Re: [EM] Simplest paper count to produce a winner in the smith set.

2011-11-29 Thread Kristofer Munsterhjelm

Clinton Mead wrote:
What would be the simplest paper count that will produce a winner in the 
smith set?


I'm not completely sure how your method works, but how about this?

Count the number of ballots on which each candidate is ranked (in any 
position). Call each candidate's count his approval score. Then while 
there is more than one candidate left, eliminate the pairwise loser of 
the two remaining candidates with the least approval score.


Eliminating losers won't turn a ranked candidate into a non-ranked 
candidate (or vice versa), so unlike IRV, you don't have to do a recount 
for every round.


It should also pick a winner from the Smith set. Say all but one of the 
Smith set candidates have been eliminated. Then the remaining Smith set 
candidate will, by definition of the Smith set, beat everybody else 
pairwise, and so nobody will be able to eliminate him. Therefore, that 
remaining Smith set member will be elected. QED.


The counting burden isn't that hard, either: you need one pass to 
calculate the approval scores, and then (n-1) (for n candidates) 
pairwise counts. I don't think you can do better than (n-1) pairwise 
counts and still be sure to elect someone in the Smith set.


You could replace the approval count with a Plurality count to get 
something simpler, but that could also be unfair to Smith set candidates 
that have few first place votes, and it wouldn't be consistent: 
eliminating candidates from a Plurality count would mean other 
candidates could be exposed, and so you'd have to recount as in IRV.



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Simplest paper count to produce a winner in the smith set.

2011-11-29 Thread Clinton Mead
On Wed, Nov 30, 2011 at 2:47 AM, Kristofer Munsterhjelm 
km_el...@lavabit.com wrote:

 Clinton Mead wrote:

 What would be the simplest paper count that will produce a winner in the
 smith set?


 Then while there is more than one candidate left, eliminate the pairwise
 loser of the two remaining candidates with the least approval score.


I was thinking the a similar thing, but then I looked at typical election
first preference counts, which are often like the following like the
following (at least in Australia).

Major Party 1: 41%
Major Party 2: 39%
Minor Party 1: 10%
Minor Party 2: 3%
Minor Party 3: 2%
Minor Party 4: 2%
Minor Party 5: 2%
Minor Party 6: 1%

Producing this entails one pass through the ballot (100% of papers need to
be examined for one preference). This is the base line for FPP.

For IRV, we can eliminate the 6 minor candidates in bulk, because they sum
to less than the vote of the second candidate. So then we reexamine the 6
minor party candidates for preferences. This means we have to look at 20%
more votes.

Our total work of IRV: 120% of FPP.

For the method you suggest (with the minor difference that I'll use first
preference to initially rank ballots) we need 100% work to do the first
count, then, with Minor Party 6 and Minor Party 5 on a total of 3%, we need
to look at the other 97% of ballots to do a pairwise comparison. Then we
eliminate the pairwise loser, then we have to look at 95% of the remaining
ballots to compare Minor 5/6 with Minor 4, etc.

We get a result which might involve 400-500% more looks at ballot papers
than FPP.

The method I suggest is slightly different in that it starts from the top.
We compare the top two candidates pairwise, this involves looking at 100%
of the votes to do the first preference count, and an additional 20% to do
the two candidate count. We're now at 120% of the work of FPP (one could
say you could do the first preference and two candidate in the same pass,
but this doesn't significantly lower the work, the time consuming work is
looking for preferences, not flicking through ballot papers).

Now, lets say Major Party 2 beats Major Party 1 pairwise. Then we
distribute Major Party 1's preferences. This takes looking at 41% of the
votes.

Now we're at 161%.

If Major Party 2 now has a majority, we have a winner. But if it doesn't,
we pairwise compare Major Party 2 with Minor Party 1.

This involves looking at all of the other minors vote, which is 10%. If
Major Party 2 beats Minor Party 1, it probably has a majority, if it
doesn't, it's very close, and will quickly get a majority as it defeats
other minor candidates pairwise and distributes their preferences.

If Minor Party 1 beats Major Party 2 however, then we need to distribute
Major Party 2's preferences,  which involves looking at another 39-50% of
the ballots.

At this point, it is likely Minor Party 1 has a majority (particularly
considering Major 1 and Major 2 are eliminated). If this is the case, we
then just need to check Minor Party 1 v Major Party 1 pairwise. This
involves looking at the 49% of votes which are not theirs. If Minor Party 1
pairwise beats Major Party 1, it is the winner, if Major Party 1 beats
Minor Party 1, we have a cycle (Major Party 1  Major Party 2  Minor Party
1  Major Party 1) and we resolve this in favour of the first preference
winner.

The idea of this method is that it typically takes only 160% or so of the
work of a FPP, and in the worse (typical) case perhaps 250% or at most 300%
of the work of a FPP count. In particular, it's not particularly burdensome
compared to IRV, which in the best case is around 120% and in the worse
case around 200%.

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Simplest paper count to produce a winner in the smith set.

2011-11-29 Thread Jameson Quinn
You can eliminate all candidates that have less than half the top approval
score, immediately. Australia is a bad example because they require full
ranking; but without that requirement, you could expect that each
candidate's approval total will be something on the order of min(50%,
2xFirst choices). Using the numbers you gave, that would mean only 3
parties left after elimination.

Jameson

2011/11/29 Clinton Mead clintonm...@gmail.com



 On Wed, Nov 30, 2011 at 2:47 AM, Kristofer Munsterhjelm 
 km_el...@lavabit.com wrote:

 Clinton Mead wrote:

 What would be the simplest paper count that will produce a winner in the
 smith set?


 Then while there is more than one candidate left, eliminate the pairwise
 loser of the two remaining candidates with the least approval score.


 I was thinking the a similar thing, but then I looked at typical election
 first preference counts, which are often like the following like the
 following (at least in Australia).

 Major Party 1: 41%
 Major Party 2: 39%
 Minor Party 1: 10%
 Minor Party 2: 3%
 Minor Party 3: 2%
 Minor Party 4: 2%
 Minor Party 5: 2%
 Minor Party 6: 1%

 Producing this entails one pass through the ballot (100% of papers need to
 be examined for one preference). This is the base line for FPP.

 For IRV, we can eliminate the 6 minor candidates in bulk, because they sum
 to less than the vote of the second candidate. So then we reexamine the 6
 minor party candidates for preferences. This means we have to look at 20%
 more votes.

 Our total work of IRV: 120% of FPP.

 For the method you suggest (with the minor difference that I'll use first
 preference to initially rank ballots) we need 100% work to do the first
 count, then, with Minor Party 6 and Minor Party 5 on a total of 3%, we need
 to look at the other 97% of ballots to do a pairwise comparison. Then we
 eliminate the pairwise loser, then we have to look at 95% of the remaining
 ballots to compare Minor 5/6 with Minor 4, etc.

 We get a result which might involve 400-500% more looks at ballot papers
 than FPP.

 The method I suggest is slightly different in that it starts from the top.
 We compare the top two candidates pairwise, this involves looking at 100%
 of the votes to do the first preference count, and an additional 20% to do
 the two candidate count. We're now at 120% of the work of FPP (one could
 say you could do the first preference and two candidate in the same pass,
 but this doesn't significantly lower the work, the time consuming work is
 looking for preferences, not flicking through ballot papers).

 Now, lets say Major Party 2 beats Major Party 1 pairwise. Then we
 distribute Major Party 1's preferences. This takes looking at 41% of the
 votes.

 Now we're at 161%.

 If Major Party 2 now has a majority, we have a winner. But if it doesn't,
 we pairwise compare Major Party 2 with Minor Party 1.

 This involves looking at all of the other minors vote, which is 10%. If
 Major Party 2 beats Minor Party 1, it probably has a majority, if it
 doesn't, it's very close, and will quickly get a majority as it defeats
 other minor candidates pairwise and distributes their preferences.

 If Minor Party 1 beats Major Party 2 however, then we need to distribute
 Major Party 2's preferences,  which involves looking at another 39-50% of
 the ballots.

 At this point, it is likely Minor Party 1 has a majority (particularly
 considering Major 1 and Major 2 are eliminated). If this is the case, we
 then just need to check Minor Party 1 v Major Party 1 pairwise. This
 involves looking at the 49% of votes which are not theirs. If Minor Party 1
 pairwise beats Major Party 1, it is the winner, if Major Party 1 beats
 Minor Party 1, we have a cycle (Major Party 1  Major Party 2  Minor Party
 1  Major Party 1) and we resolve this in favour of the first preference
 winner.

 The idea of this method is that it typically takes only 160% or so of the
 work of a FPP, and in the worse (typical) case perhaps 250% or at most 300%
 of the work of a FPP count. In particular, it's not particularly burdensome
 compared to IRV, which in the best case is around 120% and in the worse
 case around 200%.

 
 Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info