Re: [EM] Recursive Elimination Supervisor

2001-02-27 Thread Forest Simmons

Tony, I am a little worried that this simplification gives room for a
"Independence of Irrelevant Alternatives" problem to creep in.

Many methods suffer from this IIA problem (which says that the Winner
shouldn't change when some other candidate sits out) and it may be too
much to expect that we can make IIA hold in our recursion, yet in a way
a weak variant of IIA is the whole basis of my idea:

Weak version of IIA: The winner shouldn't change if the worst candidate is
thrown out.  This seems like a reasonable requirement for a decent method.

The unsimplified version implicitly uses a slightly stronger version (but
still close to the weak version): The winner shouldn't change if the worst
candidate or next to the worst candidate is thrown out.

In this simplified version we're using a much stronger version of IIA: The
winner shouldn't change if the Seed Loser is thrown out (unless the winner
is the seed loser).

Forest

  

On Tue, 27 Feb 2001, Forest Simmons wrote:

> Tony,
> 
> here's a simpler version of the Recursive Elimination Supervisor,
> based on a suggestion of yours.
> 
> Step 1.  Use the seed method in reverse to find the "Seed Loser" SL, from
> among the N candidates.
> 
> Step 2.  While the SL sits out, recursively supervise the seed method to
> find an N-1 stage recursive winner RW from among the N-1 remaining
> candidates.
> 
> Step 3.  Compare SL and RW directly.  Whichever is better is the N stage
> recursive winner. In case of a tie between these two, choose RW.
> 
> 
> Forest
> 
> 





Re: [EM] Recursive Elimination Supervisor

2001-02-27 Thread Forest Simmons

Tony,

here's a simpler version of the Recursive Elimination Supervisor,
based on a suggestion of yours.

Step 1.  Use the seed method in reverse to find the "Seed Loser" SL, from
among the N candidates.

Step 2.  While the SL sits out, recursively supervise the seed method to
find an N-1 stage recursive winner RW from among the N-1 remaining
candidates.

Step 3.  Compare SL and RW directly.  Whichever is better is the N stage
recursive winner. In case of a tie between these two, choose RW.


Forest




Re: [EM] Recursive Elimination Supervisor

2001-02-24 Thread MIKE OSSIPOFF



Interesting. This might turn out to be the best IRV mitigation.
Not that IRV advocates have ever accepted any mitigation. As I always
say, they seem determined to impose all the worst of IRV on the voting
public. But mitigations such as this should be offered to them, so
that we can later show that not only did they know about IRV's problems,
but they were also offered a number of mitigation compromises, none
of which they accepted.

Then there's always the possibility that a new method can turn out
to be one of the best, or maybe the best, in some important regard.

It would be a mistake to take it as certain that the best methods
known so far will always be the best known methods, and so sometimes
we've checked out new methods to find out if they challenge Condorcet
for the title of the best. So far none of them have, but when a new
method looks good, it should of course be checked out, and so let's
find out if this particular new method is up there with the best.

Mike Ossipoff

_
Get your FREE download of MSN Explorer at http://explorer.msn.com




[EM] Recursive Elimination Supervisor

2001-02-24 Thread Tony Simmons

Forest,

I found your scheme fascinating, and it worked with an
example or two I tried it with.

For three candidates, we first select one who wins
conventional IRV, and who we can figure is unlikely to be the
CL.  We're not sure, but that isn't necessary, since the
principal purpose of this step is just to cut the number of
candidates in the next step to two.

Then we compare the two "lower" candidates.  The one who
loses this comparison is definitely not the CW, and is
eliminated from counting.

Next, we compare the two remaining candidates.  Since the
candidate already completely eliminated is not CW, one of the
remaining two must be the CW, if there is one, and that is
the one that wins.

You have invented a Ranked Pairs method!

What's interesting is the way the method deals with a
situation in which there is no CW.  I haven't thought through
the complications sufficiently to know, but with three
candidates, is there a likelihood that your method would pick
a different winner than straight IRV?

Some other interesting things:  The first step is to find a
temporary IRV winner in order to find the first loser.  How
about just using IRV inverted to elect a first loser
directly?  Then eliminate him/her/it, transfer votes and
proceed as usual.

Or suppose:

1.  Use IRV to select a temporary winner, say, A.

2.  Select a loser from between B and C, say it's C.
That leaves A and B.

3.  Select a winner from between A and B, say it's B.
That leaves A and C.

4.  Select a loser from between A and C.  Suppose it's A.
That leaves B and C.

5.  Select a winner from B and C.  Suppose it's C.  Stop
here and call C the winner.

You could keep iterating.  Does it converge to a single
winner every iteration?  If so, is it a better winner in some
sense than you'd get straight from IRV?

How much of a difference does it make if you use something
other than IRV?

Just some interesting possibilities.  I think.  Certainly an
interesting scheme.

Tony






[EM] Recursive Elimination Supervisor

2001-02-23 Thread Forest Simmons

Any trivial method can correctly distinguish winner and loser in a two way
contest.  How about a three way contest? 

The answer is the same, yes, any old trivial method can correctly
distinguish winner and loser in a three way contest, IF (this is one of
those big IF's) the method is not just left to its own devices, like some
forlorn latchkey child. 

For example, let's use IRV as a "seed method" for our recursion. IRV does
just fine in a two way single winner contest.  And for definiteness, let's
assume that our version of IRV breaks two way ties by drawing a ballot at
random.

Now, let's go to work on the three way contest:

Step 1.  Have IRV tell us which of the three candidates he thinks should
win, temporarily label this candidate SW (for Seed Winner), and set it
aside for later use.

Step 2.  Have IRV point out from among the remaining two candidates the
one that is the worst (or the tie breaker if they are tied.) IRV can handle
this because it is just a two way contest. Label this candidate RL (for
Recursive Loser).

Step 3. Trade in SW for RL, so that now, of the three, RL is sitting out.

Step 4.  While RL sits out, have IRV pick the winner from the other pair.
(IRV can do this because he can handle a two way contest.) This time label
IRV's pick W for Winner and give IRV a star on his forehead.

Here's why W deserves to be labeled as Winner: The candidate RL found in
step 3 could not be a deserving winner (or at least not uniquely so)
because IRV distinguished him to be a loser from among two candidates, and
IRV doesn't make mistakes on two way contests.  Therefore, a true winner
was to be found among the other two. In step 4 IRV picks a deserving
winner from among the two.

Notice that although IRV is prone to get into trouble when unsupervised,
a little guidance from the older children helps him to earn a gold star.

We have just shown that IRV can pick a three way winner when correctly
supervised.  Similarly (by switching the directions of all the
preferences) a well supervised IRV can pick a three way loser competently.

Now let's help IRV handle a single winner four way contest:

Step 1.  Have IRV pick a seed winner SW from the four candidates and set
this seed winner aside as before. 

Step 2.  Supervise IRV to pick a Recursive Loser RL from the other three
candidates.  IRV does fine on this task with supervision as we just
finished showing.  (This is a recursive step in the general case.)

Note that this RL is not a deserving winner, or at least not uniquely
so.

Step 3.  Trade in SW for RL, and note that with RL sitting out, there must
still be at least one deserving winner among the remaining three.

Step 4.  While RL sits out, supervise IRV to find the Winner W from the
remaining three candidates.  We showed above that IRV can handle this task
under supervision (This is also a recursive step in the general case.) 

It is easy to see that the Winner in step 4 is truly a deserving winner,
since she was competently chosen from a group of three that had to contain
a deserving winner. 

So under appropriate supervision IRV can handle four way contests.

Now let's do the general case.  To avoid the above cumbersome
circumlocutions that result from constant care to include the possibility
of multiple deserving winners, I give a version that doesn't apply when
there are ties or cycles of deserving winners:

Step 1.  Let IRV pick the Seed Winner SW from among the N candidates, and
set this SW aside temporarily.

Step 2.  Recursively supervise IRV to pick the Recursive Loser RL from the
remaining N-1 candidates.  (Our induction hypothesis is that supervised
IRV is competent for finding best and worst among N-1 candidates.) 

Step 3.  Trade in SW for RL, and note that with RL sitting out, the
remaining N-1 candidates must contain the true winner.

Step 4.  While RL sits out, recursively supervise IRV to pick the Winner
from among the other N-1 candidates. 

Comments:  In the first step we let IRV pick the seed winner just to make
him feel important.  The seed winner could be chosen at random, but we
don't want to hurt IRV's feelings, so we let IRV choose the one to set
aside, and give it a fancy name, "the seed winner."  

In practice it would only make a difference if there were multiple
deserving winners. In that case we can think of IRV's influence as
providing flavor to the winner.  Using another seed method besides IRV
would give a different flavored winner.

I'm too tired to write in the circumlocutions for the case of non-unique
deserving winners into this general recursion statement.  Let someone else
copy them from the first two sample induction steps above. 

I haven't done the details on paper, but I believe it can be easily proven
in an induction parallel to the recursion that all (big W) Winners and
"Recursive Losers" (RL's) in the recursion are Condorcet Winners of the
direct and reverse preference rankings, respectively, in the case where
deserving winners are unique. 

This super