of theory, the first 
preference leader wins the election, exceptions have to be pretty 
rare. (None so far in the U.S. with well over thirty such elections.)


11% additional preference will flip some elections, and apparently it 
did. Indeed, some of the opposition to Bucklin seems to have come 
from parties and candidates who lost elections due to additional 
preference votes, considering that this somehow violated their basic 
right to win if they get the most first preference votes.



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


[EM] Why I think IRV isn't a serious alternative KD

2008-12-21 Thread Chris Benham
Kristofer,
Woodall's DAC and  DSC and  Bucklin and Woodall's similar QLTD
all meet mono-raise and Mutual Majority (aka Majority for Solid Coalitions).

DSC meets LNHarm and the rest meet LNHelp.

Chris Benham

 
Kristofer Munsterhjelm  wrote (Sun.Dec.21):

In any case, it may be possible to have one of the LNHs and be monotonic 
and have mutual majority. I'm not sure, but perhaps (doesn't one of DAC 
or DSC do this?). If so, it would be possible to see (at least) whether 
people strategize in the direction of early truncation by looking at 
methods that fail LNHarm but pass LNHelp; that is, Bucklin.



  Stay connected to the people that matter most with a smarter inbox. Take 
a look http://au.docs.yahoo.com/mail/smarterinbox
Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Why I think IRV isn't a serious alternative KD

2008-12-21 Thread Kristofer Munsterhjelm

James Gilmour wrote:

Kevin Venzke  > Sent: Tuesday, December 16, 2008 1:49 PM
The reason I believe LNHarm is more valuable than 
monotonicity is that when a method fails LNHarm, the voter is 
more likely to realize in what insincere way to vote 
differently, in order to compensate. When a method fails 
monotonicity, a voter will rarely know to do anything 
differently because of it.


LNH is important to ordinary electors, as I have explained in a
recent  post, at least where the voting system is susceptible to LNH
effects. If the vote counting method is not LNH-compliant, electors
are likely to vote strategically in an attempt to avoid or
mitigate the effects of LNH-failure or to try to gain some real or
imagined advantage from its effects.

Monotonicity, or more specifically, the lack of monotonicity, is of
no  importance whatsoever in public elections because neither
candidates nor voters can exploit it. It would be "nice" if the vote
counting system were monotonic, but we cannot have
monotonicity AND some of the other criteria we consider desirable.
For  example, monotonicity and later-no-harm are incompatible in
IRV and STV-PR. Of the two, LNH is important - non-monotonicity is
irrelevant.


We can't have both LNHs, mutual majority, and monotonicity (by Woodall). 
FPTP has LNH* (simply because later choices are ignored) and 
monotonicity. IRV has LNH* and mutual majority, but not monotonicity.


I'd say that IRV's monotonicity problem is indeed a problem, because 
it's so pervasive. Just look at Yee diagrams. On the other hand, I'm not 
unbiased, and so I may be saying that because it's "unaesthetic".


In any case, it may be possible to have one of the LNHs and be monotonic 
and have mutual majority. I'm not sure, but perhaps (doesn't one of DAC 
or DSC do this?). If so, it would be possible to see (at least) whether 
people strategize in the direction of early truncation by looking at 
methods that fail LNHarm but pass LNHelp; that is, Bucklin. Was bullet 
voting pervasive under Bucklin?


Unfortunately, no method that passes only LNHarm has been used, so we 
can't do the same there (to see if there was pervasive random filling in 
that case).


We can stil get some idea of how easily voters would strategize by 
looking at Bucklin, though; or for that matter, at ranked voting methods 
that fail both LNHs. Schulze's used in some technical associations 
(Debian, Wikimedia), and, although I don't have raw voting data, they 
seem to be mostly honest. The Wikimedia election had no Condorcet cycles 
down to the sixth place, for instance.



James Gilmour
No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - http://www.avg.com 
Version: 8.0.176 / Virus Database: 270.9.19/1857 - Release Date: 19/12/2008 10:09




Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info




Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Why I think IRV isn't a serious alternative KD

2008-12-20 Thread Juho Laatu
Here's one explanation to why LNH might be more
important to voters than monotonicity.

Most voters are used to election methods where
they bullet vote one of the candidates. It is a
quite natural thought that if one votes multiple
candidates on a single ballot then the vote that
the second favourite gets may take some power
away from the first favourite. This may not be
based on facts, but of course we don't expect
the voters to be aware of all the technical
properties of the methods.

The voter may be happy and trust the experts if
they tell that this particular method is LNH
compatible and therefore they can mark also their
later preferences without losing power. Also this
may be based on facts but need not be.

Strictly speaking it is enough if it is more
probable that later preferences will help the
voter than that they will cause harm. Therefore a
method that is LNH compatible in 90% of the cases
may be good enough, i.e. the voter could happily
mark also the later preferences in the ballot.

Monotonicity is a similar but reverse case.
Typical voters expect their vote to support the
candidates that they vote for. They don't expect
it to make the results worse from their point of
view. Therefore the voters are not afraid of
non-monotonicity but are happy to vote although
it could be that their vote will make the
results worse.

If the experts would convincingly tell the voters
that their vote may actually lead to a worse
result, then maybe some voters would stop voting
in the hope of improving the results.

But also here it can be claimed that it is enough
if it is more probable that the vote will improve
the results than it is to make them worse.

Voters may thus find LNH more important than
monotonicity. But this does not mean that the
method should be formally LNH compatible. It is
good enough if the methods typically behave as
wanted. It is easier for experts to convince the
voters if they themselves are convinced of their
cause, e.g. as a result of a compatibility proof
that proves that the method meets some criterion
100%.

Sufficient compatibility with the criteria may
thus often be enough. And risks may be higher in
areas where the voters don't expect risks than in
areas where they expect to find them. But the
fact remains that voters may fear some threats
more than others, rationally or irrationally.

Juho


--- On Sun, 21/12/08, James Gilmour  wrote:

> > The reason I believe LNHarm is more valuable than 
> > monotonicity is that when a method fails LNHarm, the
> voter is 
> > more likely to realize in what insincere way to vote 
> > differently, in order to compensate. When a method
> fails 
> > monotonicity, a voter will rarely know to do anything 
> > differently because of it.
> 
> LNH is important to ordinary electors, as I have explained
> in a recent post, at least where the voting system is
> susceptible to LNH
> effects.  If the vote counting method is not LNH-compliant,
> electors are likely to vote strategically in an attempt to
> avoid or
> mitigate the effects of LNH-failure or to try to gain some
> real or imagined advantage from its effects.
> 
> Monotonicity, or more specifically, the lack of
> monotonicity, is of no importance whatsoever in public
> elections because neither
> candidates nor voters can exploit it.  It would be
> "nice" if the vote counting system were monotonic,
> but we cannot have
> monotonicity AND some of the other criteria we consider
> desirable.  For example, monotonicity and later-no-harm are
> incompatible in
> IRV and STV-PR.  Of the two, LNH is important  - 
> non-monotonicity is irrelevant.
> 
> James Gilmour
> No virus found in this outgoing message.
> Checked by AVG - http://www.avg.com 
> Version: 8.0.176 / Virus Database: 270.9.19/1857 - Release
> Date: 19/12/2008 10:09
> 
> 
> 
> Election-Methods mailing list - see
> http://electorama.com/em for list info


  


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Why I think IRV isn't a serious alternative KD

2008-12-20 Thread James Gilmour
Kevin Venzke  > Sent: Tuesday, December 16, 2008 1:49 PM
> The reason I believe LNHarm is more valuable than 
> monotonicity is that when a method fails LNHarm, the voter is 
> more likely to realize in what insincere way to vote 
> differently, in order to compensate. When a method fails 
> monotonicity, a voter will rarely know to do anything 
> differently because of it.

LNH is important to ordinary electors, as I have explained in a recent post, at 
least where the voting system is susceptible to LNH
effects.  If the vote counting method is not LNH-compliant, electors are likely 
to vote strategically in an attempt to avoid or
mitigate the effects of LNH-failure or to try to gain some real or imagined 
advantage from its effects.

Monotonicity, or more specifically, the lack of monotonicity, is of no 
importance whatsoever in public elections because neither
candidates nor voters can exploit it.  It would be "nice" if the vote counting 
system were monotonic, but we cannot have
monotonicity AND some of the other criteria we consider desirable.  For 
example, monotonicity and later-no-harm are incompatible in
IRV and STV-PR.  Of the two, LNH is important  -  non-monotonicity is 
irrelevant.

James Gilmour
No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - http://www.avg.com 
Version: 8.0.176 / Virus Database: 270.9.19/1857 - Release Date: 19/12/2008 
10:09



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Why I think IRV isn't a serious alternative KD

2008-12-16 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax

At 08:49 AM 12/16/2008, Kevin Venzke wrote:

Thus, *all things being equal* (which must
be kept in mind if it's IRV that is on your mind), I would expect that
failing LNHarm will provoke more insincerity (and thus destroy more
information) than failing monotonicity.


Highly speculative. Bucklin probably experiences about the same level 
of bullet voting due to LNH fears as IRV, not much more, because the 
"harm" only happens when a majority isn't found in the first round. 
And it isn't really a "harm," that's an unfortunate aspect of the 
name. What the second vote harms is not exactly the favorite, but the 
first vote for the favorite, and only in the specific pairwise 
election against the additionally approved candidate. It is backing 
up and saying, okay, if my candidate isn't getting a majority from 
favorite votes, this additional candidate is also acceptable to me.


And, sure, that can cause the additional candidate to win. If that 
candidate is also approved by more people than my favorite. (Multiple 
majorities are rare, BTW, I've never heard of one happening in a 
Bucklin election, and I doubt that it ever happened. So, if the 
second vote "harms the favorite," it's because lower-ranked candidate 
got a majority, and the favorite didn't.


IRV can pretend that there is no harm from the second vote for two 
reasons: it eliminates the first candidate before using the second 
vote. The *voter* hasn't harmed the first candidate, because the *method* has.


Requiring that the favorite be eliminated before a second rank choice 
is considered cuts two ways. It prevents this alleged "harm," but it 
also prevents "help." I.e., second rank votes coming from other 
candidates; those are exactly the votes which would allow IRV to find 
a "compromise winner," as Robert's Rules notes. In other words, 
Center Squeeze is a direct consequence of LNH compliance by IRV.


LNH is also incompatible with actual runoff voting when there is 
majority failure, unless the runoff is simply the top two IRV 
candidates. In Vermont, the governor must be elected by a majority. 
If there is majority failure, the election goes to the legislature, 
which votes by secret ballot (Plurality election, if I'm correct) 
from among the top three candidates. The IRV legislation introduced 
by Terrill Bouricius had a ballot instruction included: voting for a 
lower ranked candidate can't hurt your favorite. It wasn't true. Your 
lower ranked vote could cause the election to complete, whereas 
without it, there would be further process, which your candidate 
could win. Even Robert's Rules of Order gets this one wrong.


Interesting, eh? Top three. A Condorcet winner is almost certainly in there!




IRV has other issues that can lead to a different conclusion, but that
isn't what I was discussing.

Kevin Venzke




Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Why I think IRV isn't a serious alternative KD

2008-12-16 Thread Kevin Venzke
Hi Kathy,

You are responding to me, not Abd ul-Rahman Lomax.

--- En date de : Mar 16.12.08, Kathy Dopp  a écrit :
> > Hi,
> >
> > --- En date de?: Dim 14.12.08, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax
>  a ?crit?:
> >> > >> That's not very generous. I can
> think of
> >> a couple of defenses. One would
> >> > >> be to point out that it is
> necessitated by
> >> the other criteria that IRV
> >> > >> satisfies. All things being equal, I
> consider
> >> LNHarm more desirable than
> >> > >> monotonicity, for instance.
> 
> Abd ul,
> 
> That is about the strangest position I've seen you take
> on any subject
> because it is equivalent to saying that it is more
> important for a
> voting method not to hurt my lower choice candidates than
> my first
> choice candidates.

The reason I believe LNHarm is more valuable than monotonicity is that
when a method fails LNHarm, the voter is more likely to realize in
what insincere way to vote differently, in order to compensate. When
a method fails monotonicity, a voter will rarely know to do anything
differently because of it. Thus, *all things being equal* (which must
be kept in mind if it's IRV that is on your mind), I would expect that
failing LNHarm will provoke more insincerity (and thus destroy more 
information) than failing monotonicity.

IRV has other issues that can lead to a different conclusion, but that
isn't what I was discussing.

Kevin Venzke


  

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info