Re: [EM] Learning from IRV's success

2011-07-08 Thread Kevin Venzke
Hi,

--- En date de : Ven 8.7.11, Kristofer Munsterhjelm  a 
écrit :
> Bob Richard wrote:
> > It turns that real live voters (including real live
> politicians) care a lot about the later-no-harm criterion,
> even if they don't know what it's called.
> > 
> 
> If true, that is unfortunate. Perhaps we would have to pick
> a better criterion that is also easy to understand,
> something like the (weak) Favorite Betrayal Criterion. But
> if we have to do that, then a lot of otherwise good methods
> go out the window.

Well, you can modify MinMax to satisfy FBC. But, you have to figure out
what to do when it returns more than one unbeaten candidate. First-
preference count is the most obvious general fix. Probably violates
Plurality. "Total support" would be better but brings in an additional
concept...

Yes, I think that if FPP didn't have such strong nomination 
disincentive, voters would be more concerned about the principle of not
having to lie about who their favorite is. As things are, who other than
a "third-party extremist" would ever need to worry about it?

It's too bad there is no conclusive, persuasive way to measure LNHarm or
FBC performance. There's certainly better and worse among methods that
fail.

Kevin Venzke


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Learning from IRV's success

2011-07-08 Thread Dave Ketchum

On Jul 8, 2011, at 10:43 AM, Juho Laatu wrote:

On 8.7.2011, at 17.16, Andy Jennings wrote:

Also, I think IRV's seemingly intuitive nature has something to do  
with it. For those who *did* investigate more deeply, IRV seemed  
sensible, too: instead of holding a bunch of expensive runoffs,  
collect all the required information at once and then act as if  
there were runoffs. That fails to account for the dynamics between  
the rounds, but that's a subtle detail and might easily be missed.


I, too, must admit that IRV has a natural feeling to it.  I had a  
friend who described to me a system he thought of "on his own" and  
he ended up describing IRV.


And MANY of us asking for Condorcet probably see it as fitting the  
above description - for the voter.


It is when we notice that IRV counting can stray FAR from awarding to  
the CW, that our attention can turn to Condorcet which:

. Has counting that awards to deserving candidates.
. Can easily handle equal ranking.
. Can learn to award to write-ins (when they are deserving).

Dave Ketchum


I agree with that (as one reason). It is a bit  like natural  
selection, or a like fight of strong men where the weakest ones must  
leave the arena first.


Juho




Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Learning from IRV's success

2011-07-08 Thread Juho Laatu
On 8.7.2011, at 17.16, Andy Jennings wrote:

> Also, I think IRV's seemingly intuitive nature has something to do with it. 
> For those who *did* investigate more deeply, IRV seemed sensible, too: 
> instead of holding a bunch of expensive runoffs, collect all the required 
> information at once and then act as if there were runoffs. That fails to 
> account for the dynamics between the rounds, but that's a subtle detail and 
> might easily be missed.
> 
> I, too, must admit that IRV has a natural feeling to it.  I had a friend who 
> described to me a system he thought of "on his own" and he ended up 
> describing IRV.

I agree with that (as one reason). It is a bit  like natural selection, or a 
like fight of strong men where the weakest ones must leave the arena first.

Juho





Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Learning from IRV's success

2011-07-08 Thread Jameson Quinn
2011/7/8 Andy Jennings 

> Also, I think IRV's seemingly intuitive nature has something to do with it.
>> For those who *did* investigate more deeply, IRV seemed sensible, too:
>> instead of holding a bunch of expensive runoffs, collect all the required
>> information at once and then act as if there were runoffs. That fails to
>> account for the dynamics between the rounds, but that's a subtle detail and
>> might easily be missed.
>>
>
> I, too, must admit that IRV has a natural feeling to it.  I had a friend
> who described to me a system he thought of "on his own" and he ended up
> describing IRV.
>

If "most likely to be independently reinvented" is the criterion, Borda wins
by a country mile. Bucklin is also compelling that way.

JQ

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Learning from IRV's success

2011-07-08 Thread Andy Jennings
>
> Also, I think IRV's seemingly intuitive nature has something to do with it.
> For those who *did* investigate more deeply, IRV seemed sensible, too:
> instead of holding a bunch of expensive runoffs, collect all the required
> information at once and then act as if there were runoffs. That fails to
> account for the dynamics between the rounds, but that's a subtle detail and
> might easily be missed.
>

I, too, must admit that IRV has a natural feeling to it.  I had a friend who
described to me a system he thought of "on his own" and he ended up
describing IRV.

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Learning from IRV's success

2011-07-08 Thread Kristofer Munsterhjelm

Bob Richard wrote:
It turns that real live voters (including real live politicians) care 
a lot about the later-no-harm criterion, even if they don't know what 
it's called.




If true, that is unfortunate. Perhaps we would have to pick a better 
criterion that is also easy to understand, something like the (weak) 
Favorite Betrayal Criterion. But if we have to do that, then a lot of 
otherwise good methods go out the window.


On the other hand, both Nanson and Bucklin has been used in the US, and 
neither of these pass LNHarm.



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Learning from IRV's success

2011-07-08 Thread Kristofer Munsterhjelm

Jameson Quinn wrote:
Russ's message about simplicity is well-taken. But the most successful 
voting reform is IRV - which is far from being the simplest reform. Why 
has IRV been successful?


I want to leave this as an open question for others before I try to 
answer it myself. The one answer which wouldn't be useful would be 
"Because CVD (now FairVote) was looking for a single-winner version of 
STV". There's a bit of truth there, but it's a long way from the whole 
truth, and we want to find lessons we can learn from moving forward, not 
useless historical accidents.


I think there's that -- and the general confusion between ranked 
balloting in general and IRV in particular. FV has kept the two linked 
together, in effect giving a depiction of the sort: "Hey, don't you just 
loathe spoilers? Wouldn't it be better if you could rank the candidates 
so that there are no spoilers? Well, with IRV, you can!".


This seemed sensible enough at first glance, so IRV was accepted. It was 
a dangerous move: it could get IRV into elections more quickly, but if 
the voters found out that IRV provided bad results, they could turn 
against ranked ballots in general.


Also, I think IRV's seemingly intuitive nature has something to do with 
it. For those who *did* investigate more deeply, IRV seemed sensible, 
too: instead of holding a bunch of expensive runoffs, collect all the 
required information at once and then act as if there were runoffs. That 
fails to account for the dynamics between the rounds, but that's a 
subtle detail and might easily be missed.



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Learning from IRV's success

2011-07-07 Thread Dave Ketchum

On Jul 7, 2011, at 7:40 PM, Bob Richard wrote:

It turns that real live voters (including real live politicians)  
care a lot about the later-no-harm criterion, even if they don't  
know what it's called.


They need to learn that Condorcet offers less painful response than  
what IRV is offering.



Dave Ketchum


--Bob Richard

On 7/7/2011 3:43 PM, Juho Laatu wrote:


I actually already touched this question in another mail. And the  
argument was that (in two-party countries) IRV is not as risky  
risky from the two leading parties' point of view as methods that  
are more "compromise candidate oriented" (instead of being "first  
preference oriented"). I think that is one reason, but it is hard  
to estimate how important.


Juho

On 7.7.2011, at 23.56, Jameson Quinn wrote:

Russ's message about simplicity is well-taken. But the most  
successful voting reform is IRV - which is far from being the  
simplest reform. Why has IRV been successful?


I want to leave this as an open question for others before I try  
to answer it myself. The one answer which wouldn't be useful would  
be "Because CVD (now FairVote) was looking for a single-winner  
version of STV". There's a bit of truth there, but it's a long way  
from the whole truth, and we want to find lessons we can learn  
from moving forward, not useless historical accidents.


JQ
--

Bob Richard
Executive Vice President
Californians for Electoral Reform
PO Box 235
Kentfield, CA 94914-0235
415-256-9393
http://www.cfer.org

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Learning from IRV's success

2011-07-07 Thread Bob Richard
It turns that real live voters (including real live politicians) care a 
lot about the later-no-harm criterion, even if they don't know what it's 
called.


--Bob Richard


On 7/7/2011 3:43 PM, Juho Laatu wrote:

I actually already touched this question in another mail. And the argument was that (in two-party 
countries) IRV is not as risky risky from the two leading parties' point of view as methods that 
are more "compromise candidate oriented" (instead of being "first preference 
oriented"). I think that is one reason, but it is hard to estimate how important.

Juho



On 7.7.2011, at 23.56, Jameson Quinn wrote:


Russ's message about simplicity is well-taken. But the most successful voting 
reform is IRV - which is far from being the simplest reform. Why has IRV been 
successful?

I want to leave this as an open question for others before I try to answer it myself. The 
one answer which wouldn't be useful would be "Because CVD (now FairVote) was looking 
for a single-winner version of STV". There's a bit of truth there, but it's a long 
way from the whole truth, and we want to find lessons we can learn from moving forward, 
not useless historical accidents.

JQ

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info



--
Bob Richard
Executive Vice President
Californians for Electoral Reform
PO Box 235
Kentfield, CA 94914-0235
415-256-9393
http://www.cfer.org


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Learning from IRV's success

2011-07-07 Thread Juho Laatu
I actually already touched this question in another mail. And the argument was 
that (in two-party countries) IRV is not as risky risky from the two leading 
parties' point of view as methods that are more "compromise candidate oriented" 
(instead of being "first preference oriented"). I think that is one reason, but 
it is hard to estimate how important.

Juho



On 7.7.2011, at 23.56, Jameson Quinn wrote:

> Russ's message about simplicity is well-taken. But the most successful voting 
> reform is IRV - which is far from being the simplest reform. Why has IRV been 
> successful?
> 
> I want to leave this as an open question for others before I try to answer it 
> myself. The one answer which wouldn't be useful would be "Because CVD (now 
> FairVote) was looking for a single-winner version of STV". There's a bit of 
> truth there, but it's a long way from the whole truth, and we want to find 
> lessons we can learn from moving forward, not useless historical accidents.
> 
> JQ
> 
> Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Learning from IRV's success

2011-07-07 Thread robert bristow-johnson


On Jul 7, 2011, at 4:56 PM, Jameson Quinn wrote:

Russ's message about simplicity is well-taken. But the most  
successful voting reform is IRV - which is far from being the  
simplest reform. Why has IRV been successful?


how can one answer a question when one does not accept the premise of  
it?


my take is that IRV is only successful when it elects the Condorcet  
winner.


I want to leave this as an open question for others before I try to  
answer it myself. The one answer which wouldn't be useful would be  
"Because CVD (now FairVote) was looking for a single-winner version  
of STV". There's a bit of truth there, but it's a long way from the  
whole truth, and we want to find lessons we can learn from moving  
forward, not useless historical accidents.


are you defining "successful" in that it may have a foothold usage in  
governmental elections whereas Condorcet has not been used in such?


--

r b-j  r...@audioimagination.com

"Imagination is more important than knowledge."





Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info