Re: Harvesting open-access data as commercial add-ons

2002-04-18 Thread Steve Hitchcock

At 12:33 18/04/02 +0100, Stevan Harnad wrote:

My own sense is that there is nothing whatsoever to worry about if
commercial publishers and providers are re-using Open Access
content and services to enhance their own products and services.

... [remainder below]

Stevan,   There is a saying in business, for those who want to try and
divine the future, follow the money. We want open archives, but we want
them to be economically sustainable. The ability to make the self-archived
peer-reviewed literature freely available to users is predicated on
absorbing the costs of running these services. In arXiv's case it attracts
funding because it is incredibly efficient, whether viewed in terms of
presentation (cost per paper) or usage (cost per user). But it still costs
something.

Institutional funding support may offer more options in future, or
commercial companies may fund services. But if I were to paint a scenario
in 10 years in which the majority of open archives were managed or owned by
a monolithic commercial entity, you would be concerned. In such a case you
can be pretty sure that if the open access model was not serving the
business plan its future would be reconsidered.

The wider issue here - and I must admit, I didn't set out to address it on
this occasion, nor via all of these lists, but have been drawn in - is not
about commercial-publisher-baiting but debating the principle of who
funds open access, and about the implications of possibly surreptitious,
possibly not, incursions into open access archives by commercial interests.

As to the rest of the speculation, it wasn't mine.

Steve Hitchcock
Open Citation (OpCit) Project http://opcit.eprints.org/
IAM Research Group, Department of Electronics and Computer Science
University of Southampton SO17 1BJ,  UK
Email: sh...@ecs.soton.ac.uk
Tel:  +44 (0)23 8059 3256 Fax: +44 (0)23 8059 2865



On Thu, 18 Apr 2002, Steve Hitchcock wrote:

 Re: From FOS Newsletter, 4/15/02:
 http://www.mathematicsweb.org/mathematicsweb/show/

 The Mathematics Web portal is clearly Elsevier (if not
 overtly so, e.g. no logo). The preprint link takes you to the Mathematics
 Preprint Server. I've visited this site before and had no idea it was an
 Elsevier service

 This appears to be an example of Guedon's assertion with regard to 'open
 article archives' such as the Chemistry Preprint Server that: I believe
 Elsevier is testing ways to reconstruct a firm grip on the evaluation
 process of science in the digital context. How significant is the low-key
 approach to this, I wonder?

...
Yes, they are trying to reposition themselves in the market, add value,
hold on to what they have, extend it, become more essential to the
evaluation process, etc. etc. That is all fine. They may or may not
be successful. It does not matter in the least. Nor does it matter
that it is they (i.e., the commercial publishers, the ones with the
high-priced journals) that are doing it.

What matters is getting the peer-reviewed content up there, with free
full-text access, OAI-compliant and in the (research) public eye. That
may well add value to toll-based products and services as a side-effect,
but that is irrelevant. What is relevant is that (1) it is available for
free for all, at last, and that (2) it will in turn draw more of the
peer-reviewed content up there.

Please let us not forget that freeing all of this content online is our
first (and last!) goal. We are not dedicated to competing with, let
alone ruining, publishers, primary or secondary, commercial or
otherwise. What kind of a goal is that? We are dedicated to providing
open access to the peer reviewed literature.

As to what might be the eventual secondary effects of our efforts, over
and above reaching the goal of open access for the whole of this special
literature (at least 20,000 journals, 2 million articles annually), we
can speculate about what those effects might be, but it simply does not
matter.


http://www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/cm200304/cmselect/cmsctech/399/399we152.htm


Moreover, it would be a mistake to focus on these speculations,
because they distract us from our real goal -- and, in an odd way,
focussing on such irrelevant speculations (e.g., in the form of
commercial-publisher-baiting) instead of our goal is and has been one
of the many things that have actually been holding us back from open
itself, as well as provoking needless opposition to open access from
publishers.

My own guess is that whereas now, while we are still in the era of
toll-access to most of this literature, the open-access archives and
services will (among other things) provide an added value to commercial
goods and services, they will also be providing (and irreversibly
converting use and users to) open access (our explicit goal). That means
that all users whose institutions cannot afford the toll-access, and
perhaps also those who can, will access this literature for free rather
than for fee, forever.

Then what about 

Re: Harvesting open-access data as commercial add-ons

2002-04-18 Thread Stevan Harnad
On Thu, 18 Apr 2002, Steve Hitchcock wrote:

 There is a saying in business, for those who want to try and
 divine the future, follow the money. We want open archives, but we want
 them to be economically sustainable. The ability to make the self-archived
 peer-reviewed literature freely available to users is predicated on
 absorbing the costs of running these services. In arXiv's case it attracts
 funding because it is incredibly efficient, whether viewed in terms of
 presentation (cost per paper) or usage (cost per user). But it still costs
 something.

That is one of the many reasons why I favour distributed
instititutional archiving rather than central:

Central vs. Distributed Archives
http://www.ecs.soton.ac.uk/~harnad/Hypermail/Amsci/0293.html

Count the reasons:

(1) Distributed institutional self-archiving distributes the archiving
load and cost. At the individual university level, the cost per paper
of permanently archiving (reliably and interoperably) all its annual
research output in OAI-compliant Eprint Archives will be a negligible
part of the university's existing annual network infrastructural costs:
so small as to be not worth talking about.

(2) Distributed institutional self-archiving focusses the
costs/benefits of the self-archiving of institutional research output
on the relevant natural entity that is involved: That entity is not the
discipline as a whole, which is no entity at all, nor the publisher,
who is a service-provider rather than a research stake-holder, but the
researcher's own institution, the one that shares with the researcher
the benefits of research impact, and the costs of its loss, because
of toll-based access barriers.
http://www.ecs.soton.ac.uk/~harnad/Tp/nature4.htm
http://www.ecs.soton.ac.uk/~harnad/Tp/thes1.html

(3) Distributed institutional self-archiving is structured exactly along
the reciprocal golden-rule lines that are the most natural ones for
inducing researchers to self-archive: Give in order to receive. In
exchange for providing open access to their own research output,
institutions all gain access to one another's research output.

(4) Central archiving got the ball rolling in physics, but it is
growing too slowly even in physics, and has not generalized across
disciplines. Research institutions (i.e., universities) cover all
disciplines.

(5) Central archiving encourages old, proprietary ways of thinking about
this anomalous, giveaway research literature, including misleading
analogies to publishing, which also happens to be a centralized concept.

 Institutional funding support may offer more options in future, or
 commercial companies may fund services.

This is far too vague. The scenario for institutional self-archiving
and its support is clear. How (and why) commercial companies will or
would cover archiving costs is another matter.

But even apart from that, there is the question of how to get the
peer-reviewed research archived in open access archives in the first
place. Distributed institutional self-archiving has both a natural
motivation and an existing means for doing this. How do the current
re-uses that are being made of what little open-access content has been
self-archived to date (the subject, after all, of Steve Hitchcock's
posting) connect with the matter of archiving costs at all (negligible
as they are, on the distributed model)?

Note that two forms of parasitism are latent in all this
discussion:

(i) the parasitism of self-archived peer-reviewed papers on the
peer review provided (and funded) by the journals publisher

Clarification of parasitism and copyright
http://www.ecs.soton.ac.uk/~harnad/Hypermail/Amsci/1827.html

These costs are currently covered by the toll-access system
(subscription/license/pay-per-view) that still exists in parallel
with the nascent open-access system. The scenarios for the transition
to covering the essential costs in other ways, if/when it becomes
necessary, have already been discussed many times:
http://www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/cm200304/cmselect/cmsctech/399/399we152.htm

The True Cost of the Essentials (Implementing Peer Review)
http://www.ecs.soton.ac.uk/~harnad/Hypermail/Amsci/0303.html

Distinguishing the Essentials from the Optional Add-Ons
http://www.ecs.soton.ac.uk/~harnad/Hypermail/Amsci/1437.html

The True Cost of the Essentials
http://www.ecs.soton.ac.uk/~harnad/Hypermail/Amsci/1973.html

(ii) the parasitism of commercial re-use of self-archived papers by
commercial services

Here the parasitism is in the opposite direction, but irrelevant.

 But if I were to paint a scenario
 in 10 years in which the majority of open archives were managed or owned by
 a monolithic commercial entity, you would be concerned.

And that is one of the (many) reasons I am advocating distributed
institutional self-archiving rather than central. So stop worrying.
(And why paint needless scenarios?)

 In such a case you
 can be pretty sure that if the open access model