[PEN-L:5160] Re: the exploding Pinto and Gingrich

1995-05-19 Thread glevy

I don't have an exact figure to give in answer to Doug Orr's question but 
I do have a very interesting story to tell concerning exploding Pintos. 
In the period 1978-79, I worked as an assembler at Ford Motor Company's 
Metuchen (New Jersey) Assembly Plant where we built Ford Pintos and 
Mercury Bobcats.  Anyway, I worked mostly on the rear underbody line in 
the Chasis Department.  The person who installed gasoline tanks, who was 
a UAW Local 980 official, told me that he was told by an engineer about 
the problem BEFORE they built the first Pinto.  My friend asked the engineer:
"For God's sake, if you know there's a problem, why don't you fix it 
now?"  The engineer told him that they had costed out how much money it 
would cost to change the design (I believe he said 50 cents per car) and 
management determined (multiplying 50 cents times X-many million Pintos 
that the Company planned to sell) that the cost was too high!

I often think of this story when I hear about externalities and the 
arguments for and against deregulation.

On Fri, 19 May 1995, DOUG ORR wrote:

> It is amazing how pieces of important info. slip away.  Gingrich wants to
> limit the maximum product liability award to $250,000.  If I remember correctly,
> when Lee Iaccoca wrote his memo deciding to continue to sell Pintos that he
> knew would explode into flames in a collision, he used an estimate of
> $250,000 per affected car as a likely settlement amount and concluded that
> at that cost, it would be more cost effect to let people burn.  Does anyone
> out there remember the exact amount he used in his calculations?
> 
> Thanks,
> Doug Orr
> [EMAIL PROTECTED]
> 
> 



[PEN-L:5159] More trouble coming in Mexico

1995-05-19 Thread D Shniad

MEXICAN DEBT LOOMING AS AN EXPLOSIVE PROBLEM

According to figures by Mexico's Treasury
Secretariat, as of March 31, 1995, debt service has
increased in a very significant way:

 Total external public debt outstanding (3/31):
$87.5 bn dlls.
 Total external debt service payments (1Q):
$ 9.5 bn dlls.
 Total internal public debt outstanding (3/31):
$29.4 bn dlls.
 Total internal debt service payments (1Q):
$ 3.2 bn dlls.

As a percentage of Gross Domestic Product, in the
last three months the total public debt has
increased from 35 to 52.3%.  So despite the upbeat
talk from Mexican and U.S. government spokespeople,
it appears that it's just a matter of time until
the country's debt crisis explodes again.

 Source -- MEXPAS: Bulletin # 22, Information



[PEN-L:5158] Review of Goldsmith's The Trap

1995-05-19 Thread D Shniad

IN THESE TIMES -- APRIL 3,1995

MONEY ISN'T EVERYTHING

-- By Art Hilgart

How is it," Sir James Goldsmith asks, "that nearly
two hundred years after the birth of the Industrial
Revolution, which produced humanity's greatest
period of economic expansion, the absolute number
of those living in misery, both material and
social, has grown exponentially?" This is a rather
interesting question, especially considering its
source.  Goldsmith, a man who epitomizes the modem
paper capitalist, accumulated a very large fortune
before tuming 50, mostly through corporate
takeovers, stock speculation and generous rewards
for not taking over companies.  He consolidated his
holdings and gave up business for politics in 1987,
forming l'Autre Europe, a European Parliament
coalition of assorted leftists and conservatives
from several countries opposed to the growing power
of Brussels.
  If it seems a little out of the ordinary for an
ex-Master of the Universe to rhetorically question
the justice of capitalism in its golden age, that
is because Goldsmith is himself a bit of an odd
fish, a character of seemingly contradictory
inclinations.  A vigorous proponent of national
distinctiveness, Goldsmith is himself cosmopolitan.
French-bom, Goldsmith observes with delight that
the English think he is French and the French think
he is English.  While he describes his religious
views as a blend of the Far East and Native
American, he notes that Catholics think he is a Jew
and Jews think he is a Catholic.  A financial
speculator, he was the darling of socialist prime
minister Harold Wilson, who was ultimately
responsible for Goldsmith's knighthood.
  In The Trap, which reprises a series of
interviews with Yves Messarovitch, the economics
editor of Le Figaro, Goldsmith decries the brand of
globalism now purveyed by transnational
corporations and First World governments.  It is a
globalism that, in his view, subordinates human
interests to the unlimited pursuit of profit by
transnational corporations and that, through the
indiscriminate use of technology, transforms people
into disposable commodities.
  Goldsmith questions a fundamental premise of
ortholox economics, the idea that the primary
objective of society is growth in gross national
product (GNP).  One pitfall of endowing growth
figures with too much evaluative significance, he
notes, is that they can give a misleadingly
incomplete picture.  Any money transaction will
boost GNP, regardless of whether it truly
represents an augmentation of social well-being.
Growth in prison building and nuclear waste
disposal boosts GNP, as does transferring child
care from families to paid workers.  More
importantly, GNP growth is indifferent to the
distribution of wealth.  Not only in the Third
World but in England, France and the United States,
poverty has grown along with GNP.  Goldsmith blames
this growing maldistribution of income in large
part on free trade among nations and the
industrialization of agriculture.
  Traditionally, free trade theory has rested on
Ricardo's principle that aggregate production and
consumption are maximized when each country
produces goods for which it is best suited.
Nations with abundant coal resources, for example,
should export steel because they can produce it
more cheaply than countries without coal.  A
country's prosperity rests on its ability to
identify and exploit such "comparative advantages."
Goldsmith observes that this principle is becoming
less relevant in modern economies because the
important factors in modern comparative advantage -
- money and technology -- are now universally
transferable.  Intemational competition has thus
been reduced to a search for cheap labor.  The
clothing trade illustrates his point: many
"American" clothing manufacturers now move
equipment back and forth between countries like
China and Guatemala in their quest for the lowest
costs.  This competition for work creates downward
pressure on wages globally -- including those of
workers in the First World -- and brings in its
wake the grinding poverty and urban slums so common
throughout the world.
  Part of the solution to this problem, says
Goldsmith, is to allow the free movement of capital
and technology, but not goods.  If Ford wants to
sell cars in Mexico, then it should be required to
build plants in Mexico and make the cars there,
with access to patents, know-how and funding from
anywhere; the U.S. market, in the meantime, should
be served with cars made in the United States by
American workers. This may be in the strictest
sense less efficient, but it serves the human needs
of both countries. Mexican industry would have a
chance to develop, and American labor would
preserve its living standards and working
conditions.
  In modern economies, lower production costs do
not necessarily lead to lower prices.  Patents,
copyrights and trademarks confer monopoly pricing
power on sellers, and the latest GATT agreements
extend this control over prices globally. In an
asid

[PEN-L:5157] Debunking the IMF

1995-05-19 Thread D Shniad

AFRICA REPORT, November-December 1994

DEBUNKING THE MYTH

BLAME FOR AFRICA'S CONTINUING ECONOMIC DECLINE, THE
AUTHORS ARGUE, CAN BE LAID AT THE DOOR OF THE WORLD
BANK, THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND, AND THE
WESTERN DONOR NATIONS THAT HAVE ENTHUSIASTICALLY
SUPPORTED THEIR STRUCTURAL ADJUSTMENT PROGRAMS.
THE FAILED POLICY MUST BE HALTED, THE AUTHORS
CONTEND, AND ECONOMIC REFORM LENDING REORIENTED TO
STRENGTHEN PRODUCTIVE ACTIVITIES OF THE POOR --
PARTICULARLY WOMEN, WHO DO 80 PERCENT OF THE
AGRICULTURAL WORK IN AFRICA -- AND TO ENSURE SMALL
PRODUCERS ACCESS TO CREDIT AND INPUTS.


By DOUG HELLINGER and ROSS HAMMOND

  0ne of the great myths of the past decade is
finally being put to rest.
  Last year, U.S. Treasury Undersecretary Larry
Summers presented to the House of Representatives
evidence that poverty was sharply increasing in
Africa.  Not only was the number of poor people on
the rise, but those already poor actually were
becoming poorer.  The Treasury provided statistics
for this tragedy that unfolded during the 1980s,
the so-called "decade of adjustment" in which the
World Bank and the International Monetary Fund were
fully engaged in dictating economic policies across
the continent.
  News of Africa's economic decline may not have
come as a surprise to most people.  And the
Treasury's acknowledgment of reality was small
consolation to the people of Africa and to the many
African governments, NGOs, and UN agencies that had
been citing, for over a decade, the damaging
effects of structural adjustment.  But the
significance of Summers' submission to the Congress
was that it is the Treasury that has been the
greatest proponent of adjustment programs and that
it will be the U.S. government, and clearly not the
Bank and IMF bureaucracies, that will have to
signal a shift in direction if fundamental change
is to come to the international financial
institutions (IFIs).
  The Treasury is, in fact, now quietly discussing
the need for a change in policy, at least in the
case of Africa.  As a step in that direction, the
U.S. government, under pressure from NGOs at the
United Nations Summit for Social Development
preparatory committee meeting in New York in
August, recommended to the Secretariat that the
formulation of structural adjustment programs be
opened to the active participation of
"representative organizations of civil society." At
least lip-service was also paid to integrating
gender-equity and poverty-reduction objectives into
these policy programs and to increasing small-farm
productivity to satisfy local food needs.
  At this point, these are but words on a page.
Will they be translated into action?  To do so
would constitute a shift in emphasis, if not
course, in U.S. foreign policy.  It would also
eventually require fundamental turnabouts in
institutions that have been so intimately involved
as architects of Africa's economic disaster that
they have gone to great lengths to mislead the
public and policy-makers about the reality and
causes of the crisis.


The Bank's Tale
 
  Although the IMF, the U.S. Agency for
International Development (U.S.AID), and other
donors have also been involved in the Africa cover-
up, it was the World Bank that led the way.  Last
March, the Bank released yet another in a series of
public relations initiatives entitled, Adjustment
in Africa: Reforms, Results, and the Road Ahead.
In this volume, it claims that adjustment is
working in Africa and that countries that have most
closely followed its advice have grown the fastest,
directly contradicting even its own internal 1992
draft study entitled, "Why Structural Adjustment
Has Not Succeeded in Sub-Saharan Africa."
  Given the Bank's sorry record on the continent,
this most recent release and its companion case
studies were not well-received.  The BBC questioned
the Bank's self-interest in evaluating its own
policy prescriptions, while The Economist accused
the Bank of "complacency" on the issue of poverty
and stated that it "desperately needs to see
success," whatever the reality on the ground.
  One of the strongest reactions came from the
British charity, Oxfam, which condemned the report
as a "blend of half-truths, over-simplifications,
and institutional propaganda" and claimed that the
Bank "has lost any claim to intellectual and
political credibility."  Last year, Oxfam condemned
the "fundamental failure" of structural adjustment
programs in Africa "either to create a platform for
sustained economic recovery, or to enable the poor
to benefit from market reforms."  Even where
adjustment programs have led to modest increases in
economic growth, says Oxfam, "there is no evidence
that they have substantially reduced poverty
levels, or reduced trade deficits and inflation to
sustainable levels.  Moreover, their 'success' has
been based on substantial aid transfers, rather
than on investment-led recovery."
  Of the six countries that the Bank now puts
forward as adjustment "successes" -- Ghana,
Tanzania, the Gambia, B

[PEN-L:5156] Re: Usury & Exploitation

1995-05-19 Thread Jim Devine


This discussion may be a waste of time for others, but luckily it
isn't for me. (As he reminds me often, I can't speak for Gil.) It
allows me to add some important clarifying touches to a paper that
I'm finishing, one that tries to explain (rationally reconstruct)
the Marxian theory of exploitation in mainstream terms without
reducing that theory to mainstream ideology. It is helpful to have a
dialogue with someone who knows mainstream microeconomics much
better than I do. Thanks, Gil. I apologize to the list for any
repetition. But it's very easy to delete this without reading it.

On Fri, 19 May 1995, Gil Skillman writes:

1. >>Re Jim's most recent comments... I go back to the bottom line:
Jim asserts that some form of subsumption... is necessary for the
extraction of surplus value in Jim's sense of the term. This is a
very strong claim. Nobody, certainly not Jim, has established this
claim on grounds which do not presuppose the conclusion.<<

Saying that something is a "strong claim" simply implies the
question "strong by what standards?" This question is made less
vague if we ask "what is Gil's alternative hypothesis?" Gil's _null_
hypothesis, i.e., the one he's trying to _disprove_ is mine, i.e.,
that coercion is a necessary to the existence and persistence of
capitalist exploitation. His _alternative_ hypothesis, if I may make
an effort at mind-reading, would be the following:

AH1: People are willing to be "exploited" voluntarily under a
competitive market system, with no relations of coercion either
structural or instrumental, i.e., no subjection of labor by capital
of any kind.(*) (This is the conclusion of Roemer's models, in which
the scarcity of means of production is sufficient to allow
capitalists to "exploit" workers.)

The validity of AH1 depends on what we mean by "exploitation." More
importantly, this meaning helps distinguish my view from Gil's.
Since, as I've discovered, Gil thinks that the distinction between
primary and secondary exploitation is crucial, let's bring it in to
help.

Start with the latter, on which there is no disagreement, as far as
I can tell. If I remember correctly, Gil and I have _always_ agreed
that no coercion at all is needed for much or most secondary
exploitation, what Marx termed "the redistribution of surplus-value"
and others have called "unequal exchange" to occur, except on the
basic level of the state preserving property rights. Voluntary
exchange under competitive markets is sufficient. I am sure that Gil
remembers my analogy here: those rentiers who hold government bonds
need not engage directly in any kind of coercion to receive interest
incomes. The government's police force and IRS will do the coercive
job for them. For more on "secondary exploitation," see part 2.

But in order for there to be _redistribution_ of surplus-value (or
more generally a surplus-product), a surplus has to be produced. It
is this "primary exploitation" where I think coercion (subjection)
is needed. Further, secondary exploitation is _dependent on_ the
existence of coercion: without primary exploitation, i.e., the
creation of a surplus-product, secondary exploitation is simply the
redistribution of a fixed quantity of products.

So let's restate what I think of as Gil's alternative hypothesis,
which shows the _true_ basis of our differences.

AH2: People are willing to _produce_ a surplus-product and
voluntarily turn it over to others for a competitive market system,
with no subjection of labor by capital of any kind.

This is what I consider to be "a very strong claim." Further,
nobody, certainly not Gil, "has established this claim on grounds
which do not presuppose the conclusion."

In his recent work, Gil relies on the neoclassical principal/agent
literature, which _assumes_ that profits exist in the mythical "full
information" economy. Since the P/A problem is not necessarily
neoclassical, so Gil substitutes Roemer's Walrasianization of Marx
for this neoclassical tradition. But Roemer's view of the origins of
the surplus is based on poor theorizing or simply assuming that a
surplus-product is produced (as in the "isomorphism" theorem). Gary
Dymski and I criticized Roemer's main models in Economics &
Philosophy in 1989 and Roemer, in essence, agreed that we were
right. He totally agreed that the center-piece of his theory -- the
scarcity of means of production -- had no theoretical explanation
and then turned to the Marxian tradition that he had scorned
(including Rosa Luxemburg) for an explanation. At the time, neither
of us were impressed enough by the "isomorphism" theorem to think
that it was worth talking about. I've criticized the isomorphism
theorem several times in this debate and do not feel like repeating
my arguments further.

So I'll just leave what I think of as the true statement of Gil's
alternative hypothesis (AH2) as a statement of our disagreements.
Perhaps it will stimulate Gil to explain why workers voluntarily
choose to create a surplus-product in

[PEN-L:5155] the exploding Pinto and Gingrich

1995-05-19 Thread DOUG ORR

It is amazing how pieces of important info. slip away.  Gingrich wants to
limit the maximum product liability award to $250,000.  If I remember correctly,
when Lee Iaccoca wrote his memo deciding to continue to sell Pintos that he
knew would explode into flames in a collision, he used an estimate of
$250,000 per affected car as a likely settlement amount and concluded that
at that cost, it would be more cost effect to let people burn.  Does anyone
out there remember the exact amount he used in his calculations?

Thanks,
Doug Orr
[EMAIL PROTECTED]



[PEN-L:5154] CBPP and CTJ?

1995-05-19 Thread DOUG ORR

Can someone tell me how to get on the mailing list for the Center for Budget
and Policy Priorities and the Center for Tax Justice.  I keep finding 
references to the work, but it is usually several months after the release.
I would like to get it in a more timely fashion.
Thanks,
Doug Orr
[EMAIL PROTECTED]



[PEN-L:5153] Follow-up re NSF Funding Crisis

1995-05-19 Thread Doug Henwood

>From another list - Doug Henwood


>Please feel free to scroll to mid section of this post where action
>directives can be found.  APA has developed a letter that can be used as
>a format for your own letter, should you desire to forward one.  There
>are also other suggestions noted that might also be fairly simply to
>follow.
>
>Tammy Mann, Ph.D.
>SPSSI Fellow
>202-336-6068
>[EMAIL PROTECTED]
>*Forwarded Message Follows
>*
> American Psychological Association
>  Science Advocate Network
>
>
>! LEGISLATIVE ACTION ALERT !
>
> House Budget Resolution Targets Social, Behavioral
>and Economic Sciences at NSF
>
>The House and Senate Budget Committees approved the spending
>blueprint for FY 1996 last week.  This budget resolution
>determines the size of the federal budget for FY 1996, sets
>out spending priorities and provides guidance to the House and
>Senate Appropriations committees on how the federal budget
>should be allocated.  The House and Senate budget resolutions
>are accompanied by report language that goes into more detail
>on the fiscal assumptions made by the Committees in arriving
>at the recommended budget numbers.
>
>Included in the House Budget report language is the following
>statement regarding the recommendations for NSF: "This
>proposal assumes that while science and technology must
>contribute to the immediate fiscal reality, they must also
>provide for the opportunities that must be developed in the
>future.  In order for the technological revolution to
>continue, a strong, fundamental science is needed.  Therefore,
>the proposal assumes that basic research should be
>prioritized.  For instance, NSF CIVILIAN RESEARCH AND RELATED
>ACTIVITIES WITH THE EXCLUSION OF SOCIAL, BEHAVIORAL AND
>ECONOMIC STUDIES [capitals added] and the critical
>technologies institute, can be provided at their current
>levels plus three percent growth.  No reductions are assumed
>to NSF basic research in the physical sciences.  Education and
>Human Resources can be maintained and Academic Research
>Infrastructure is assumed at President Clinton's requested
>level."
>
>Rep. Robert Walker Throws Fuel on the Flames
>
>This disturbing language from the House Budget Committee was
>followed by statements from Rep. Robert Walker (R-PA) at a
>news conference on May 11, where he was quoted as saying that
>the "social, behavioral and economic STUDIES" [capitals added]
>at NSF were fields that NSF had "wandered into . . .[to be]
>politically correct."  Since Rep. Walker is Chair of the House
>Science Committee that authorizes NSF, is a top Republican on
>the House Budget Committee, and part of the House Republican
>leadership -- his remarks were taken very seriously concerning
>House Republican plans for behavioral and social science at
>NSF.
>
>  *
>  * APA Mobilizes *
>  *
>
>
>In immediate response to these developments, APA has done the
>following:
>
>
>  --- SENT THE FOLLOWING LETTER TO REP. WALKER ---
>
>
>The Honorable Robert S. Walker
>Chair
>House Science Committee
>2320 Rayburn House Office Bldg.
>Washington, DC 20515-6301
>
>Dear Mr. Chairman:
>
>I am writing on behalf of the American Psychological
>Association (APA), a scientific and professional organization
>of 132,000 psychologists, to object to your characterization
>of the behavioral and social sciences at the National Science
>Foundation (NSF).  In the May 12 Washington Post you were
>quoted as saying that the "social, behavioral and economic
>studies" (italics added) at NSF were fields that NSF had
>"wandered into . . .[to be] politically correct."  I would
>like to assure you that the behavioral and social sciences at
>NSF were not inadvertent additions meant to satisfy someone's
>notion of "political correctness."
>
>NSF support for basic research in the behavioral and social
>sciences is long-standing, and its importance to the
>scientific knowledge base has long been recognized by the
>wider scientific community that supported the creation of SBE.
>The Social, Behavioral and Economic Science (SBE) Directorate
>was created as a separate entity in 1991 in recognition of the
>maturity of the behavioral and social sciences, and to provide
>greater focus on the research base in these sciences.  This
>research had been supported at NSF for more than 40 years --
>long before the formal organization of these sciences into a
>Directorate.
>
>This followed extensive discussion both within NSF and within
>the research community regarding the merits of creating SBE.
>There was agreement in the biological, behavioral and social
>science community that this was the best way to support this
>valuable research.  In none of the many discussions and
>meetings held on the creation of SBE was there any hint of the
>impetus being "political correctness."

[PEN-L:5152] Re: Usury & Exploitation

1995-05-19 Thread GSKILLMAN

Re Jim's most recent comments on this subject, I go back to the 
bottom line:  Jim asserts that some form of subsumption (formal, 
real, or "macro") is necessary for the extraction of surplus value in 
Jim's sense of the term.  This is a very strong claim.  Nobody, 
certainly not Jim, has established this claim on grounds which do not 
presuppose the conclusion.  

Further, the claim is implausible.  If it's true, why isn't it the 
case that interest capitalists must subsume industrial capitalists in 
order to extract their piece of surplus value in modern 
capitalism?  Similarly, why don't landlords have to subsume 
industrial capitalists to achieve the same outcome?

Finally, contrary to Jim's suggestion, there is indeed a coherent 
historical-materialist explanation for the possibility of capitalist 
exploitation via circuits of capital or ground rent which do not 
presuppose the subsumption of labor under capital.  This explanation 
suggests, in direct opposition to Jim's (unproven) representation, 
that rendering producers "free in the double sense" (i.e. what 
Jim calls "macro" subsumption) makes exploitation harder, not easier, 
because capitalists cannot in that case demand collateral for loans, 
where they could do so in the era of usury and the putting-out system. 
Without this "stick", it becomes strategically much harder to get 
producers to cough up surplus product in return for access to 
capital.

Gil Skillman



[PEN-L:5151] Re: Brits, NZ, and inequality

1995-05-19 Thread M Schettino



On Tue, 16 May 1995, Jeff Oman wrote:

>  The sequence is as follows, more inequality reduces 
> >incentives to save (or to accumulate human capital) to the less 
> >favoured by the distribution. The amount of savings and human capital 
> >that is lost is not compensated by the savings and human capital of 
> >the rich ones. 
> 
> 
> You mean tinkle-down doesn't work? ; )
> Jeff Oman
> 
> 

Exactly. What I found is that poor people becomes poorer in time, 
since most of their capital returns (wether physical or human) go, in 
fact, to rich people. The reason behind, I suppose and I am trying to 
prove, has to do with institutions, in that the stability they provide 
also generates inertia in the way income is distributed.

MOst empirical evidence is closer to this approach than to 
trickle-down, but most theory (neoclassical theory) goes the other 
way. I think that if development theory can go anyway, this is it.

Macario



[PEN-L:5150] Re: Justice

1995-05-19 Thread Justin Schwartz


I agree that being a Marxist worth anything--i.e., a practical
revolutionary not just a Kathedersozialist--requires that we manifest
appropriate virtues, including justice, in our personal lives, and that
these virtues be broadly compatible with those of our comrades. Note that
"compatible" doesn't mean "the same"; we just have to be able to get along
in a way that fosters mutual respect and consideration and wins the
respect of those whgom we seek to organize. I don't think that there's a
specifically Marxist set of virtues, though--just the ordinary ones,
tinted red by our choice of sides.

The public schools question hits home for me, as I believe in the public
svchools, but we just decided to send our daughter to a private first
grade. Our local school, largely poor working class, is as far as we can
tell a fine school to which we'd be happy to send her, but it's too poor
to sustain a latchkey program. School starts at 9.15 and ends at 3.30, and
there's no way we can manage the pickup and dropoff, not with a working
Mom and a Dad in first year law school. Hannah was accepted at an
"alternative" lottery school, public, which had a latchkey, but janis and
I were deeply unimpressed by both the school and the latchkey, both on the
bottom end of mediocre, minimally acceptabvle if tgere was nothing else,
but no more than that. So we decided to keep herin private school for a
year to see if an opening comes along at a better alternative school OR if
after I finish One-L my schedule is more flexible and we can arrange
flextime for Janis, so we can swing the neighborhood school.

So, did we do wrong? I don't think so. N.B. we pay property taxes which
support the public schools and vote for every levy.

I don't think it is a failure of virtue to want the best for your kids.
Caring about your own kids is a virtue--someone who regards everyone's
kids as just as important to him or her as his or her own is either a
fanatic or neglectful. _How_ yhou care about them matters--if by a "good"
school for then you really mean "all white," you're indulging in closet or
not so closet racism. But you also don't help the public schools, the
anti-racist struggle, or your own kids by sending them to a crumby, much
less a dangerous school, merely because it is public.

Sometimes virtues lead to conflict--our values don't always point in the
same direction. The virtue of being a good parent and that of being a good
antiracicist and socialist may indicate different choices inb a matter of
where you send your kids to school. It did for us, and though we made what
we thought was the right choice, we feel the conflict and we'd rather send
Hannah to a public school, other things being not even equal but adequate.

Well, I thought I'd mention it.

--Justin Schwartz

On Fri, 19 May 1995, bill mitchell wrote:

> Curtis offered much more than is here:
> 
> [deletions]
> >  The book's fallacy lies in thinking that virtuous people will
> >grow up to become a virtuous society.  On the contrary, as
> >Reinhold Niebuhr taught us, there is a "basic difference between
> >the morality of individuals and the morality of collectives." 
> >Virtuous people grow up to hold news conferences putting
> >corporate concerns ahead of the common good.
> >
> [deletions]
> >
> >  I guess that the point of the above article as it relates to
> >Bill Mitchell's post (see below) is that we as individuals have
> >to do something MORE than simply practice personal virtues, or
> >society isn't going to get any better.  This something more
> >surely involves actively promoting a good social democratic
> >POLITICAL agenda as another PEN-ler pointed out in response to
> >Mitchell's post.  
> 
> And of-course i agree. and did i not say that in the stream of 
> mails on this topic.
> 
> but movements become corrupted unless the individuals have compatible
> values. 
> 
> it also raises the general issue off whether being a marxist extends into
> a personal code of conduct as well as the collective code of conduct and
> organisation. personally i feel it does, but i know others definately don't
> agree with me. 
> 
> we had this for example in the private/public school debate. progressives on
> this list said "sure i believe in the public sector, but not for my kids". i
> was and am implacably opposed to that view. how can your own children be
> more important than all the rest of the kids? at what point does socialism
> cease to work when the so-called progressives are willing to privatise gains
> at the 
> obvious expense of the collective?
> 
> there are many more examples and issues here. we can talk about it if people
> like. tonight (late friday afternoon) i still have a mountain of things to do.
> 
> kind regards
> bill
> **   
>  William F. MitchellTelephone: +61-49-215027  .-_|\   
>  Department of Economics   +61-49-705133 / \
>  The Universit

[PEN-L:5149] technological change and Africa today

1995-05-19 Thread jones/bhandari

In Trade, Development and Foreign Debt (London: Pluto Press, 1992) Michael
Hudson explains the polarization tendencies in the world economy, so
devastatingly demonstrated in  Africa this decade: 

"The preceding pages have established that economic obsolescence in less
developed countries is a direct function of more rapid rates of capital
formation, research, development and general technological progress in the
lead-nations.  The problem is that resources that are not modernised will
not be employed, unless prices for their output are supported by subsidies
and trade barriers.  These programmes may involve substantial economic
overhead to support or modernise obsolete labour, land and capital.  Not to
undertake such public spending is to doom the least developed countries to
a fate of world mendicancy.  Yet IMF austerity programmes block such
investment." (222-223)

Hudson continues: "The logical international culmination of this
polarization process was described in 1864 by the Rev. W Winwood Reade with
regard to the African population: 

This vast continent...will finally be divided almost equally between France
and England.
In N Africa, France already possesses the germ of a great military empire. 
She will ally herself with the Mohammedan powers.  With a more peaceful
course, will colonize Angola by means of black emigrants, run a railway
across Mozambique, and grow on the tablelands of Southern Central Africa
the finest wool and cotton in the world.
Africa shall be redeemed.  Her children shall perform this mighty work. 
Her morasses shall be drained; her deserts shall be watered by canals; her
forests shall be reduced to firewood.  Her children shall do all this. 
They shall pour an elixir vitae into the vein of their mother, now withered
and diseased. They shall restore her to youth and to immortal beauty.
In this amiable task they may possibly be exterminated.  We must learn to
look on this result with composure. It illustrates the beneficient law of
Nature, that the weak must be devoured by the strong.  
But a grateful Posterity will cherish their memories.  When the Cockneys of
Timbuctoo have their tea-gardens in the Oases of the Sahara; when hotels
and guide-books are established at the soruces of the Nile; when it becomes
fashionable to go yachting on the lakes of the Great Plateau; when
noblemen, building seats in Central Africa, will have their elephant parks
and their hippopotami waters, young ladies on camp-stools under palm-trees
will read with tears THE LAST OF THE NEGROES, and the Niger will become as
romantic as the Rhine."

Hudson comments: "These quotations are not merely antiquarian documents of
the past, they are scenarios for the future.  Market forces may be cited to
starve out populations unfortunate enough to have been left behind by the
course of economic progress.  Droughts and famine will be blamed on nature
rather than on deforestation, inadequate irrigation expenditures, and
related shortfalls in infrastructure spending by governments saddled with
austerity programmes. The ultimate question is not whether third world
labour is cheap enough but whether it is so low-priced as to deprive it of
earning the income necessary to invest in education and related
human-capital skills at a rate sufficient to make itself competitive in
today's high technology world." (235-6)

Rakesh Bhandari
UC Berkeley




[PEN-L:5148] Re: profit-rate equalization

1995-05-19 Thread ECAS


Ajit continues his discussion with me on value thus:
-
In Marx a theory of prices is needed to insure the
reproduction of the system, which intails realization of
the surplus. Thus prices occupy different places and
significance in different theoretical structure, and so
are 'abstract' concepts.

Paul
-
I think that this is a highly questionable interpretation
of Marx. It looks like Marx seen through the Sraffian
problematic. But is does not sit with the way things are
actually presented in Marxs writings in his published
volume of Capital and in the Contribution to the Critique
which contain extensive passages dealing with money, his
concern is with questions like why quantities of social
labour are expressed as prices, ie in the form of
quantities of gold. This is part of the general argument
that establishes that the prices of commodities are
proportional to their labour contents, which leads on to
the theory of exploitation. The theory of surplus value
depends upon being able to translate price quantities (
including the price of labour power ) into quantities of
time, and thus logically depends upon his earlier
explanation of price.

The question of reproduction and realisation is not gone
into until volume II of capital, and it is here examined
quite independently of prices. Prices are not returned to
until volume 3 where he deals with how they may
systematically diverge from values under the influence of
private property in land and of competition between
capitals. It is here introduced as a 'realist'
accomodation to what Marx believed to be an empirical
fact - a very narrow dispersion of profit rates. But it
is dealt with quite appart from the treatment of
reproduction. It is only later writers,  who have tried
to deal simultaneously with reproduction and the
formation of an equal rate of profit and to derive rules
for the formation of prices that would achieve this
___

This is the crux of the matter. In the *Contribution to the Critique* as well
as the first chapter of *Capital*, the question of surplus does not arise
because the system has only one class, the class of commodity producers/owners.
Marx introduces the problematic of value in this context, where the problem is
the allocation of the *total social labour* in order to fulfill the total needs
or demand registered in the market. The framework is essentially the
neo-classical framework of allocation of the *given* resources, where value or
prices play the role of allocating the resource (the given social labour) such
that supply matches demand. Marx's letter to Kugelmann of July 11, 1868 as well
as his various comments such as "[Robinson Crusoe's problem] contain[s] all the
essential determinants of value" could scarcely mean anything else. My thesis
is that once *capital* and *wage labour* are introduced in the system, a
fundamental *break* takes place in Marx's problematic. Marx's problematic
shifts from a *scarcity* problematic to a *surplus* problematic. The
fundamental assumption of the scarcity or allocative problematic that the
resources or the total social labour is *given* cannot be maintained in his
surplus framework. In a simple commodity producing economy the producer or the
supplier of labour supplies labour in order to fulfill his/her needs, i.e. both
the demand and supply decisions are rooted in the single individual and
therefore, Say's law holds. The neo-classical economics maintains the same
framework for the supply of labour in the capitalist economy as well, where the
workers determine labour supply on the basis of their utility functions. But in
Marx's framework the total real wage basket, on the one hand, is determined by
social and historical factors, whereas the *supply of labour* is determined by
the struggle between the two *classes* (i.e. the strength of the combatents).
And this struggle determines the production of surplus--given the wage basket.
As you can see, in this framework the *total social labour* is by no means
*given*. It is an outcome of a class struggle. Before you could introduce the
problematic of allocation, you have to deal with the production of surplus.
Thus my statement that the problematic of value must be read in the context of
the reproduction of the capitalist system that entails realization of the
surplus. 

Cheers, ajit sinha



[PEN-L:5147] Re: Justice

1995-05-19 Thread bill mitchell

Curtis offered much more than is here:

[deletions]
>  The book's fallacy lies in thinking that virtuous people will
>grow up to become a virtuous society.  On the contrary, as
>Reinhold Niebuhr taught us, there is a "basic difference between
>the morality of individuals and the morality of collectives." 
>Virtuous people grow up to hold news conferences putting
>corporate concerns ahead of the common good.
>
[deletions]
>
>  I guess that the point of the above article as it relates to
>Bill Mitchell's post (see below) is that we as individuals have
>to do something MORE than simply practice personal virtues, or
>society isn't going to get any better.  This something more
>surely involves actively promoting a good social democratic
>POLITICAL agenda as another PEN-ler pointed out in response to
>Mitchell's post.  

And of-course i agree. and did i not say that in the stream of 
mails on this topic.

but movements become corrupted unless the individuals have compatible
values. 

it also raises the general issue off whether being a marxist extends into
a personal code of conduct as well as the collective code of conduct and
organisation. personally i feel it does, but i know others definately don't
agree with me. 

we had this for example in the private/public school debate. progressives on
this list said "sure i believe in the public sector, but not for my kids". i
was and am implacably opposed to that view. how can your own children be
more important than all the rest of the kids? at what point does socialism
cease to work when the so-called progressives are willing to privatise gains
at the 
obvious expense of the collective?

there are many more examples and issues here. we can talk about it if people
like. tonight (late friday afternoon) i still have a mountain of things to do.

kind regards
bill
**   
 William F. MitchellTelephone: +61-49-215027  .-_|\   
 Department of Economics   +61-49-705133 / \
 The University of NewcastleFax:   +61-49-216919 \.--._/*<-- 
 Callaghan   NSW  2308v  
 Australia  Email : [EMAIL PROTECTED]

 WWW Home Page: http://econ-www.newcastle.edu.au/~bill/billyhp.html 
**