Re: [Election-Methods] Improved Approval Runoff

2007-10-02 Thread Paul Kislanko
Just to make myself clear here, to a voter a "utility" is something like the
electric company, or the municipal water supplier. "Utilities" is a category
of stocks traded on various exchanges. 

They have nothing to do with how we vote.



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [Election-Methods] Improved Approval Runoff

2007-08-22 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax
At 04:01 PM 8/22/2007, Kevin Venzke wrote:
>To be clear, I thought you were claiming that any method (not just a
>Condorcet method) that allows such votes could simply be called a mix
>of Condorcet and Approval. That's why I brought up ER-IRV.

Oh. That is so blatantly false that it did not even occur to me that 
what I wrote could be read that way, though, of course, it is a 
possible reading, even a literal one. No, what I intended to write was:

Any *Condorcet* method which allows equal ranking and truncation is 
Condorcet/Approval, *not* referring to a specific method by that 
name, and not specifying exactly how the votes are counted and the 
winner determined, beyond it being a Condorcet method.

In fact, however, I also had in mind IRV, and IRV / Approval is pretty simple.


> > There are lots of Condorcet methods, of course. But allowing equal
> > ranking and truncation causes most of them to take on aspects of
> > Approval, and, of course, voters could elect to cast what are
> > essentially approval ballots. If all of them did, I would assume that
> > the Approval winner would win
>
>If the method strictly satisfies Condorcet, then yes, the candidate with
>the most votes would have to win.

Right.

>However, MinMax (pairwise opposition), which does still determine its
>winner strictly from the strengths of pairwise contests, would not
>necessarily elect the approval winner on such votes. On the other hand,
>it satisfies FBC and LNHarm.

No claim is made that such a method is optimal. I do claim that 
allowing equal ranking and truncation generally improve methods.

("The Approval winner" is indistinguishable from a Condorcet winner 
in the context described, a Condorcet method that allows equal 
ranking and truncation. At least that is how it looks to me, superficially.)



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [Election-Methods] Improved Approval Runoff

2007-08-22 Thread Kevin Venzke
Hi,

--- Abd ul-Rahman Lomax <[EMAIL PROTECTED]> a écrit :
> At 09:04 AM 8/22/2007, Kevin Venzke wrote:
> >I wouldn't choose it either. This comment of mine is a response to you
> >seeming to claim that if a method allows equal-ranking and truncation,
> >this is a sufficient condition for it to be called "Condorcet/Approval."
> >
> >If that's not what you were saying than I wonder what you meant in your
> >first mail that used the term "Condorcet/Approval"?
> 
> I was not aware when I wrote that of a method called, specifically 
> "Condorcet/Approval." I now see a wiki page on it, specifically on 
> Improved Condorcet/Approval. I was not claiming that any Condorcet 
> method allowing equal ranking and truncation was *this* particular 
> method. In particular, I did not state that approval would be used to 
> resolve cycles.

To be clear, I thought you were claiming that any method (not just a
Condorcet method) that allows such votes could simply be called a mix
of Condorcet and Approval. That's why I brought up ER-IRV.

> There are lots of Condorcet methods, of course. But allowing equal 
> ranking and truncation causes most of them to take on aspects of 
> Approval, and, of course, voters could elect to cast what are 
> essentially approval ballots. If all of them did, I would assume that 
> the Approval winner would win

If the method strictly satisfies Condorcet, then yes, the candidate with
the most votes would have to win.

However, MinMax (pairwise opposition), which does still determine its
winner strictly from the strengths of pairwise contests, would not
necessarily elect the approval winner on such votes. On the other hand,
it satisfies FBC and LNHarm.

Kevin Venzke


  
_ 
Ne gardez plus qu'une seule adresse mail ! Copiez vos mails vers Yahoo! Mail 

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [Election-Methods] Improved Approval Runoff

2007-08-22 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax
At 10:42 PM 8/21/2007, Dave Ketchum wrote:
>On Tue, 21 Aug 2007 21:59:49 -0400 Abd ul-Rahman Lomax wrote:
>>At 10:48 PM 8/20/2007, Kevin Venzke wrote:
>>
>>>That's still pretty strange... What about IRV with equal rankings allowed?
>WHAT do the vote counters do that maybe can claim equal strength for 
>such rankings, when others are not doing such?
> Joe ranks A and B at top - give same count to each as the one 
> Joe would otherwise select and they get an advantage.

IRV with equal ranking is really almost identical in procedure. IRV 
is a single-candidate elimination process. If equal ranking is 
allowed, each stage becomes an Approval-loser election instead of a 
Plurality-loser election.

Were the argument of unfairness true, it would also apply to simple 
Approval. It does not. There is no advantage, unless you consider 
some restoration of fairness and advantage.

IRV with equal ranking could ameliorate the center squeeze effect. 
But, of course, if voters don't use the option, it would have no 
effect. In any case, it costs nothing.

Mr. Ketchum has been around for some time, I'd expect him to understand this.

(Others have made the same error in the past, though.)


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [Election-Methods] Improved Approval Runoff

2007-08-21 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax
At 01:32 AM 8/21/2007, Paul Kislanko wrote:
>Just to make myself clear here, to a voter a "utility" is something like the
>electric company, or the municipal water supplier. "Utilities" is a category
>of stocks traded on various exchanges.
>
>They have nothing to do with how we vote.

Ah, this is really offensive.

Look it up, Paul!

>6 utility
>  (economics) a measure that is to be maximized in any situation 
> involving choice

Were we proposing that the world "utility" appear on ballots, the 
objection that it could be confusing would be cogent. But we are not.






Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [Election-Methods] Improved Approval Runoff

2007-08-21 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax
At 01:23 AM 8/21/2007, Paul Kislanko wrote:
>There is no such thing as "utility" to a voter. That is an abstraction used
>by analysts for which I have seen no definition that is useful to me, a
>voter, despite having pleaded for one on this list for at least three years
>now.

The term is widely used, and it has generally accepted meanings, 
though often lacking precision. There are certain assumptions 
underlying the concept.

And there are equivalent terms. Expected Satisfaction is one.

If Candidate A wins this election, how satisfied would you be?

0 Very Dissatisfied
1 Moderately Dissatisfied
2 Slightly Dissatisfied
3 Neither Satisfied nor Dissatisfied
4 Slightly Pleased
5 Moderately Pleased
6 Very Pleased.

This could be a Range 6 ballot.

It is usually a bad idea to claim that something that many find a 
useful concept does not exist. It does, at least in some way

Utility is used in game theory to find optimum actions. Each possible 
choice is assigned a utility, some value. In some cases, this can be 
done accurately; if, for example, various outcomes have economic 
value, they might be valued in dollars. There are voting schemes 
where one essentially bids with taxes. (I find this idea interesting, 
and not necessarily plutocratic, if what is being decided with the 
"votes" is how taxes will be spent. But it is not my purpose here to 
examine this kind of proposal, it is merely an example where 
"utility" has a very specific meaning for a given voter. It would be, 
in this case, how much you were willing to bid to get the outcome you want.)

The utilities in Range Voting are really the same as utilities in game theory.

In simulations, it is assumed that people have some kind of internal 
process for assigning value to candidates. While, in fact, there may 
be no such valuation, rather people consider candidates pairwise and 
rank through a series of pairwise comparisons, people also have a 
sense of preference strength, and, through pairwise comparisons and 
preference strengths, one can estimate a scale. Can there be a 
Condorcet Cycle? Not in the simulations, but, in reality, it might be 
possible, for when we compare two candidates, we may compare them 
based on a particular set of characteristics that are salient for 
that pair; with another pair, another set may be used, and thus it 
becomes possible to have a cycle.

The simulations that I'm aware of use "issue space." If I am correct, 
it is presumed that there are a series of issues, with a linear scale 
associated with each. Voters and candidates are assigned positions on 
each of these scales, according to some distribution considered 
realistic (it would not realistically be a linear distribution; 
rather the opinions of people cluster). The distance between the 
voter's position and the candidate's position is "regret" if that 
candidate is elected, on that scale. I don't know, actually, if only 
one issue scale is used, or if there are a series in vector space. In 
any case, resulting from this is an assignment of numerical values to 
each candidate. In the simulations, this is the utility. That, then, 
is translated into a Range vote using various strategies.

Range votes are, however, just votes. They are not "utilities." But 
*if* there are commensurable utilities, and voters vote Range Votes 
proportional to them, Range optimizes utility summed over all voters. 
If the utilities are "relative expected satisfaction," somewhat like 
what I listed above, Range, then, optimizes overall voter 
satisfaction with the result, minimizing dissatisfaction.

Obviously, there is a series of assumptions being made. However, they 
are reasonable ones. We are quite capable of ranking candidates, and, 
in addition, of estimating preference strengths. This, then, means 
that we are capable of *rating* candidates. Rating is just ranking 
with varying spread between the ranks. Rating is utility is expected 
voter satisfaction; however, in the end, all of this is theory and 
perhaps rationalization, the reality is that the voter is casting 
votes which have effects on the outcome.

It just happens that Range apparently *does* optimize overall 
satisfaction, not perfectly, but better than other methods on the 
table. Even if voters vote "strategically," i.e., choose the votes 
which game theory would indicate are optimal. It's really rather 
silly, the objection about strategic voting in Range. We want people 
to express what they want, and how strongly they want it. If they 
think they gain advantage by voting strongly, *they have strong 
preferences,* at least if they are sane.

(There are hysterics who make everything a matter of strong 
preference. But Range Voting is not turning society over to 
hysterics. There are probably hysterics on all sides of the issues, 
and they average out. The presence of "hysterical voters" -- who 
would vote quite as people claim strategic voters would vote -- 
merely shifts the election toward Approval, which 

Re: [Election-Methods] Improved Approval Runoff

2007-08-21 Thread Dave Ketchum
On Tue, 21 Aug 2007 21:59:49 -0400 Abd ul-Rahman Lomax wrote:
> At 10:48 PM 8/20/2007, Kevin Venzke wrote:
> 
>>That's still pretty strange... What about IRV with equal rankings allowed?
> 
WHAT do the vote counters do that maybe can claim equal strength for such 
rankings, when others are not doing such?
 Joe ranks A and B at top - give same count to each as the one Joe 
would otherwise select and they get an advantage.
> 
> Well, I suggested it long ago as a simple improvement. Voters can 
> essentially vote it as Approval if they want.
> 
> In an Approval election, if all the candidates you approve are not 
> going to win, your vote has been wasted. (Unless, of course, it is 
> Asset Voting or some PR scheme). Having a fallback vote makes sense.
> 
> However, I wouldn't personally choose IRV as the ranked method to 
> use. Why in the world not use a Condorcet method, if you want ranked?
  Now you get away from IRV's failures.
  Condorcet can and does give equal power to equal ranking (only thing 
special is that A=B means they are equal - they get fully normal 
relationship to higher and lower ranks).
> 
> The trick that I've proposed to make Range methods MC compliant could 
> also be used with IRV. Let the IRV election play out, then reanalyze 
> the ballots fully and see if anyone beats the IRV winner pairwise. 
> Since you need only compare the pairs including the IRV winner, the 
> counting is simplified. This would detect the Condorcet winner 
> (though it might detect more than one candidate beating the IRV 
> winner -- but that should be rare, since IRV does usually pick the 
> Condorcet winner unless there are a lot of candidates.)
> 
> You could either award the victory to the one who beats the pairwise 
> winner -- in some fashion -- or hold a runoff. A real runoff is the 
> ultimate challenge, the proof that the winner is acceptable to a 
> majority, at least comparatively. (A true test would be a pure Yes/No 
> ratification.)
-- 
  [EMAIL PROTECTED]people.clarityconnect.com/webpages3/davek
  Dave Ketchum   108 Halstead Ave, Owego, NY  13827-1708   607-687-5026
Do to no one what you would not want done to you.
  If you want peace, work for justice.




Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [Election-Methods] Improved Approval Runoff (small correction)

2007-08-21 Thread Chris Benham



Chris Benham wrote:


31: A>>B
32: B>>C
37: C>>A

Leaving aside the approval cutoffs, methods that don't elect C here 
must fail mono-raise.
With these rankings and also C being the most approved candidate, for 
me a method needs

a good excuse for not electing C.

DMC and also "Approval-Weighted Pairwise" both elect C. 


The last line is wrong. I meant to write


DMC and also "Approval-Weighted Pairwise" both fail to elect C.


They both elect B. Sorry if  I caused any confusion.

Chris Benham






Peter Barath wrote:


And what about the method (I don't know the name) in which
the least approved candidate is eliminated until there is
a Condorcet-winner?

That is called "Definite Majority Choice". It has some alternative 
algorithms.


http://wiki.electorama.com/wiki/Definite_Majority_Choice


Does it also fail FBC?



Yes. All methods that meet the Condorcet criterion fail FBC. Condorcet 
is incompatible
with FBC. Kevin's "adjustment" of Condorcet//Approval to meet FBC 
causes it to no

longer strictly meet the Condorcet criterion.


Did somebody
analyse the strategy incentives then?


Yes, it has been discussed a lot at EM. It used to be my favourite.

31: A>>B
32: B>>C
37: C>>A

Leaving aside the approval cutoffs, methods that don't elect C here 
must fail mono-raise.
With these rankings and also C being the most approved candidate, for 
me a method needs

a good excuse for not electing C.

DMC and also "Approval-Weighted Pairwise" both elect C.

http://wiki.electorama.com/wiki/Cardinal_pairwise

I like  "Approval-Sorted Margins".

http://wiki.electorama.com/wiki/Approval_Sorted_Margins

I also like using that method to find the lowest-ordered candidate, 
eliminate that candidate, and then
repeat the process until one remains, each time interpreting ballots 
that make no approval distinction
among remaining candidates as approving all except those they rank 
(among the remaining candidates)
bottom or equal-bottom. (I think that is also good for plain ranked 
ballots that allow truncation but not

an explicit approval cutoff.)

An algorithm that is equivalent or nearly equivalent to ASM is to use 
one of  Beatpath, River or Ranked Pairs
measuring the 'defeat strength' by the difference between the two 
candidates' approval scores. I proposed this

a while ago as  "Approval Margins".

Chris Benham



By the way, electing from the Condorcet top tier using approval
would be called Smith//Approval or Schwartz//Approval depending on
which top tier is used. I don't typically consider these methods
because they are more complicated than Condorcet//Approval and
can't be adjusted to satisfy FBC.
   



And what about the method (I don't know the name) in which
the least approved candidate is eliminated until there is
a Condorcet-winner? Does it also fail FBC? Did somebody
analyse the strategy incentives then?

(And here I don't think of a method in which all ranked
candidates are considered as approved, but a whole preference
order with a cutoff mark somewhere between.)

Peter Barath


Tavaszig, most minden féláron! ADSL Internet már 1 745 Ft/hó -tól.
Keresse ajánlatunkat a http://www.freestart.hu oldalon!

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


 





Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info
 


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [Election-Methods] Improved Approval Runoff

2007-08-21 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax
At 10:48 PM 8/20/2007, Kevin Venzke wrote:
>That's still pretty strange... What about IRV with equal rankings allowed?

Well, I suggested it long ago as a simple improvement. Voters can 
essentially vote it as Approval if they want.

In an Approval election, if all the candidates you approve are not 
going to win, your vote has been wasted. (Unless, of course, it is 
Asset Voting or some PR scheme). Having a fallback vote makes sense.

However, I wouldn't personally choose IRV as the ranked method to 
use. Why in the world not use a Condorcet method, if you want ranked?

The trick that I've proposed to make Range methods MC compliant could 
also be used with IRV. Let the IRV election play out, then reanalyze 
the ballots fully and see if anyone beats the IRV winner pairwise. 
Since you need only compare the pairs including the IRV winner, the 
counting is simplified. This would detect the Condorcet winner 
(though it might detect more than one candidate beating the IRV 
winner -- but that should be rare, since IRV does usually pick the 
Condorcet winner unless there are a lot of candidates.)

You could either award the victory to the one who beats the pairwise 
winner -- in some fashion -- or hold a runoff. A real runoff is the 
ultimate challenge, the proof that the winner is acceptable to a 
majority, at least comparatively. (A true test would be a pure Yes/No 
ratification.)



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [Election-Methods] Improved Approval Runoff

2007-08-20 Thread Paul Kislanko
 Abd ul-Rahman Lomax wrote in reply Peter Barath:

>I guess this is an unjust blame because this thing
>affect all voting methods.

No. It *particularly* affects ranked methods, because ranked methods 
obscure preference strength. While there may be methods which promote 
the expression of absolute utilities in the votes (one possibility is 
mentioned below by Mr. Barath), if we set these aside, even Range 
methods may fail to accurately aggregate utilities because of 
normalization, resolution, or, yes, issues of strategy.
 
 
to which I reply:

There is no such thing as "utility" to a voter. That is an abstraction used
by analysts for which I have seen no definition that is useful to me, a
voter, despite having pleaded for one on this list for at least three years
now.

If you can't define "utility", don't use that in any argument. If you can,
please do so. 



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [Election-Methods] Improved Approval Runoff

2007-08-20 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax
At 04:58 PM 8/20/2007, Peter Barath wrote:
> >Sure. That's been proposed many times. However,
> >it's not a very good method. First of all, it is
> >blatantly obvious, if you care to look, that the
> >Condorcet winner is sometimes *not* the best
> >winner, by far.
>
>I guess this is an unjust blame because this thing
>affect all voting methods.

No. It *particularly* affects ranked methods, because ranked methods 
obscure preference strength. While there may be methods which promote 
the expression of absolute utilities in the votes (one possibility is 
mentioned below by Mr. Barath), if we set these aside, even Range 
methods may fail to accurately aggregate utilities because of 
normalization, resolution, or, yes, issues of strategy.

Assuming that the Condorcet winner in an election is, 
unconditionally, the best winner, is blatantly an error, because it 
is easy to construct scenarios where reasonable people will agree 
that a different winner is better, and deliberative process would be 
almost certain to choose that winner. Election methods are shortcuts, 
which reduce what may be considered impossibly tedious or complex 
deliberative process to a matter of counting and analyzing ballots, 
but it is practically inherent that the shortcut introduces flaws; 
this does indeed affect Range as well as ranked methods. But not as 
badly, not *nearly* as badly.

Most analysts here comment that, with "sincere voters," Range is the 
best method; they then, often, go on to claim that, however, because 
of the issue of strategic voting, Range is impractical or dangerous 
or whatever. Yet I have never seen a scenario which actually shows 
this, and, at the same time, shows votes that make any sense, that 
real voters would be at all likely to cast. The basis of the claim is 
often that voters will essentially disable themselves by voting weak 
votes against smart strategic voters who vote strong votes. However, 
if I vote a weak vote, it means that my preference is weak, and I 
have little ground to complain if, therefore, someone who expresses 
strong preference prevails. I allowed that by my vote. And, I claim, 
we should take the votes as writ.

In any case, I find the question interesting, "What is the ideal 
method with sincere voters?" It is obvious that Condorcet methods 
*fail* rather badly with sincere voters, when they trip over the 
matter of preference strength.

In a ranked method, where A>B>C is expressed, no information at all 
is provided about preference strength. If we assume that A>>B>>C is 
impossible, an assumption that Range generally makes (you only have 
one vote to express, so you cannot express full vote strength in the 
AB pair and at the same time full vote strength in the BC pair), we 
can look at the three rough possibilities: A>>B>C, A>B>C, A>B>>C, 
plus a ranked method that does not allow equal ranking may also have, 
as actual preferences of the voter, A=B>>C, and A>>B=C. (I'm 
neglecting the weak A=B>C and A>B=C; in the language of Range, I'm 
normalizing.)

Those votes are really quite different in meaning and value. I may be 
able to discern a preference and therefore express it in a ranked 
method, but this preference may be insignificant compared to the 
preference I have for both these candidates as compared to all the 
others. Yet any ranked method will treat this maximally weak 
preference -- it may actually be no preference if the method forces 
ranking and does not allow equal ranking -- as quite the same as a 
life-or-death, full vote preference.

Blatantly, this causes, under some conditions, poor results. The 
Condorcet Criterion sounds good, it would seem obvious that a proper 
election winner, if the election allows full ranking, should not lose 
the pairwise contest with any other candidate, i.e., if the election 
were immediately held, at the outset, only between these two, vote 
for one, we would think that the ideal winner would not lose. But 
that is only true if we neglect preference strength.

In real elections, the effect I'm talking about is more rare than we 
might expect because if, in fact, voters have a weak preference, they 
might not even bother to vote, depending on who the frontrunners are.

>  Even in a two-candidate
>contest where every considerable method becomes
>Plurality, it's possible that the minority has
>stronger preference, so the winner is not the
>social optimum.

In public elections under present conditions, absolutely, no method 
will choose the true SU winner unless somehow absolute utilities are 
expressed. It does happen, sometimes, and sometimes we forget that 
election methods are general and public elections are not the only 
application. Further, in some public elections, the context is *not* 
the highly competitive, polarized situation we commonly think of with 
regard to elections.

Normalization with two candidates only obscures the preference 
strength, causing all preferences to become equal. However, it is a 
serious erro

Re: [Election-Methods] Improved Approval Runoff

2007-08-20 Thread Kevin Venzke
--- Abd ul-Rahman Lomax <[EMAIL PROTECTED]> a écrit :
> At 01:22 PM 8/20/2007, Kevin Venzke wrote:
> > > And method which allows equal ranking and truncation is
> > > "Condorcet/Approval."
> >
> >By "And" did you mean "Any"?
> 
> Lucky guess!
> 
> >I don't think either equal ranking or truncation are necessary rules for
> >Condorcet//Approval. The method could require a strict ranking but
> >feature an explicitly placed cutoff.
> 
> I did not make the condition described a necessary one, merely a 
> sufficient one.

That's still pretty strange... What about IRV with equal rankings allowed?

Condorcet//Approval with the two slashes has a pretty specific meaning.

Kevin Venzke


  
_ 
Ne gardez plus qu'une seule adresse mail ! Copiez vos mails vers Yahoo! Mail 

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [Election-Methods] Improved Approval Runoff

2007-08-20 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax
At 12:30 PM 8/20/2007, Chris Benham wrote:
>And method which allows equal ranking and truncation is "Condorcet/Approval."
>
>Abd,
>Is  "And.." suppose to read  'Any...', or is there some missing 
>word?   As written, to the extent that it makes
>sense it is false.

Yes. Any.

>>The term "Approval" is somewhat misleading for the method, because 
>>a  vote does not necessarily represent any absolute "Approval" of 
>>the candidates, and some people have a reaction to the method based 
>>on an idea that it does.
>That is purely a secondary marketing issue. Perhaps you would like 
>to unilaterally change Approval's name?

We already have. Approval is now being marketed as "Count All the Votes."

You may think it secondary if you are only concerned about the 
theoretical properties of methods, but some of us are only interested 
in election methods from the point of view of improving politics and 
the process of government, as well as other practical uses of election methods.

Much argument about Approval hinges on some expectation that voters 
will "approve" of those they "approve." And not those that they do 
not. But a supporter of a third party candidate, here, with no hope 
of his favorite winning, may well choose to vote for the preferred 
major candidate in addition to his favorite. Does this mean that this 
voter "approves" of this candidate? You could argue that it does, but 
only by assuming, quite simply, that "approval" is an action, in this 
case, of choosing, which is not really the ordinary meaning. And,, 
since the ordinary meaning of approval, i.e., to hold a favorable 
opinion of, to consider that the actions of the one "approved" are 
beneficial, could mean that the voter does *not* approve of this 
candidate in any absolute sense, but only in comparison with the 
other frontrunner, and this preference might be relatively small. Do 
I prefer a quick poison or a slow one? If I make a choice, does this 
mean that I "approve" of it?

Absolutely, I have seen Approval as a voting method used in the real 
world where the vote meant to "accept." But this was not a 
competitive context, it was one where a group had a number of 
possible choices and needed to choose one only. An Approval polls was 
taken, the question was "which of these are acceptable to you?" And, 
indeed, the first preference of the majority (probably a 2/3 
majority}, was passed over. But not by the poll. The poll was not 
binding, it was not the act of decision. When it was apparent from 
the poll that there was a choice that all but one "accepted," the 
motion was made to make that nearly universal choice. And that motion 
passed unanimously. Apparently the single holdout in the Approval 
poll either abstained or changed her mind.

(This was a poll made in person, by show of hands. Under that 
situation, sequence matters. Everyone knows how everyone voted for 
the prior choices. It is entirely possible that the holdout revised 
her opinion based on a subsequent vote It is an error to suppose 
that people have some kind of fixed internal preference, our actual 
preferences do shift in response to the preferences of others. We are 
social animals.)

>>It's a vote, pure and simple. "Approval" is a method which allows
>>overvoting, or equal rating.
>It is, but is that supposed to be its definition? Maybe you are on 
>your way to changing Approval's definition.

The method is the method; that is, properly, an election method 
should not depend on what it is called, or the precise manner in 
which the process is described. You can describe Approval as it was 
originally described, that is, with a ballot instruction. However, 
ballot instructions which include something like "Vote for those you 
approve," are not neutral, they could shift the election results, and 
then we get all this stuff about how "strategic voters" are taking 
advantage of the poor "sincere voters." But that only occurs if the 
"sincere voters" are simply following instructions regarding "Approval."

If they understand that they are simply voting, that they are marking 
a ballot such that a vote is added to the total of a candidate, and 
that the candidate with the most votes wins, and that they may do 
what the ballot itself would allow them to do, which is to vote for 
more than one (I do not recall seeing a ballot instruction that 
informs voters that their vote will be discarded if they vote for 
more than one, and my suspicion is that some level of overvoting is 
from voters who think that the votes will be counted, even though 
what I *do* see on ballots is "Vote for One.")

The word "Approve" should not appear on the ballot unless some very 
specific purpose justifies it. Simply Approval does not have an 
"Approval cutoff." If the ballot is a ranked or range ballot, and 
approval cutoff has a meaning with the method, then I'd think it 
acceptable. With ordinary Count All the Votes, standard, basic 
Approval, the term is misleading, there is no Approval c

Re: [Election-Methods] Improved Approval Runoff

2007-08-20 Thread Chris Benham



Peter Barath wrote:


And what about the method (I don't know the name) in which
the least approved candidate is eliminated until there is
a Condorcet-winner?

That is called "Definite Majority Choice". It has some alternative 
algorithms.


http://wiki.electorama.com/wiki/Definite_Majority_Choice


Does it also fail FBC?



Yes. All methods that meet the Condorcet criterion fail FBC. Condorcet 
is incompatible
with FBC. Kevin's "adjustment" of Condorcet//Approval to meet FBC causes 
it to no

longer strictly meet the Condorcet criterion.


Did somebody
analyse the strategy incentives then?


Yes, it has been discussed a lot at EM. It used to be my favourite.

31: A>>B
32: B>>C
37: C>>A

Leaving aside the approval cutoffs, methods that don't elect C here must 
fail mono-raise.
With these rankings and also C being the most approved candidate, for me 
a method needs

a good excuse for not electing C.

DMC and also "Approval-Weighted Pairwise" both elect C.

http://wiki.electorama.com/wiki/Cardinal_pairwise

I like  "Approval-Sorted Margins".

http://wiki.electorama.com/wiki/Approval_Sorted_Margins

I also like using that method to find the lowest-ordered candidate, 
eliminate that candidate, and then
repeat the process until one remains, each time interpreting ballots 
that make no approval distinction
among remaining candidates as approving all except those they rank 
(among the remaining candidates)
bottom or equal-bottom. (I think that is also good for plain ranked 
ballots that allow truncation but not

an explicit approval cutoff.)

An algorithm that is equivalent or nearly equivalent to ASM is to use 
one of  Beatpath, River or Ranked Pairs
measuring the 'defeat strength' by the difference between the two 
candidates' approval scores. I proposed this

a while ago as  "Approval Margins".

Chris Benham



By the way, electing from the Condorcet top tier using approval
would be called Smith//Approval or Schwartz//Approval depending on
which top tier is used. I don't typically consider these methods
because they are more complicated than Condorcet//Approval and
can't be adjusted to satisfy FBC.
   



And what about the method (I don't know the name) in which
the least approved candidate is eliminated until there is
a Condorcet-winner? Does it also fail FBC? Did somebody
analyse the strategy incentives then?

(And here I don't think of a method in which all ranked
candidates are considered as approved, but a whole preference
order with a cutoff mark somewhere between.)

Peter Barath


Tavaszig, most minden féláron! ADSL Internet már 1 745 Ft/hó -tól.
Keresse ajánlatunkat a http://www.freestart.hu oldalon!

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


 


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [Election-Methods] Improved Approval Runoff

2007-08-20 Thread Peter Barath
>>1. If there is a Condorcet-winner she/he/it wins. If there is
>>not, the Approval winner wins.

>Sure. That's been proposed many times. However,
>it's not a very good method. First of all, it is
>blatantly obvious, if you care to look, that the
>Condorcet winner is sometimes *not* the best
>winner, by far.

I guess this is an unjust blame because this thing
affect all voting methods. Even in a two-candidate
contest where every considerable method becomes
Plurality, it's possible that the minority has
stronger preference, so the winner is not the
social optimum.

(The only defense against this is the money voting, the
Clarke-tax, which is - I think - treated also a little
unjustly. At least the theoretical honor should be given
for showing the possibility of strategy-freeness.
And who knows, one day it can be proven even practical
in some circumstances.)

Peter Barath


Tavaszig, most minden féláron! ADSL Internet már 1 745 Ft/hó -tól.
Keresse ajánlatunkat a http://www.freestart.hu oldalon!

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [Election-Methods] Improved Approval Runoff

2007-08-20 Thread Peter Barath
>By the way, electing from the Condorcet top tier using approval
>would be called Smith//Approval or Schwartz//Approval depending on
>which top tier is used. I don't typically consider these methods
>because they are more complicated than Condorcet//Approval and
>can't be adjusted to satisfy FBC.

And what about the method (I don't know the name) in which
the least approved candidate is eliminated until there is
a Condorcet-winner? Does it also fail FBC? Did somebody
analyse the strategy incentives then?

(And here I don't think of a method in which all ranked
candidates are considered as approved, but a whole preference
order with a cutoff mark somewhere between.)

Peter Barath


Tavaszig, most minden féláron! ADSL Internet már 1 745 Ft/hó -tól.
Keresse ajánlatunkat a http://www.freestart.hu oldalon!

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [Election-Methods] Improved Approval Runoff

2007-08-20 Thread Chris Benham



Abd ul-Rahman Lomax wrote:


At 09:44 PM 8/19/2007, Kevin Venzke wrote:
 


I would guess that if you searched the EM archives you would find
literally dozens of proposed methods that combine approval with a pairwise
measure.
   



And method which allows equal ranking and truncation is "Condorcet/Approval."



Abd,
Is  "And.." suppose to read  'Any...', or is there some missing word?   
As written, to the extent that it makes

sense it is false.

The term "Approval" is somewhat misleading for the method, because a 
vote does not necessarily represent any absolute "Approval" of the 
candidates, and some people have a reaction to the method based on an 
idea that it does.


That is purely a secondary marketing issue. Perhaps you would like to 
unilaterally change Approval's name?


It's a vote, pure and simple. "Approval" is a method which allows 
overvoting, or equal rating.


It is, but is that supposed to be its definition? Maybe you are on your 
way to changing Approval's

definition.

Chris Benham




At 09:44 PM 8/19/2007, Kevin Venzke wrote:
 


I would guess that if you searched the EM archives you would find
literally dozens of proposed methods that combine approval with a pairwise
measure.
   



And method which allows equal ranking and truncation is "Condorcet/Approval."

The term "Approval" is somewhat misleading for the method, because a 
vote does not necessarily represent any absolute "Approval" of the 
candidates, and some people have a reaction to the method based on an 
idea that it does.


It's a vote, pure and simple. "Approval" is a method which allows 
overvoting, or equal rating. Basic Approval is just Plurality with 
that tweak. (Which is actually removing an old errooneous assumption, 
the idea that an overvote is necessarily an error on the part of an 
error. Why is it an error? Because the rules will discard the ballot. 
Why will they discard the ballot? Because it is an error. Oops! A 
very old Catch-22.)



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info

 


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [Election-Methods] Improved Approval Runoff

2007-08-20 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax
At 09:44 PM 8/19/2007, Kevin Venzke wrote:
>I would guess that if you searched the EM archives you would find
>literally dozens of proposed methods that combine approval with a pairwise
>measure.

And method which allows equal ranking and truncation is "Condorcet/Approval."

The term "Approval" is somewhat misleading for the method, because a 
vote does not necessarily represent any absolute "Approval" of the 
candidates, and some people have a reaction to the method based on an 
idea that it does.

It's a vote, pure and simple. "Approval" is a method which allows 
overvoting, or equal rating. Basic Approval is just Plurality with 
that tweak. (Which is actually removing an old errooneous assumption, 
the idea that an overvote is necessarily an error on the part of an 
error. Why is it an error? Because the rules will discard the ballot. 
Why will they discard the ballot? Because it is an error. Oops! A 
very old Catch-22.)


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [Election-Methods] Improved Approval Runoff, Lomax

2007-08-19 Thread Kevin Venzke
Hi,

--- Abd ul-Rahman Lomax <[EMAIL PROTECTED]> a écrit :
>> At 01:29 PM 8/16/2007, Diego Renato wrote:
>> We should resist TACTICAL bullet voting for the same reason that many 
>> other methods than plurality. Increase the overall satisfaction of the
>> voters.
> 
> It's an error. The one most harmed by "tactical" bullet-voting is the 
> voter who votes that way. Some analysts are confused by the fact that 
> it can look like tactical voting is advantageous.

> If a so-called "tactical voter" supposedly approves of two 
> candidates, but only votes for one, we must look at why. Let me 
> suggest why: the voter has a preference, and the preference is strong 
> enough to motivate the voter to bullet-vote. There is a contradiction 
> in the assumptions: weak preference is assumed if we think the voter 
> approves of two, and strong preference in the action of voting.
>
> The voter has a reason for voting that way! He wants his favorite to win!
>
> And there is *nothing* wrong with this.

Diego Renato's point is not that the voter is doing something wrong, it's
that it is undesirable that the voter should perceive that he can gain
an advantage by withholding information. It would be better if (in this
particular situation) the voter could approve both candidates without any
loss of advantage.

That's why Diego Renato went on to suggest a method where arguably a 
bullet vote is not likely to be optimal.

Kevin Venzke


  
_ 
Ne gardez plus qu'une seule adresse mail ! Copiez vos mails vers Yahoo! Mail 

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [Election-Methods] Improved Approval Runoff

2007-08-19 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax
At 07:01 PM 8/19/2007, Peter Barath wrote:
>Which means that the concept of "two candidates with the best chances"
>depends not solely on the candidates themselves but theoretically
>possibly on the voting method too!

Yes. Of course. But I don't think that voting 
method results in a different estimation of who 
is in the top two or three, which is all that is 
relevant in nearly all real-world situations. 
Let's leave out the California gubernatorial recall

>In your example with 47 percent firm Bush supporters the voters
>were very wrong in supposing that he is a harmless candidate.
>In reality, in this case the strategic votes would be identical
>to the honest ones.
>
>However, I think your example did point to a widely ignored fact:
>that the ugly dilemma of the Plurality vote: "how will other
>voters vote?" does exist in Approval, even if it's smaller

It's not widely ignored. The question of how to 
vote in Approval is certainly not as simple as 
"Which candidates do you approve of?" However, it 
is quite a reasonable way to vote in Approval to, 
quite simply, answer the question sincerely, for 
yourself, and vote for those candidates. It is 
not necessarily strategically optimal. But what 
is the penalty for failure? One suboptimal vote is not much to worry about!

>So it's plausible to mix Approval.

Absolutely, this does not follow from what was 
stated. For one thing, "Approval" is absolutely 
the simplest, cheapest reform on the table. 
Simply Count all the Votes. Few among us consider 
Approval the best method, though there are, in 
fact, some experts who do. It's a respectable position.

However, there is no doubt but that Count All the 
Votes -- the name "Approval" greatly confuses the 
issue -- is a vast improvement for no cost. Sure, 
when you have a third party candidate who 
approaches parity with the big two, i.e., there 
are more than two frontrunners, strategic issues 
arise again. However, they do not bite as badly.

And they bite even less in Range. The choice 
becomes more difficult in Approval merely because 
the method is so black and white, so ... binary.

>  My favourite (at this moment)
>is a preference ranking with an approval cutoff. For me it's
>interesting enough that it can be used in two ways:

Well, I've been suggesting the reverse: Approval with preference indication.

>1. If there is a Condorcet-winner she/he/it wins. If there is
>not, the Approval winner wins.

Sure. That's been proposed many times. However, 
it's not a very good method. First of all, it is 
blatantly obvious, if you care to look, that the 
Condorcet winner is sometimes *not* the best 
winner, by far. Secondly, if you *do* think that 
the Condorcet winner is the best, if one exists, 
one would think that, if there is a cycle, that 
the winner should come from a candidate who is a 
member of the cycle, and not be an Approval 
winner, who would have been beaten by any member 
of the cycle. So if you really want to go this 
way, you use approval level to determine which 
member of the cycle wins. And I don't know what 
this is called, but it is certainly a known method.

However, consider the reverse, and, while we are 
at it, we might as well use a Range ballot. Range 
ballots need be no more complicated than ranked 
ballots, but they provide more information. You 
can do preference analysis on Range ballots, but 
not range analysis on Ranked ballots.

It is already established practice in many 
places, when there is no majority preference 
shown in the election, to hold a runoff. What is 
generally done is that the runoff is between the 
top two. And, of course, this is just like IRV, 
except better. And more of a nuisance, hence the 
idea of combining the runoff with the first 
election But my point, really, is that certain conditions trigger a runoff.

Now, Range is the only method on the table that 
considers true preference strength. Some 
Condorcet methods use a presumed measure of 
preference strength, but there is no reliability 
to it at all. In any case, in simulations, Range 
outperforms nearly all other methods in 
optimizing overall voter satisfaction with the 
result; it essentially does this by using 
*expressed* expected satisfaction! Some claim 
that this makes it vulnerable to "strategic 
voting," but the term is actually misapplied to 
Range, in part because there is no fixed 
algorithm for converting sincere preferences and 
internal absolute utilities to specific Range 
votes. Essentially, what I've come to, is a Range 
vote is a *vote*, i.e., an action, not a sentiment.

And the simulations show that even if voters 
"strategize" to their heart's content, Range 
still outperforms other methods. *On average*. 
You can always come up with specific scenarios 
that will make it appear otherwise, but what I 
find fascinating is that, so far, all such 
scenarios I have seen depend on contradictory 
assumptions. A voter has a weak preference, i.e., 
does not care much which of

Re: [Election-Methods] Improved Approval Runoff

2007-08-19 Thread Kevin Venzke
Hi,

--- Peter Barath <[EMAIL PROTECTED]> a écrit :
> My favourite (at this moment)
> is a preference ranking with an approval cutoff. For me it's
> interesting enough that it can be used in two ways:
> 
> 1. If there is a Condorcet-winner she/he/it wins. If there is
>not, the Approval winner wins.

I think that Condorcet//Approval is an ok method. I made a revision to
it that preserves Approval's feature that you never need to use favorite
betrayal:
http://wiki.electorama.com/wiki/Improved_Condorcet_Approval

> 2. Calculate the two candidates with the most Approval points
>and the pairwise winner of them wins.

However, this procedure is easily undermined when every serious candidate
simply has a "running mate" nominated with him.

I would guess that if you searched the EM archives you would find 
literally dozens of proposed methods that combine approval with a pairwise
measure.

Kevin Venzke


  
_ 
Ne gardez plus qu'une seule adresse mail ! Copiez vos mails vers Yahoo! Mail 

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [Election-Methods] Improved Approval Runoff

2007-08-19 Thread Peter Barath
>47: Bush >> Gore > Nader
>27: Gore > Nader >> Bush (honest); Gore >> Nader > Bush (strategic)
>26: Nader > Gore >> Buch (honest);  Nader >> Gore > Bush (strategic)

>Bush wins the first rount, but loses for Gore in a runoff (IAR).
>With strategic voting, the spoiler effect is possible under simple
>approval.

But this example was made possible only by the fact that
many voters made bad estimates.

It's a well accepted fact that in the most cases (no, not
in all cases, as Warren D. Smith has low probability
counter-examples for that) a strategic Approval vote is made by:

- making a honest preference order
- putting a cutoff mark between the two candidates with the best
  chances
- if the better one seems to have more chance, put the cutoff
  immediately under her/him/it
- if the worse one seems to have more chance, put the cutoff
  immediately above her/him/it

But rarely is the question asked: what do we mean by the "two
candidates with the best chances"? I think we are best to measure
this only by the fact of how we expect all other voters to vote.

Which means that the concept of "two candidates with the best chances"
depends not solely on the candidates themselves but theoretically
possibly on the voting method too!

In your example with 47 percent firm Bush supporters the voters
were very wrong in supposing that he is a harmless candidate.
In reality, in this case the strategic votes would be identical
to the honest ones.

However, I think your example did point to a widely ignored fact:
that the ugly dilemma of the Plurality vote: "how will other
voters vote?" does exist in Approval, even if it's smaller.

So it's plausible to mix Approval. My favourite (at this moment)
is a preference ranking with an approval cutoff. For me it's
interesting enough that it can be used in two ways:

1. If there is a Condorcet-winner she/he/it wins. If there is
   not, the Approval winner wins.

2. Calculate the two candidates with the most Approval points
   and the pairwise winner of them wins.

Peter Barath


Tavaszig, most minden féláron! ADSL Internet már 1 745 Ft/hó -tól.
Keresse ajánlatunkat a http://www.freestart.hu oldalon!

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [Election-Methods] Improved Approval Runoff

2007-08-19 Thread Chris Benham



Diego Renato wrote:


2007/8/18, Gervase Lam:

> [With a reweight of 0 a] concern [is] that if you approve your
compromise
> candidate, who ends up being the most approved, you can weaken
your votes
> for your favorite candidate and cause him to fail to qualify for the
> second round.

The ideal way to sort out this concern would be have the
reweighting be
1 instead of 0.  However, having a reweighting of 1 means that a
faction
could get a turkey candidate into the second round, as Chris has
pointed
out.  The compromise between a reweighting of 0 and 1 is 1/2!
Personally, I agree with dropping rule #2 but would keep the
reweighting
at 1/2.


I devised an example where a reweighting of 0 results CW fail to run 
second round (>> is approval cutoff):


33: Right >> Center > Left
8: R > C >> L
7: C > R >> L
8: C >> R > L
8: C >> L > R
8: C > L >> R
7: L > C >> R
21: L >> C > R

First count: R: 48; C: 46; L: 36
Second count: C: 38,5; L: 36 (IAR), C: 31; L: 36 (Chris' proposal)

Under IAR, candidates from right and center compete in the second 
round, and centrist wins. Under Crhis' method, the competitors are 
from right and left, and rightist wins.


Diego,
I don't think your example works. My approval scores are C53,  R48,   
L36.  (Note there are 107 ballots. FP scores are R41, C38, L28)
Both methods have C as the first qualifier and  R as the second. C 
easily pairwise beats both R and L so C wins.


For your method the scores in the second count are R40.5,  L28.5.  In my 
suggested method the second count scores are R33,  L21.


It obviously isn't possible for any version of  top-2 approval runoff to 
guarantee the election of a sincere CW when there are more than two 
candidates,

so if your example did work I can't see what it would prove.

Chris Benham






Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [Election-Methods] Improved Approval Runoff

2007-08-19 Thread Diego Renato
2007/8/18, Gervase Lam:
>
> > [With a reweight of 0 a] concern [is] that if you approve your
> compromise
> > candidate, who ends up being the most approved, you can weaken your
> votes
> > for your favorite candidate and cause him to fail to qualify for the
> > second round.
>
> The ideal way to sort out this concern would be have the reweighting be
> 1 instead of 0.  However, having a reweighting of 1 means that a faction
> could get a turkey candidate into the second round, as Chris has pointed
> out.  The compromise between a reweighting of 0 and 1 is 1/2!
> Personally, I agree with dropping rule #2 but would keep the reweighting
> at 1/2.


I devised an example where a reweighting of 0 results CW fail to run second
round (>> is approval cutoff):

33: Right >> Center > Left
8: R > C >> L
7: C > R >> L
8: C >> R > L
8: C >> L > R
8: C > L >> R
7: L > C >> R
21: L >> C > R

First count: R: 48; C: 46; L: 36
Second count: C: 38,5; L: 36 (IAR), C: 31; L: 36 (Chris' proposal)

Under IAR, candidates from right and center compete in the second round, and
centrist wins. Under Crhis' method, the competitors are from right and left,
and rightist wins.

I agree that dropping rule #2 is better. However, as Dave said, runoffs are
expensive. In parliamentary systems, 50%+ support is sufficient to maintain
a head of government, because this i thought a winner in same conditions is
not a bad outcome.

Diego Santos

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [Election-Methods] Improved Approval Runoff

2007-08-18 Thread Gervase Lam
> Date: Sat, 18 Aug 2007 20:23:19 +0200 (CEST)
> From: Kevin Venzke
> Subject: [Election-Methods] RE :  Improved Approval Runoff

> --- Diego Renato <[EMAIL PROTECTED]> a ?crit?:
> > 3) If not, that candidate runs a second round against other candidate -
> > the
> > most approved after a new count which the votes for the first one are
> > reweighted to 1/2.

> The difference is that Chris' suggestion doesn't have rule #2, and in
> rule #3 the reweight is to 0.

> [With a reweight of 0 a] concern [is] that if you approve your compromise 
> candidate, who ends up being the most approved, you can weaken your votes 
> for your favorite candidate and cause him to fail to qualify for the 
> second round.

The ideal way to sort out this concern would be have the reweighting be
1 instead of 0.  However, having a reweighting of 1 means that a faction
could get a turkey candidate into the second round, as Chris has pointed
out.  The compromise between a reweighting of 0 and 1 is 1/2!
Personally, I agree with dropping rule #2 but would keep the reweighting
at 1/2.

Thanks,
Gervase.



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [Election-Methods] Improved Approval Runoff

2007-08-17 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax
At 01:29 PM 8/16/2007, Diego Renato wrote:
We should resist TACTICAL bullet voting for the same reason that many 
other methods than plurality. Increase the overall satisfaction of the voters.

It's an error. The one most harmed by "tactical" bullet-voting is the 
voter who votes that way. Some analysts are confused by the fact that 
it can look like tactical voting is advantageous. However, what it 
boils down to is like this:

You are the last voter. By some process, you know how everyone else 
voted. There is a tie between two candidates. You approve of both of 
them. How should you vote?

Well, you have a choice. You can vote for both, and thus let, 
usually, chance determine between them, or you can vote for your 
favorite. The choice is yours.

And, indeed, this is the situation with voting, properly: the choice 
is yours, as a voter.

If a so-called "tactical voter" supposedly approves of two 
candidates, but only votes for one, we must look at why. Let me 
suggest why: the voter has a preference, and the preference is strong 
enough to motivate the voter to bullet-vote. There is a contradiction 
in the assumptions: weak preference is assumed if we think the voter 
approves of two, and strong preference in the action of voting.

The voter has a reason for voting that way! He wants his favorite to win!

And there is *nothing* wrong with this.

We suggest that the proper way for each voter to vote is to increase 
his or her own satisfaction. And then we try to use methods that take 
this information, and use it to find the winner who will satisfy the most.

If the voter conceals relevant satisfaction information, then the 
method will not know how to satisfy this voter! And it may err, with 
regard to this one, and thus to the overall satisfaction. We must 
note, that if this "strategic voter" prevails, and the candidate 
wins, that candidate must have been also approved by others. We may 
argue that if the voter had also voted for another candidate, that 
the winner might have changed, and this might have resulted in more 
people being satisfied. But it is just as likely, unless the voter 
has the kind of knowledge described above, that the voter who bullet 
votes ends up with a candidate that the voter is not satisfied with.

When I studied the specific outcomes in a Range 2 election (ratings 
of 0, 1, 2), what I saw with bullet voting as distinct from so-called 
sincere voting was the same expected outcome, *but* greater 
variability. That is, sometimes bullet-voting caused the favorite to 
win, a desirable outcome for the voter, but sometimes it caused the 
least-favored to win, because the voter did not also approve of the 
middle candidate. As I recall, there was one scenario (the study 
looks at all possible pre-vote scenarios where the voter's vote can 
affect the outcome) out of 27 where a sincere vote resulted in a 
worse outcome than bullet voting, and one where it resulted in a 
better outcome. Looking at approval style votes, in particular bullet 
voting, there were two scenarios where the voter gained by bullet 
voting, and two where the voter lost.

This was a zero-knowledge election.

What has happened is that far too many analysists have not taken a 
close enough look at the actual scenarios, at what actually happens 
in voting, but instead they rely on superficial analyses and specific 
examples that make it look like the strategic voter gains something 
unjust. But the strategy used only makes sense in certain contexts, 
and the risks of that strategy, in that context, are not considered 
by the analyst.

 From what I've seen, the regret of the strategic voter whose 
strategy fails is deeper than the regret of the sincere voter who 
loses some value because of voting sincerely. If you give a candidate 
some support, but not enough, because you had a favorite you wanted 
to reserve the full vote for, you may regret it, but you know that 
you were, at least, sincere, and the result turned out differently 
simply because others did not agree with you.

But if you fail to vote at all for someone you really would prefer to 
the one who wins, you may kick yourself for a long time. why 
didn't I just express what I felt?

But if the voter really did express how he felt, if he really 
*didn't* want to vote for that candidate, then his vote was sincere, 
it was not a strategic vote.

We set up a contradiction when, in Range and Approval, we assume weak 
preference in a context where the voter indicates a strong one. 
Suppose you are out with friends, and you are choosing a pizza.

(Oh, no, here comes the pizza election again!)

Your friends say they prefer Pepperoni, but Mushroom is okay with 
them. You are the last voter.

Suppose you are Jewish, keeping kosher, you can't eat Pepperoni. (I 
think some Jews will have other problems as well, with food not 
prepared in a kosher kitchen, but lots of Jews aren't that strict, 
but they won't eat pork.)

You will say so, presumably, you will i

Re: [Election-Methods] Improved Approval Runoff

2007-08-17 Thread Gervase Lam
> Date: Wed, 15 Aug 2007 17:00:59 -0300
> From: "Diego Renato"
> Subject: [Election-Methods] Improved Approval Runoff

> 1) On the first round, the voter can vote for as many or as few candidates
> as desired.
> 2) If some candidate has more than 50% of approvals, the most approved is
> elected.
> 3) If not, that candidate runs a second round against other candidate - the
> most approved after a new count which the votes for the first one are
> reweighted to 1/2.
> 4) The winner is the candidate who receives a majority of votes on the
> second round.

I did think of this idea awhile back, but it excluded step 2.  That is,
there will always be a second round (just to make sure?...)

Rightly or wrongly, I dismissed the idea because it was really just a
variation of Sequential PAV ('Proportional' Approval Voting).  That is,
the ballots who voted for the winner in the first round is halved.

Thanks,
Gervase.



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [Election-Methods] Improved Approval Runoff]

2007-08-16 Thread Dave Ketchum
I do not see where I expressed a bias I do not feel:
For many elections most voters would be happy with Plurality.
We NEED to have a method that will both satisfy their needs AND
provide for satisfying voter desires when they are ready for something
more complex.

Could be that Brazil is more ready to discard Plurality, though we do have
multiparty races in the US - and thus reason to move on to better methods.

I LIKE Condorcet for, with reasonable simplicity, it lets voters express
order of desirability of candidates as they see such.

I dislike runoffs as expensive for all concerned.

I dislike your variation of Approval as complicated to understand, yet
less desirable than Condorcet.

DWK

On Thu, 16 Aug 2007 13:06:38 -0300 Diego Renato wrote:

  >
  >
  > 2007/8/15, Dave Ketchum:
  >
  > On most elections many, if not most, voters? preference will be a
  > single
  > candidate.  Why is this something to fight?
  >   One candidate can overshadow the competition.
  >   Voters can be loyal to their party.
  >
  > For occasional exception elections there will be more interest in
voting
  > for multiple candidates, and it is DESIRABLE to support this 
voting for
  > whichever elections may inspire voter interest in such.
  >
  > Fighting complications that make the rules for deciding on winners
  > hard to
  > understand make such complications undesirable unless they provide
major
  > benefits.
  >
  > DWK
  >
  >
  > Your viewpoint is biased to two-party system. In multi-party
  > democracies, like Brazil, your assumption is likely wrong.  No one-round
  > voting system is able to differentiate them. I?ll try to illustrate it.
  > Suppose an election which three candidates (Bush, Gore, Nader) runs.
  > These are the real preferences of the voters:
  >
...


  > 
  > Diego Santos
  > Aluno de Ciência da Computação
  > Integrante do projeto Wireless(Petrobras/DEE-UFCG)
-- 
  [EMAIL PROTECTED]people.clarityconnect.com/webpages3/davek
  Dave Ketchum   108 Halstead Ave, Owego, NY  13827-1708   607-687-5026
Do to no one what you would not want done to you.
  If you want peace, work for justice.




Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [Election-Methods] Improved Approval Runoff

2007-08-16 Thread Chris Benham



Diego Renato wrote:

All one-round voting systems that allows ballot truncation are 
vulnerable to bullet voting, resulting the same results of plurality 
voting. For instance, suppose that some voter has A as his/her first 
preference. S/he can vote like this:


Approval: A: approved; B: rejected; C: rejected; D: rejected ...
Range (0 - 100 scale): A: 100; B: 0; C: 0; D: 0 ...
Preferential (IRV, Condorcet, etc): A>B=C=D=...



A voter never gets a better result for hirself in IRV by bullet voting, 
because lower rankings do nothing until the voter's higher-ranked 
candidates have been eliminated.

IRV meets "Later-no-Harm".

Also as has been pointed out, in all the methods you mention it only 
takes a small proportion of voters to max. score or rank more than one 
candidate to give a different
result from plurality voting. I regard Approval as vastly vastly better 
than Plurality (FPP) even if in practice nearly all voters bullet vote 
and the result is always the same

as if they all had.

Additionally, there are several instances which only binary input 
voting systems are reasonable. Complex systems are hard to adopt in 
low-educated underdeveloped countries.


Yes, interesting problem.

This system, called Improved Approval Runoff (IAR), has the goal to 
resist bullet voting through simple ballots.


Description:

1) On the first round, the voter can vote for as many or as few 
candidates as desired.
2) If some candidate has more than 50% of approvals, the most approved 
is elected.
3) If not, that candidate runs a second round against other candidate 
- the most approved after a new count which the votes for the first 
one are reweighted to 1/2.
4) The winner is the candidate who receives a majority of votes on the 
second round.


On computer simulations, the top-two approval runoff method selected 
more times the Condorcet winner than any Condorcet method. I think 
that IAR is slightly fairer than top-two approval runoff under real 
voters.


Any comments?



I think this is not bad for a simple method and a big improvement on 
"top-two approval runoff", which I long ago rejected as a strategy farce.


Parties with a chance of winning a normal approval election will run 
pairs of clones and ask their supporters to approve both of them.  Normal
plurality top-2 runoff is more vulnerable than IRV to the Pushover 
strategy, but approval top-2 runoff is much much more vulnerable again.
Voters who are confidant that their favourite or one of their favourites 
(with their approval) can qualify will have incentive to also approve 
all the
candidates they are sure that their favourite/s can beat in the runoff.  
If  a faction succeeds with this strategy then the final round will be 
between
their favourite and a  candidate with much less sincere support.  If  
more than one faction attempts it then it is just possible that both 
qualifiers will

be "turkeys" with very little sincere support.


*push-over*
The strategy of ranking a weak alternative higher than one's preferred 
alternative, which may be useful in a method that violates 
monotonicity <#monotonicity>.





2) If some candidate has more than 50% of approvals, the most approved 
is elected.


This is understandable, but if more than one candidate has more than 
50%  approval then I would still like to see a runoff.  Maybe I'd like to
see a runoff in some circumstances even when only one candidate has 50+% 
approval.  This special rule of yours creates extra Compromise incentive
and also means that the result can be changed by adding or removing 
ballots that ignore all the viable candidates (just by changing the 
absolute size of

the 50% threshold).

3) If not, that candidate runs a second round against other candidate 
- the most approved after a new count which the votes for the first 
one are reweighted to 1/2. 



This prevents the final from being between a pair of clones from the 
same party. It makes the Pushover strategy a bit less effective because 
voters
can't have their first-round votes count at full strength for both their 
sincere favourite and the turkey. How did you decide on the reweighting 
figure
of 1/2?  Why not  "reweight" those ballots that supported the first 
qualifier to zero?  That would mean that Pushover strategists would have 
to take
some extra risk by not approving their sincere favourite in the first 
round (as in normal plurality top-2 runoff).


Chris Benham








All one-round voting systems that allows ballot truncation are 
vulnerable to bullet voting, resulting the same results of plurality 
voting. For instance, suppose that some voter has A as his/her first 
preference. S/he can vote like this:


Approval: A: approved; B: rejected; C: rejected; D: rejected ...
Range (0 - 100 scale): A: 100; B: 0; C: 0; D: 0 ...
Preferential (IRV, Condorcet, etc): A>B=C=D=...

Additionally, there are several instances which only binary input 
voting systems are reasonable. Complex systems are hard to adopt in 
low-edu

Re: [Election-Methods] Improved Approval Runoff

2007-08-16 Thread Diego Renato
Correction:


> 2nd count (1st round):
> 22,5 Bush clone
> 27 Gore <- selected for runoff.
> 26 Nader
>
>

Diego Santos

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [Election-Methods] Improved Approval Runoff

2007-08-16 Thread Diego Renato
2007/8/16, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax:

> At 04:00 PM 8/15/2007, Diego Renato wrote:
> >All one-round voting systems that allows ballot truncation are
> >vulnerable to bullet voting, resulting the same results of plurality
> voting.
>
> "Vulnerable" implies that there is something wrong with this. It is
> not correct to claim that this gives "the same results" as plurality
> voting. That's only true if *all* voters bullet vote. And if that is
> what they want to do, who are we to say that they should not?
>

Read my previous message. If the majority of voters really intend to vote
for one candidate, they still are able to do it under IAR.

>  For instance, suppose that some voter has A as his/her first
> > preference. S/he can vote like this:
> >
> >Approval: A: approved; B: rejected; C: rejected; D: rejected ...
> >Range (0 - 100 scale): A: 100; B: 0; C: 0; D: 0 ...
> >Preferential (IRV, Condorcet, etc): A>B=C=D=...
>
> Yes. What's the problem? In a good method, if truncation results in
> no majority winner, that is, majority consent to the win is not
> apparent from the ballots, there should be a runoff.
>
> >Additionally, there are several instances which only binary input
> >voting systems are reasonable. Complex systems are hard to adopt in
> >low-educated underdeveloped countries.
> >
> >This system, called Improved Approval Runoff (IAR), has the goal to
> >resist bullet voting through simple ballots.
>
> I'm mystified as to why we should "resist" bullet-voting.


We should resist TACTICAL bullet voting for the same reason that many other
methods than plurality. Increase the overall satisfaction of the voters.

>Description:
> >
> >1) On the first round, the voter can vote for as many or as few
> >candidates as desired.
> >2) If some candidate has more than 50% of approvals, the most
> >approved is elected.
> >3) If not, that candidate runs a second round against other
> >candidate - the most approved after a new count which the votes for
> >the first one are reweighted to 1/2.
> >4) The winner is the candidate who receives a majority of votes on
> >the second round.
>
> It seems with the reweighting that it is assumed that the voter only
> votes for two, otherwise why that particular reweighting?
>
> I'm not sure I understand the "second round." The expression was a
> bit garbled, I suspect. I assume that the "second round" is not an
> actual runoff, but a recounting. As written, it would seem manifestly
> unfair to the first candidate, the plurality winner of the approval
> election.


It is a runoff. The weight of 1/2 fo the second round of count after first
election is based on Sequential Proportional Approval Voting. The contenders
of second runoff are the same winners of an hypotetical two-winner election
under SPAV. This approach increases chances of a consensus candidate be
selected to compete in runoff.

An example with four candidates: Bush, Bush clone, Gore and Nader. Bush
clone is a candidate strategically nominated:

2: Bush >> Bush clone > Gore > Nader
45: Bush = Bush clone >> Gore > Nader
27: Gore > Nader >> Bush = Bush clone (honest); Gore >> Nader > Bush = Bush
clone (strategic)
26: Nader > Gore >> Bush = Bush clone (honest);  Nader >> Gore > Bush = Bush
clone (strategic)

If under top-two approval, Bush and Bush clone will run the runoff election.
Under IAR, Bush and Gore will run.

1st count (1st round):
47 Bush <- selected for runoff
45 Bush clone
27 Gore
26 Nader

2nd count (1st round):
22,5 Bush clone
27 Gore
26 Nader<- selected for runoff.

Final result (runoff)
47 Bush
53 Gore (winner)

There is no way to guarantee that a candidate gets "the majority of
> votes" except by redefining votes to mean something other than "the
> majority of voters approve this outcome of the election." (Top two
> runoff does it by a trick: the voters only have two choices, and any
> ballot which does not select one of them is discarded. This is
> actually a failure of democracy, election results, when possible,
> should always be ratified by a majority. That's what happens in small
> societies using full democratic process, this step is only skipped in
> large elections, supposedly for efficiency.
>
> However, Asset Voting methods could make real runoffs and
> ratifications quite efficient.
>
> >On computer simulations, the top-two approval runoff method selected
> >more times the Condorcet winner than any Condorcet method. I think
> >that IAR is slightly fairer than top-two approval runoff under real
> voters.
>
> Again, I don't think that's true. Approval is *not* guaranteed to
> pick the Condorcet winner, no matter how you slice it, and any
> Condorcet method, by definition, will. That is, a Condorcet method
> *always* finds the Condorcet winner if voters vote sincerely, and
> there are few reasons to treat the matter as if they will not.
>
> however, the Condorcet winner is not necessarily the best winner;
> Approval may, indeed, select a better winner, as shown by social
> utility simulations. Approv

Re: [Election-Methods] Improved Approval Runoff

2007-08-16 Thread Diego Renato
2007/8/15, Dave Ketchum:
>
> On most elections many, if not most, voters' preference will be a single
> candidate.  Why is this something to fight?
>   One candidate can overshadow the competition.
>   Voters can be loyal to their party.

For occasional exception elections there will be more interest in voting
> for multiple candidates, and it is DESIRABLE to support this voting for
> whichever elections may inspire voter interest in such.
>
> Fighting complications that make the rules for deciding on winners hard to
>
> understand make such complications undesirable unless they provide major
> benefits.
>
> DWK
>
>
Your viewpoint is biased to two-party system. In multi-party democracies,
like Brazil, your assumption is likely wrong.  No one-round voting system is
able to differentiate them. I'll try to illustrate it. Suppose an election
which three candidates (Bush, Gore, Nader) runs. These are the real
preferences of the voters:

47: Bush >> Gore > Nader
33: Gore >> Nader > Bush
10: Gore > Nader >> Bush
10: Nader > Gore >> Bush

Under honest approval voting, Gore receives 53 approvals, Bush 43 and Nader
20. Gore wins. It looks fair to me.

However, note that Nader voters voted honestly because they were sure that
Nader is not likely to win. Instead of, if is not known the winner of a
pairwise comparison between Gore and Nader, there is incentive for bullet
voting. This is the reason of Bucklin is no longer used in US.

47: Bush >> Gore > Nader
27: Gore > Nader >> Bush (honest); Gore >> Nader > Bush (strategic)
26: Nader > Gore >> Buch (honest);  Nader >> Gore > Bush (strategic)

Bush wins the first rount, but loses for Gore in a runoff (IAR). With
strategic voting, the spoiler effect is possible under simple approval.


Diego Santos
Aluno de Ciência da Computação
Integrante do projeto Wireless(Petrobras/DEE-UFCG)

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [Election-Methods] Improved Approval Runoff

2007-08-15 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax
At 04:00 PM 8/15/2007, Diego Renato wrote:
>All one-round voting systems that allows ballot truncation are 
>vulnerable to bullet voting, resulting the same results of plurality voting.

"Vulnerable" implies that there is something wrong with this. It is 
not correct to claim that this gives "the same results" as plurality 
voting. That's only true if *all* voters bullet vote. And if that is 
what they want to do, who are we to say that they should not?

>  For instance, suppose that some voter has A as his/her first 
> preference. S/he can vote like this:
>
>Approval: A: approved; B: rejected; C: rejected; D: rejected ...
>Range (0 - 100 scale): A: 100; B: 0; C: 0; D: 0 ...
>Preferential (IRV, Condorcet, etc): A>B=C=D=...

Yes. What's the problem? In a good method, if truncation results in 
no majority winner, that is, majority consent to the win is not 
apparent from the ballots, there should be a runoff.

>Additionally, there are several instances which only binary input 
>voting systems are reasonable. Complex systems are hard to adopt in 
>low-educated underdeveloped countries.
>
>This system, called Improved Approval Runoff (IAR), has the goal to 
>resist bullet voting through simple ballots.

I'm mystified as to why we should "resist" bullet-voting.


>Description:
>
>1) On the first round, the voter can vote for as many or as few 
>candidates as desired.
>2) If some candidate has more than 50% of approvals, the most 
>approved is elected.
>3) If not, that candidate runs a second round against other 
>candidate - the most approved after a new count which the votes for 
>the first one are reweighted to 1/2.
>4) The winner is the candidate who receives a majority of votes on 
>the second round.

It seems with the reweighting that it is assumed that the voter only 
votes for two, otherwise why that particular reweighting?

I'm not sure I understand the "second round." The expression was a 
bit garbled, I suspect. I assume that the "second round" is not an 
actual runoff, but a recounting. As written, it would seem manifestly 
unfair to the first candidate, the plurality winner of the approval election.

There is no way to guarantee that a candidate gets "the majority of 
votes" except by redefining votes to mean something other than "the 
majority of voters approve this outcome of the election." (Top two 
runoff does it by a trick: the voters only have two choices, and any 
ballot which does not select one of them is discarded. This is 
actually a failure of democracy, election results, when possible, 
should always be ratified by a majority. That's what happens in small 
societies using full democratic process, this step is only skipped in 
large elections, supposedly for efficiency.

However, Asset Voting methods could make real runoffs and 
ratifications quite efficient.

>On computer simulations, the top-two approval runoff method selected 
>more times the Condorcet winner than any Condorcet method. I think 
>that IAR is slightly fairer than top-two approval runoff under real voters.

Again, I don't think that's true. Approval is *not* guaranteed to 
pick the Condorcet winner, no matter how you slice it, and any 
Condorcet method, by definition, will. That is, a Condorcet method 
*always* finds the Condorcet winner if voters vote sincerely, and 
there are few reasons to treat the matter as if they will not.

however, the Condorcet winner is not necessarily the best winner; 
Approval may, indeed, select a better winner, as shown by social 
utility simulations. Approval begins the progression of Range 
methods, which match the very method of measuring what it means to 
have a good result. ("Condorcet Criterion" can be shown to manifestly 
make a poor choice under certain conditions, it really is not 
controversial. That is, a small society would *never* choose what the 
Condorcet Criterion would indicate should win, given sufficient 
knowledge, under certain conditions, basically those of a majority 
with a sufficiently weak preference and a minority with a 
sufficiently strong one. Who decides, properly, when such a condition 
should result in the violation fo the Majority Criterion?

The majority, but it is crucial that the decision be explicit.

What I have suggested is that Approval have a preference marker 
added. I called this A+; that is, Approval with a "Plus" indicator 
that shows preference. This marker could be used for more than one, 
but the general intention is that it would be used to show the 
Favorite. The ballot then indicates the set of approved candidates -- 
these are considered acceptable under the present conditions by the 
voter -- and the favorite -- or favorites -- as well.

However, initially the ballots are counted without regard to the Plus 
marker. It's an Approval election, initially. Now, with basic A+, 
that's it. The Plus marker is used for analysis of election results, 
allocation of campaign funding, and other informational purposes.

But having this preference inf

Re: [Election-Methods] Improved Approval Runoff

2007-08-15 Thread Dave Ketchum
On Thu, 16 Aug 2007 01:04:21 +0100 James Gilmour wrote:
> Dave Ketchum> Sent: 15 August 2007 22:57
> 
>>On most elections many, if not most, voters' preference will be a single 
>>candidate.
> 
> 
> On what basis do you say that?  Surely it is, to a very great extent, a 
> function of the voting system.  If the voting
> system says (directly or indirectly) "pick one winner", then the voter's 
> preference will be one candidate.  It will also
> apply when there are only two candidates contesting the seat.
> 
First, I am writing from and for the US, where we have MANY elective 
offices.  While some offices have the potential for attracting more 
candidates if supported by a good election method, many will not often 
attract more than a couple of serious candidates.

When there is no good reason for more than a couple candidates, Plurality 
would be good enough - though I propose installing better voting methods 
to give their flexibility whenever it would be useful.
> 
> 
>> Why is this something to fight?
> 
> 
> This is not something to "fight", but it seems reasonable to offer the voters 
> a more sensitive voting system so that
> those voters who wish can express their preferences more fully, if we can 
> devise such a voting system.
> 
As I say above, the voting method should support voters selecting multiple 
candidates.

The problem to fight is twisting voters' arms to encourage them to select 
more candidates than their desires support.
> 
>>  One candidate can overshadow the competition.
> 
> 
> True, but not always the case.
> 
> 
>>  Voters can be loyal to their party.
> 
> 
> True, but not always the case.
> 
> 
> 
>>For occasional exception elections there will be more interest in voting 
>>for multiple candidates, and it is DESIRABLE to support this voting for 
>>whichever elections may inspire voter interest in such.
> 
> 
> Why would such elections be "exceptional"?  Surely at every election, if the 
> voter knows there is a chance her/his most
> preferred candidate may not win, that voter would welcome the opportunity to 
> express one or more additional preferences
> among the other candidates that might influence the outcome?
> 
To get into this game there must be a suitable election method (assumed 
for this discussion), and a suitable collection of candidates to interest 
this voter in backing more than one of them.

Write-ins can, if they choose, become extra candidates - but this becomes 
practical only if they choose to be serious about it.
> 
> 
>>Fighting complications that make the rules for deciding on winners hard to 
>>understand make such complications undesirable unless they provide major 
>>benefits.
> 
> 
> Avoidable complication is always to be avoided.  If the rules for your "new" 
> voting system are too hard to understand
> the electors will not support your proposed reform.

You seem to echo my thought.
> 
> James Gilmour

See also my related post:
[Election-Methods] Plurality + Approval + Condorcet.
Sat, 04 Aug 2007 18:10:05 -0400
-- 
  [EMAIL PROTECTED]people.clarityconnect.com/webpages3/davek
  Dave Ketchum   108 Halstead Ave, Owego, NY  13827-1708   607-687-5026
Do to no one what you would not want done to you.
  If you want peace, work for justice.




Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [Election-Methods] Improved Approval Runoff

2007-08-15 Thread James Gilmour
Dave Ketchum> Sent: 15 August 2007 22:57
> On most elections many, if not most, voters' preference will be a single 
> candidate.

On what basis do you say that?  Surely it is, to a very great extent, a 
function of the voting system.  If the voting
system says (directly or indirectly) "pick one winner", then the voter's 
preference will be one candidate.  It will also
apply when there are only two candidates contesting the seat.


>  Why is this something to fight?

This is not something to "fight", but it seems reasonable to offer the voters a 
more sensitive voting system so that
those voters who wish can express their preferences more fully, if we can 
devise such a voting system.

>   One candidate can overshadow the competition.

True, but not always the case.

>   Voters can be loyal to their party.

True, but not always the case.


> For occasional exception elections there will be more interest in voting 
> for multiple candidates, and it is DESIRABLE to support this voting for 
> whichever elections may inspire voter interest in such.

Why would such elections be "exceptional"?  Surely at every election, if the 
voter knows there is a chance her/his most
preferred candidate may not win, that voter would welcome the opportunity to 
express one or more additional preferences
among the other candidates that might influence the outcome?


> Fighting complications that make the rules for deciding on winners hard to 
> understand make such complications undesirable unless they provide major 
> benefits.

Avoidable complication is always to be avoided.  If the rules for your "new" 
voting system are too hard to understand
the electors will not support your proposed reform.

James Gilmour


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [Election-Methods] Improved Approval Runoff

2007-08-15 Thread Dave Ketchum
On most elections many, if not most, voters' preference will be a single 
candidate.  Why is this something to fight?
  One candidate can overshadow the competition.
  Voters can be loyal to their party.

For occasional exception elections there will be more interest in voting 
for multiple candidates, and it is DESIRABLE to support this voting for 
whichever elections may inspire voter interest in such.

Fighting complications that make the rules for deciding on winners hard to 
understand make such complications undesirable unless they provide major 
benefits.

DWK

On Wed, 15 Aug 2007 17:00:59 -0300 Diego Renato wrote:
> All one-round voting systems that allows ballot truncation are 
> vulnerable to bullet voting, resulting the same results of plurality 
> voting. For instance, suppose that some voter has A as his/her first 
> preference. S/he can vote like this:
> 
> Approval: A: approved; B: rejected; C: rejected; D: rejected ...
> Range (0 - 100 scale): A: 100; B: 0; C: 0; D: 0 ...
> Preferential (IRV, Condorcet, etc): A>B=C=D=...
> 
> Additionally, there are several instances which only binary input voting 
> systems are reasonable. Complex systems are hard to adopt in 
> low-educated underdeveloped countries.
> 
> This system, called Improved Approval Runoff (IAR), has the goal to 
> resist bullet voting through simple ballots.
> 
> Description:
> 
> 1) On the first round, the voter can vote for as many or as few 
> candidates as desired.
> 2) If some candidate has more than 50% of approvals, the most approved 
> is elected.
> 3) If not, that candidate runs a second round against other candidate - 
> the most approved after a new count which the votes for the first one 
> are reweighted to 1/2.
> 4) The winner is the candidate who receives a majority of votes on the 
> second round.
> 
> On computer simulations, the top-two approval runoff method selected 
> more times the Condorcet winner than any Condorcet method. I think that 
> IAR is slightly fairer than top-two approval runoff under real voters.
> 
> Any comments?
>  
> 
> Diego Santos
-- 
  [EMAIL PROTECTED]people.clarityconnect.com/webpages3/davek
  Dave Ketchum   108 Halstead Ave, Owego, NY  13827-1708   607-687-5026
Do to no one what you would not want done to you.
  If you want peace, work for justice.




Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


[Election-Methods] Improved Approval Runoff

2007-08-15 Thread Diego Renato
All one-round voting systems that allows ballot truncation are vulnerable to
bullet voting, resulting the same results of plurality voting. For instance,
suppose that some voter has A as his/her first preference. S/he can vote
like this:

Approval: A: approved; B: rejected; C: rejected; D: rejected ...
Range (0 - 100 scale): A: 100; B: 0; C: 0; D: 0 ...
Preferential (IRV, Condorcet, etc): A>B=C=D=...

Additionally, there are several instances which only binary input voting
systems are reasonable. Complex systems are hard to adopt in low-educated
underdeveloped countries.

This system, called Improved Approval Runoff (IAR), has the goal to resist
bullet voting through simple ballots.

Description:

1) On the first round, the voter can vote for as many or as few candidates
as desired.
2) If some candidate has more than 50% of approvals, the most approved is
elected.
3) If not, that candidate runs a second round against other candidate - the
most approved after a new count which the votes for the first one are
reweighted to 1/2.
4) The winner is the candidate who receives a majority of votes on the
second round.

On computer simulations, the top-two approval runoff method selected more
times the Condorcet winner than any Condorcet method. I think that IAR is
slightly fairer than top-two approval runoff under real voters.

Any comments?


Diego Santos

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info